Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Similar documents
Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

The Black-Scholes Equation

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Risk Neutral Valuation

1 Geometric Brownian motion

3.1 Itô s Lemma for Continuous Stochastic Variables

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Monte Carlo Simulations

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

The Black-Scholes Model

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

The Black-Scholes Model

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Lévy models in finance

5. Itô Calculus. Partial derivative are abstractions. Usually they are called multipliers or marginal effects (cf. the Greeks in option theory).

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Financial Risk Management

Deriving and Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Geometric Brownian Motion

King s College London

Extensions to the Black Scholes Model

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Errata, Mahler Study Aids for Exam 3/M, Spring 2010 HCM, 1/26/13 Page 1

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Lecture: Continuous Time Finance Lecturer: o. Univ. Prof. Dr. phil. Helmut Strasser

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

Risk Neutral Pricing Black-Scholes Formula Lecture 19. Dr. Vasily Strela (Morgan Stanley and MIT)

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction

King s College London

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Solutions to Practice Problems

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

************* with µ, σ, and r all constant. We are also interested in more sophisticated models, such as:

Lecture 3. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences.

The stochastic calculus

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Numerical schemes for SDEs

The Black-Scholes Model

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Stochastic Modelling in Finance

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

JDEP 384H: Numerical Methods in Business

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 6

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Derivative Securities

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

1. 2 marks each True/False: briefly explain (no formal proofs/derivations are required for full mark).

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

Financial derivatives exam Winter term 2014/2015

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 2 Solutions

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

MAS452/MAS6052. MAS452/MAS Turn Over SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS AND STATISTICS. Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics

CHAPTER 5 ELEMENTARY STOCHASTIC CALCULUS. In all of these X(t) is Brownian motion. 1. By considering X 2 (t), show that

Introduction Taylor s Theorem Einstein s Theory Bachelier s Probability Law Brownian Motion Itô s Calculus. Itô s Calculus.

Near-Expiry Asymptotics of the Implied Volatility in Local and Stochastic Volatility Models

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Transcription:

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus

Continuous time models We start with the model from Chapter 3 log S j log S j 1 = µ t + p tz j Sum it over j: log S N log S 0 = NX µ t + NX p tzj j=1 j=1 Can we take the limit as N approaches infinity (delta t tends to zero)? What are the benefits? last sum converges to a normal random variable, so we call it lognormal! what is more important than the distribution of S at a fixed time? increments: log S N log S M = NX µ t + NX p tzj j=m+1 j=m+1

Stock price as a process Prices at different times: S 0,S 1,S 2,...,S N We must consider them as a collection of random variables Obviously the order is important - when you enter at time j and exit at time k, you care about log S j log S k, another random variable A collection of time indexed random variables - a stochastic process Not only are we concerned about individual need to consider all possible increments S j log S j as a random variable, we also log S k As random variables, we ask for their distributions. But the relations between different increments can be crucial for dependence consideration Natural first step: independent increments. Is it appropriate for stock prices?

Increments Price change over a time period What we get from our discrete model: a sum of independent Bernoulli rv s - binomial rv If we further divide the time period into subintervals, we are still dealing with binomial rv s As the partition increases, these binomial rv s converge to normal rv s (in distribution), justified by CLT. Statistics: the mean and the variance (of increments) should depend on the time elapsed: µ(t j t k ) and 2 (t j t k ) Independent increments: as long as individual rv s are independent!

Random walk and Markov property Use notation X j = log S j A sum of steps, each consisting of two components (drift + Z) Called a random walk, X_j is the position of the walk at time j Increments X j X k, independent of all the previous X s before k Distribution of X at j, given X at k, is unaffected by the X values before k Dependence of the history up to k - only through X at k This is called the Markov property!

From random walk to Brownian motion Think of the limiting process as N!1, t! 0, N t = T X j = X tj! X t, collection of rv s indexed by a continuous time variable t Properties inherited or extended: X at t is a normal random variable; increment X t X s is a normal random variable: N µ(t s), 2 (t s) increments from nonoverlapping periods are independent The path, X as a function of t, is continuous, but nowhere differentiable Standard notation: W t

Definition of BM W t W 0 =0 W t W s A process indexed by t for t>=0 is a Brownian motion if, and for every t and s (s<t), we have distributed as a normal random variable with mean 0 and variance t-s, and the random variable W t W s is independent of the W random variables before s. The above says much more. Just compare with X t = p ty where Y = N(0, 1) Quadratic variations and the relevance: why is it that the variance is proportional to the time elapsed? why is that BM paths are so ragged? how does the stock price variance grow in time?

