Derivative Instruments

Similar documents
Derivative Instruments

Properties of Stock Options

Financial Derivatives Section 3

University of Colorado at Boulder Leeds School of Business MBAX-6270 MBAX Introduction to Derivatives Part II Options Valuation

Derivative Instruments

Option Properties Liuren Wu

12 Bounds. on Option Prices. Answers to Questions and Problems

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Chapter 14. Exotic Options: I. Question Question Question Question The geometric averages for stocks will always be lower.

EC3070 FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES FUTURES: MARKING TO MARKET

Derivative Instruments

ECO OPTIONS AND FUTURES SPRING Options

Chapter 2 Questions Sample Comparing Options

S 0 C (30, 0.5) + P (30, 0.5) e rt 30 = PV (dividends) PV (dividends) = = $0.944.

Options and Derivatives

MATH 6911 Numerical Methods in Finance

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 10

Chapter 14 Exotic Options: I

Lecture 12. Stock Option boundary conditions. Agenda:

Forwards, Futures, Options and Swaps

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology

Options Markets: Introduction

I. Reading. A. BKM, Chapter 20, Section B. BKM, Chapter 21, ignore Section 21.3 and skim Section 21.5.

Interest Rates & Present Value. 1. Introduction to Options. Outline

CHAPTER 1 Introduction to Derivative Instruments

CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II. Derivatives and Risk Management By Rajiv Srivastava. Copyright Oxford University Press

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Help Session 4. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

LECTURE 1 : Introduction and Review of Option Payoffs

LECTURE 12. Volatility is the question on the B/S which assumes constant SD throughout the exercise period - The time series of implied volatility

Chapter 1 Introduction. Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright John C. Hull

B. Combinations. 1. Synthetic Call (Put-Call Parity). 2. Writing a Covered Call. 3. Straddle, Strangle. 4. Spreads (Bull, Bear, Butterfly).

OPTIONS & GREEKS. Study notes. An option results in the right (but not the obligation) to buy or sell an asset, at a predetermined

Week 5. Options: Basic Concepts

Applying Principles of Quantitative Finance to Modeling Derivatives of Non-Linear Payoffs

Chapter 17. Options and Corporate Finance. Key Concepts and Skills

UNIVERSITY OF AGDER EXAM. Faculty of Economicsand Social Sciences. Exam code: Exam name: Date: Time: Number of pages: Number of problems: Enclosure:

Valuation of Options: Theory

CHAPTER 17 OPTIONS AND CORPORATE FINANCE

Mechanics of Options Markets. Prf. José Fajardo Fundação Getulio Vargas

Notes for Lecture 5 (February 28)

2 The binomial pricing model

C T P T S T

CHAPTER 27: OPTION PRICING THEORY

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

P1.T3. Financial Markets & Products. Hull, Options, Futures & Other Derivatives. Trading Strategies Involving Options

Option Pricing: basic principles Definitions Value boundaries simple arbitrage relationships put-call parity

3 + 30e 0.10(3/12) > <

RMSC 2001 Introduction to Risk Management

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

The Binomial Approach

Super-replicating portfolios

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Market, exchange over the counter, standardised ( amt, maturity), OTC private, specifically tailored)

CHAPTER 20 Spotting and Valuing Options

Equity Option Valuation Practical Guide

Chapter 2. An Introduction to Forwards and Options. Question 2.1

Futures and Forward Contracts

Lecture 7: Trading Strategies Involve Options ( ) 11.2 Strategies Involving A Single Option and A Stock

Financial Mathematics Principles

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

MBF1243 Derivatives Prepared by Dr Khairul Anuar

The Binomial Model for Stock Options

JEM034 Corporate Finance Winter Semester 2017/2018

MATH4210 Financial Mathematics ( ) Tutorial 6

ECON4510 Finance Theory

American options and early exercise

Introduction to Forwards and Futures

A GLOSSARY OF FINANCIAL TERMS MICHAEL J. SHARPE, MATHEMATICS DEPARTMENT, UCSD

Lecture 4: Barrier Options

Answers to Selected Problems

The parable of the bookmaker

Derivatives Analysis & Valuation (Futures)

Appendix: Basics of Options and Option Pricing Option Payoffs

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

University of Texas at Austin. HW Assignment 5. Exchange options. Bull/Bear spreads. Properties of European call/put prices.

The Multistep Binomial Model

ActuarialBrew.com. Exam MFE / 3F. Actuarial Models Financial Economics Segment. Solutions 2014, 1 st edition

Technically, volatility is defined as the standard deviation of a certain type of return to a

Fin 501: Asset Pricing Fin 501:

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

A grantor retained annuity trust (GRAT) is a financial

Lecture 16: Delta Hedging

Lecture 5. Trading With Portfolios. 5.1 Portfolio. How Can I Sell Something I Don t Own?

Chapter 20: Financial Options

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

MATH 476/567 ACTUARIAL RISK THEORY FALL 2016 PROFESSOR WANG. Homework 3 Solution

Options (2) Class 20 Financial Management,

Chapter 15. Learning Objectives & Agenda. Economic Benefits Provided by. Options. Options

MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS

Global Financial Management. Option Contracts

Introduction to Binomial Trees. Chapter 12

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

AFM 371 Winter 2008 Chapter 25 - Warrants and Convertibles

Financial Derivatives Section 1

Options. Investment Management. Fall 2005

Transcription:

Derivative Instruments Paris Dauphine University - Master I.E.F. (272) Autumn 2016 Jérôme MATHIS jerome.mathis@dauphine.fr (object: IEF272) http://jerome.mathis.free.fr/ief272 Slides on book: John C. Hull, Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, Pearson ed. LEDa Chapter 9 Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 1 / 39

Chapter 9: Properties of Stock Options Outline 1 Introduction 2 Factors Affecting Option Prices 3 4 Summary Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 2 / 39

Introduction Motivation We shall use a number of different arbitrage arguments to explore the relationships between European option prices, American option prices, and the underlying stock price. The most important of these relationships is put-call parity, which is a relationship between the price of a European call option, the price of a European put option, and the underlying stock price. We shall also examine whether American options should be exercised early. We shall see that in most cases it is not optimal to exercise an American call option on a non-dividend-paying stock prior to the option s expiration. When there are dividends, it can be optimal to exercise either calls or puts early. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 3 / 39

Chapter 9: Properties of Stock Options Outline 1 Introduction 2 Factors Affecting Option Prices 3 4 Summary Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 4 / 39

Factors Affecting Option Prices Notation Call option price: c: European C: American Put option price: p: European P: American Stock price: S 0 : today S T : at maturity T Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 5 / 39

Factors Affecting Option Prices Notation K : Strike price σ: Volatility of stock price Roughly speaking, the volatility of a stock price is a measure of how uncertain we are about future stock price movements. D: PV of dividends paid during life of option r: Risk-free rate for maturity T with continuous compounding. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 6 / 39

Factors Affecting Option Prices Effect of Variables on Option Pricing Variable c p C P S 0 + + K + + T?? + + S 0 : the higher the stock price today, the higher (resp. lower) the call (resp. put) option price. K : Call (resp. put) options become less (resp. more) valuable as the strike price increase. T : American options become more valuable as the time to expiration increases. European options usually become more valuable as the time to expiration increases, but this is not always the case. If a very large dividend is expected then an european call option that expires before the dividend is paid is worth more than an european call option that expires after the dividend is paid. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 7 / 39

Factors Affecting Option Prices Effect of Variables on Option Pricing Variable c p C P σ + + + + D + + σ: As volatility increases, the chance that the stock will do very well or very poorly increases. For the owner of a stock, these two outcomes tend to offset each other. However, the owner of an option benefits from one particular direction price change but has limited downside risk in the event of a change in the opposite direction, because the most the owner can lose is the price of the option. The values of both calls and puts therefore increase as volatility increases. D: Dividends have the effect of reducing the stock price on the ex-dividend date. This is bad news for the value of call options and good news for the value of put options. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 8 / 39

Factors Affecting Option Prices American vs European Options An American option is worth at least as much as the corresponding European option C c and P p. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 9 / 39

Chapter 9: Properties of Stock Options Outline 1 Introduction 2 Factors Affecting Option Prices 3 4 Summary Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 10 / 39

Upper Bounds An American or European call option gives the holder the right to buy one share of a stock for a certain price. No matter what happens, the option can never be worth more than the stock. Hence, the stock price is an upper bound to the option price: c S 0 and C S 0. If these relationships were not true, an arbitrageur could easily make a riskless profit by buying the stock and selling the call option. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 11 / 39

Upper Bounds An American put option gives the holder the right to sell one share of a stock for K. No matter how low the stock price becomes, the option can never be worth more than K. Hence, P K. For European options, we know that at maturity the option cannot be worth more than K. It follows that it cannot be worth more than the present value of K today: p Ke rt. If this were not true, an arbitrageur could make a riskless profit by writing the option and investing the proceeds of the sale at the risk-free interest rate. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 12 / 39

Lower Bound for Calls on Non-Dividend-Paying Stocks Proposition A lower bound for the price of a European call option on a non-dividend-paying stock is max(s 0 Ke rt, 0). Proof. Consider the following two portfolios: Portfolio A: one European call option plus a zero-coupon bond that provides a payoff of K at time T. Portfolio B: one share of the stock. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 13 / 39