Extending BM Add a (time-dependent) drift Allow local variance (for each step) to be time-dependent Discrete time: X j X j 1 = µ j t + j p tzj Continuous time: dx t = µ(t) dt + (t) dw t Stock return over (t,t+dt): ds t S t = µ(t) dt + (t) dw t This is the Black-Scholes model for stock price ds t Attempt to solve - do we have = d log S t? S t

Ito s lemma assume that f(x) is continuously twice differentiable usual differential: df = f (x) dx if x=x(t) is also continuously differentiable (in t): df = f (x) x (t) dt now let x=x_t from a stochastic process as described in the previous slide notice W_t is nowhere differentiable guess: df (X t )=f 0 (X t ) dx t = f 0 (X t )(µdt + dw t )? not quite! as we see expect dw 2 t =2W t dw t + dt Wt+h 2 Wt 2 =(W t+h W t )(W t+h + W t ) =2W t (W t+h W t )+(W t+h W t ) 2

From Taylor expansion Assuming f(x) twice differentiable f(x t+h )=f(x t )+f 0 (X t )(X t+h X t )+ 1 2 f 00 (X t )(X t+h X t ) 2 + Ito process: dx t = µ(x t,t) dt + (X t,t) dw t X t+h X t = µh + p hz + e with approximations: (X t+h X t ) 2 = µ 2 h 2 + 2 hz 2 +2µ h 3/2 Z + Leading term (in h) after replacing Z^2 with 1: 2 h Justifications: the difference has mean and variance: 2 he[z 2 1] = 0, 4 h 2 Var(Z 2 1) = 3 4 h 2

Ito s lemma Letting h! dt Assuming differentiability again d(f(x t )) = f 0 (X t )µ + 12 f 00 (X t ) 2 If we allow f to be time dependent dt + f 0 (X t ) dw t d(f(x t,t)) = f t (X t,t)+f x (X t,t)µ + 12 f xx(x t,t) 2 dt + f x (X t,t) dw t Theorem 5.1 (page 110) notations dt 2 =0 dt dw t =0 (dw t ) 2 = dt

Applications Product rule: let X_t and Y_t be Ito processes d(x t Y t )=X t dy t + Y t dx t + dx t dy t If dx t = µ 1 dt + 1 dw t then dy t = µ 2 dt + 2 dw t dx t dy t = 1 2 (dw t ) 2 = 1 2 dt What about d Xt Y t

Applications in stock price modeling Solving SDE ds t S t = µdt+ dw t Try f(s t ) = log S t df (S t )= 1 ds t + 1 1 S t 2 1 2 = µ dt + 2 S 2 t dw t 2 S 2 t dt Integrate in t, assuming constant mu and sigma log S T log S 0 = µ 1 2 2 T + W T S T = S 0 exp apple µ 1 2 2 T + W T

CEV model Assuming volatility is S-dependent ds t = µdt + S 1 t S t dw t 0 < < 1 implies that the volatility is inverse proportional to S f(s) = S1, Ito s lemma gives 1 d(f(s t )) = S 1 µ 2 S 1 2 dt + dw t No luck in explicit solution unless beta=1

Deriving Black-Scholes Equation Consider the pricing of a call option C, with strike K, expiration T Assume S follows a geometric BM Risk free interest rate r At time t<t, the price of call is a function of stock price at the time (S) Recognizing C=C(S,t) dc(s t,t)= @C @t = dt + @C @S ds t + 1 2 C t + µsc S + 1 2 @ 2 C @S 2 (ds t) 2 2 S 2 C SS dt + SC S dw t

Deriving Black-Scholes Equation (continued) Forming a portfolio: one share of call + alpha shares of the stock Change of the portfolio over (t,t+dt), assuming constant alpha: d(c + S) = C t + µsc S + 1 2 2 S 2 C SS + µs If we choose = C S (delta hedging), the random component disappears, which implies that the portfolio is hedged - no effect of stock price fluctuation dt + S (C S + ) dw t Portfolio is iick-free, we must have d(c + S) =r(c + S)dt This leads to the Black-Scholes PDE with terminal condition C t + rsc S + 1 2 2 S 2 C SS = rc C(S T,T) = max(s T K, 0) Compare with the standard heat equation, suggest backward in time

Use of the PDE The PDE is parabolic, solutions will be smoothed in time (backward) Set up a region in (S,t): 0 < t < T, 0<S< S_max Terminal condition imposed at t=t Solve backward in time to 0: C(S,0) Enter the observed current price S(0) in place of S Boundary conditions: C(0,t) = 0, C(S_max,t) = (S_max - K) exp(-r(t-t)) Advantage of the PDE approach: easy to extend to time-dependent sigma efficient numerical methods available