Lower Bound for Calls on Non-Dividend-Paying Stocks Proof. In portfolio A, at time T we have: The zero-coupon bond is worth K. If S T > K, the call option is exercised. The portfolio A is then worth (S T K ) + K = S T. If S T < K, the call option expires worthless The portfolio A is then worth K. Hence, at time T portfolio A is worth max(s T, K ). Portfolio B is worth S T at time T. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 14 / 39

Lower Bound for Calls on Non-Dividend-Paying Stocks Proof. Hence, portfolio A is always worth as much as, and can be worth more than, portfolio B at the option s maturity. It follows that in the absence of arbitrage opportunities this must also be true today. The zero-coupon bond is worth Ke rt today. Hence, c + Ke rt S 0 c S 0 Ke rt. Because the worst that can happen to a call option is that it expires worthless, its value cannot be negative. This means that c 0 and therefore c max(s 0 Ke rt, 0). Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 15 / 39

Lower Bound for European Puts on Non-Dividend-Paying Stocks Proposition For a European put option on a non-dividend-paying stock, a lower bound for the price is Proof. max(ke rt S 0, 0) Consider the following two portfolios: Portfolio C: one European put option plus one share. Portfolio D: a zero-coupon bond paying off K at time T. If S T < K, then the option in portfolio C is exercised at option maturity and the portfolio becomes worth K. If S T > K, then the put option expires worthless and the portfolio is worth S T at this time. Hence, portfolio C is worth max{s T, K } in time T. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 16 / 39

Lower Bound for European Puts on Non-Dividend-Paying Stocks Proof. Portfolio D is worth K in time T. Hence, portfolio C is always worth as much as, and can sometimes be worth more than, portfolio D in time T. It follows that in the absence of arbitrage opportunities portfolio C must be worth at least as much as portfolio D today. Hence, p + S 0 Ke rt p Ke rt S 0. Because p 0 we have p max(ke rt S 0, 0). Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 17 / 39

Put-Call Parity Proposition (Put-Call Parity) The value of a European call with a exercise price K and exercise date T can be deduced from the value of a European put with the same exercise price and exercise date, and vice versa, according to the following formula c + Ke rt = p + S 0. Proof. Consider the two A and C used in the proof of the previous proposition. We have already shown that they are both worth max{s T, K } at time T. Since the portfolios have identical values at time T, they must have identical values today. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 18 / 39

Put-Call Parity Proof. The components of portfolio A are worth c and Ke rt today. The components of portfolio C are worth p and S 0 today. Hence, c + Ke rt = p + S 0. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 19 / 39

Put-Call Parity Question What would be the arbitrage opportunity if c + Ke rt < p + S 0? Solution Action now: Buy call for c; Short put to realize p; Short the stock to realize S 0 ; and Invest S 0 + p c for T years. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 20 / 39

Put-Call Parity Solution Action in T years if S T > K : Receive (S 0 + p c) e rt from investment; Exercise call to buy stock for K ; Net profit = (S 0 + p c) e rt K. Action in T years if S T < K : Receive (S 0 + p c) e rt from investment; Put exercised: buy stock for K ; Net profit = (S 0 + p c) e rt K. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 21 / 39

Put-Call Parity Question What would be the arbitrage opportunity if c + Ke rt > p + S 0? Solution Action now: Buy put for p; Buy the stock for S 0 ; Short call to realize c; and Borrow p + S 0 c for T years. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 22 / 39

Put-Call Parity Solution Action in T years if S T > K : Call exercised: sell stock for K ; Use (S 0 + p c) e rt to repay loan; Net profit = K (S 0 + p c) e rt. Action in T years if S T < K : Exercise put to sell stock for K ; Use (S 0 + p c) e rt to repay loan; Net profit = K (S 0 + p c) e rt. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 23 / 39

Put-Call Parity Proposition (Put-Call Parity) When there are no dividends, an American option satisfies S 0 K C P S 0 Ke rt. Proof. Homework. (Hint: For the first part of the relationship consider (a) a portfolio consisting of a European call plus an amount of cash equal to K and (b) a portfolio consisting of an American put option plus one share.) Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 24 / 39

Early Exercise of Calls on a Non-Dividend Paying Stock There are two reasons an American call on a non-dividend-paying stock should not be exercised early. One relates to the insurance that it provides. A call option, when held instead of the stock itself, in effect insures the holder against the stock price falling below the strike price. Once the option has been exercised and the strike price has been exchanged for the stock price, this insurance vanishes. The other reason concerns the time value of money. From the perspective of the option holder, the later the strike price is paid out the better. Indeed, we have C c S 0 Ke rt S 0 K. This means that C is always greater than the option s intrinsic value prior to maturity. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 25 / 39

Upper and lower bounds Because American call options are never exercised early when there are no dividends, they are equivalent to European call options, so that C = c. It follows that upper and lower bounds are given by max(s 0 Ke rt, 0) c = C S 0. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 26 / 39

Upper and lower bounds We then have the following figure Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 27 / 39

Early Exercise on Puts on a Non-Dividend Paying Stock It can be optimal to exercise an American put option on a non-dividend-paying stock early. To illustrate, consider an extreme situation. Suppose that the strike price is $10 and the stock price is virtually zero. By exercising immediately, an investor makes an immediate gain of $10. If the investor waits, the gain from exercise might be less than $10, but it cannot be more than $10, because negative stock prices are impossible. Furthermore, receiving $10 now is preferable to receiving $10 in the future. It follows that the option should be exercised immediately. Therefore at any given time during its life, a put option should always be exercised early if it is sufficiently deep in the money. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 28 / 39

Upper and lower bonds on Puts on a Non-Dividend Paying Stock For European options, when there is no dividend we already know that max(ke rt S 0, 0) p Ke rt. For an American put option on a non-dividend-paying stock, we have max(k S 0, 0) P because the option can be exercised at any time. American put option on a non-dividend-paying stock then satisfies max(k S 0, 0) P K Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 29 / 39

Upper and lower bonds on Puts on a Non-Dividend Paying Stock We then have the following figure Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 30 / 39

Exercise (6) The price of an American call on a non-dividend-paying stock is $4. The stock price is $31, the strike price is $30, and the expiration date is in three months. The risk-free interest rate is 8%. Derive upper and lower bounds for the price of an American put on the same stock with the same strike price and expiration date. Solution (6) We have S 0 K C P S 0 Ke rt with S 0 = 31, K = 30, C = 4, r = 0.08, and T = 0.25. So $2.41 P $3.00 Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 31 / 39

The Impact of Dividends on Lower Bounds to Option Prices Let D denotes the present value of the dividends during the life of the option. We have max(s 0 D Ke rt, 0) c and max(d + Ke rt S 0, 0) p Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 32 / 39

The Impact of Dividends on Put-Call Parity We also have c + D + Ke rt = p + S 0 and S 0 D K C P S 0 Ke rt. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 33 / 39

Exercise (5) The price of a European call that expires in six months and has a strike price of $30 is $2. The underlying stock price is $29, and a dividend of $0.50 is expected in two months and again in five months. The term structure is flat, with all risk-free interest rates being 10%. What is the price of a European put option that expires in six months and has a strike price of $30? Solution (5) The put-call parity can be written as In this case p = c + Ke rt + D S 0 p = 2 + 30e 0.1 6 12 + (0.5e 0.1 2 12 + 0.5e 0.1 5 12 ) 29 = $2.51 Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 34 / 39

Chapter 9: Properties of Stock Options Outline 1 Introduction 2 Factors Affecting Option Prices 3 4 Summary Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 35 / 39

Summary We have examine five factors affecting the value of a stock option: the current stock price; the strike price; the expiration date; the stock price volatility; and the dividends expected during the life of the option. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 36 / 39

Summary The value of a call generally: increases as the current stock price, the time to expiration, and the volatility increase; and decreases as the strike price and expected dividends increase. The value of a put generally: increases as the strike price, the time to expiration, the volatility, and the expected dividends increase; and decreases as the current stock price increase. It is possible to reach some conclusions about the value of stock options without making any assumptions about the volatility of stock prices. For example, the price of a call option on a stock must always be worth less than the price of the stock itself. Similarly, the price of a put option on a stock must always be worth less than the option s strike price. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 37 / 39

Summary A European call option on a non-dividend-paying stock must be worth more than max(s 0 Ke rt, 0) where S 0 is the stock price, K is the strike price, r is the risk-free interest rate, and T is the time to expiration. A European put option on a non-dividend-paying stock must be worth more than max(ke rt S 0, 0) When dividends with present value D will be paid, the lower bound for a European call option becomes max(s 0 D Ke rt, 0) and the lower bound for a European put option becomes max(e rt + D S 0, 0) Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 38 / 39

Summary Put-call parity is a relationship between the price, c, of a European call option on a stock and the price, p, of a European put option on a stock. For a non-dividend-paying stock, it is c + Ke rt = p + S 0 For a dividend-paying stock, the put-call parity relationship is c + D + Ke rt = p + S 0 Put-call parity does not hold for American options. However, it is possible to use arbitrage arguments to obtain upper and lower bounds for the difference between the price of an American call and the price of an American put. Jérôme MATHIS (LEDa) Derivative Instruments Chapter 9 39 / 39