Justification of the derivation How do we justify this price (solution from a PDE)? Imagine you start with C(S,0), when the stock price is S. By following the delta hedge strategy, you want to end up with the value max(s_t-k,0), no matter what happens to the market Replication strategy: invest C(S,0) in stock and the risk-less bond, adjusting according to the call delta, verify at T that the total value matches the call payoff Composition of the portfolio: alpha shares of the stock, beta units of the bond P (t) = (t)s(t)+ (t)b(t) (t), (t) to be adjusted, according to the strategy

Change of value in the portfolio Change of portfolio value in time: P (t + t) P (t) In differential: dp = (t)ds(t)+ (t)db(t)+ S(t)d (t)+ B(t)d (t) In discrete form: (t + t)s(t + t) (t)s(t) = (t + t)s(t + t) (t)s(t + t)+ (t)s(t + t) (t)s(t) =( (t + t) (t)) S(t + t) + (t)(s(t + t) S(t)) (t + t)b(t + t) (t)b(t) = (t + t)b(t + t) (t)b(t + t)+ (t)b(t + t) (t)b(t) =( (t + t) (t)) B(t + t) + (t)(b(t + t) B(t)) Total change in two parts: (t)(s(t + t) S(t)) + (t)(b(t + t) B(t))! ds + db ( (t + t) (t)) S(t + t) +( (t + t) (t)) B(t + t)! Sd + Bd + d ds + d db

Self-financing strategy First part in the last slide: change in stock price, bond price, holding shares fixed over time period Second part: adjusting the number of shares, all at the end of the time period Self-financing strategy: making sure the second part is zero This corresponds to rebalancing in such a way that no money is taken out of the portfolio, and no money is injected into the portfolio either Such is the name of the strategy: self-financing Consequence of this trading strategy: dp = ds + db

Replicating the call Begin with a portfolio Following = @C @S, and a beta such that it is a self-financing strategy Want to show P(T) = C(S(T),T), no matter what S(T) ends up with Consider the differential P = (0)S(0) + (0)B(0) = C(S(0), 0) d (P (S, t) C(S, t)) = dp dc = @C @C ds + db @S = rbdt @t dt @C @t dt 1 2 @ 2 C @S 2 @C @S ds 1 @ 2 C 2 @S 2 (ds)2 2 S 2 dt We use ds S = µdt + dw, db = rbdt, P = @C @S S + B, and the BS equation Result: d(p C) =r (P SC S ) dt r (C SC S ) dt = r(p C)dt

Matching at T Solving the ODE: P (t) C(t) =(P (0) C(0)) e rt =0 We have P (S, t) =C(S, t), for 0 <tapple T, the call is replicated! Need to check the self-financing condition Theorem 5.3: A unique beta exists, given alpha is a smooth function of S and an initial portfolio value P(0), such that P = S + B is a self-financing portfolio with initial value P(0). Implication on the hedging practice: by the end of the trading adjustment period, the rebalancing needs to observe the following condition: there can only be transfer of money within the stock and bond accounts

Solving the PDE Linear PDE, variable coefficients A series of changes of variables introduced to reduce to the heat equation First, S = e Z, we arrive at a constant-coefficient equation @C @t + r 1 2 2 @C @Z + 1 2 2 @2 C @Z 2 = rc Change of time variable @C @ r 1 2 2 @C @Z = T 1 2 t 2 @2 C + rc =0 @Z2 C = e r D @D @ r 1 2 2 @D @Z 1 2 2 @2 D @Z 2 =0

Heat Equation Eliminate the first-order term: y = Z + r 1 2 2 Standard heat equation @D @ = 1 2 2 @2 D @y 2 Initial condition is also likewise transformed Solution transformed into the original variables Black-Scholes formula reproduced

Dividend-paying stock The previous model assumes no dividend paying stocks Many stocks do pay dividends FX products - foreign currency as the underlying and it grows at its rf rate This model assumes reinvestment If the dividend rate is d, one share at t will grow to exp(d(t-t)) shares at T Buying exp(-d(t-t)) shares is equivalent to one futures contract: Price of a futures contract: S(t)e d(t t) Ke r(t t) or delivery contract price delivered at T X(t) =S(t)e d(t t), the price at t to have one share

Call option on X An option on X with expiration T must have the same value as an option on S But the delivery contract pays no dividend (X is its price) Process for X: Drift does not matter! dx t X t =(µ + d) dt + dw t Call price: C(S, t) =XN(d 1 ) Ke r(t t) N(d 2 ) = Se d(t t) N(d 1 ) Ke r(t t) N(d 2 ) with d 1 = log(s/k)+ r d + 1 2 2 (T t) p p, d 2 = d 1 T t T t Applies to commodity options - it costs money to hold commodities (d=-q), this is the cost of carry.