Ability to Pay and Agriculture Sector Stability. Erin M. Hardin John B. Penson, Jr.

Similar documents
THE ROLE OF DEBT IN FARMLAND OWNERSHIP

What variables have historically impacted Kentucky and Iowa farmland values? John Barnhart

Macroeconomic Outlook: Implications for Agriculture. It has been 26 years since we have experienced a significant recession

Forecasting Cash Rent Values Erin M. Hardin, Justin R. Benavidez

Jason Henderson Vice President and Branch Executive Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Omaha Branch April 10, 2012

Credit Conditions for Young and Beginning Farmers. by Nathan S. Kauffman 1

Debt and Input Misallocation in Farm Supply and Marketing Cooperatives: A DEA Approach

Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez

Finding Your Financial Footing in 2016

October U.S. Farm Sector Capital Expenditures Michael Langemeier, Associate Director, Center for Commercial Agriculture

Jason Henderson Vice President and Branch Executive Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Omaha Branch May 17, 2011

Measuring Risk and Uncertainty Michael Langemeier, Associate Director, Center for Commercial Agriculture

Using Land Values to Predict Future Farm Income

Jason Henderson Vice President and Branch Executive Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Omaha Branch September 2012

Chapter 4. Agricultural Finance Calum G. Turvey, W.I. Myers Professor of Agricultural Finance

Effects of Price Volatility and Surging South American Soybean Production on Short-Run Soybean Basis Dynamics by. Rui Zhang and Jack Houston

Jason Henderson Vice President and Branch Executive Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Omaha Branch January 27, 2010

Leverage of U.S. Farmers: A Deeper Perspective

Farmland Values Will the Boom Turn Bust?

Indicators of the Kansas Economy

Macroeconomic Risks for Farmer Cooperatives

MANAGING THE RISK CAPTURING THE OPPORTUNITY IN CROP FARMING. Michael Boehlje and Brent Gloy Center for Commercial Agriculture Purdue University

Finding the New, New Normal in Agriculture

Brady Brewer, Allen Featherstone, Christine Wilson, and Brian Briggeman Department of Agricultural Economics Kansas State University

Center for Commercial Agriculture

Opportunities and challenges for agriculture. How will agriculture and the swine industry fare in today s economic climate? Opportunities.

The agricultural economy is in a constant state of adjustment,

Impact of Crop Insurance on Land Values. Michael Duffy

An Analysis of Historical Illinois Farmland Valuations

The impacts of cereal, soybean and rapeseed meal price shocks on pig and poultry feed prices

Farm Finance Update. Nate Kauffman Omaha Branch Executive and Economist Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. March 17, 2017

Agricultural Economic Update

Farmland Values, Government Payments, and the Overall Risk to U.S. Agriculture: A Structural Equation-Latent Variable Model

Agricultural Outlook Forum 1999 Presented: Monday, February 22, 1999

GRAIN MARKETS SENSITIVE TO EXPORTS, SOUTH AMERICAN WEATHER

How the Federal Reserve Can Affect Agriculture

Macroeconomic Outlook for U.S. Agriculture

This article is the second of a two-part series addressing credit risk

Lessons from previous US recessions and recoveries

To understand where the U.S. Economy is going, we need to understand where we have been

Relationship between Cash Rent and Net Return to Land

Second Quarter 2011 Earnings Conference Call. 18 May 2011

Fundamental Factors Affecting Agricultural and Other Commodities. Research & Product Development Updated July 11, 2008

Fund Management Diary

Incentives for Machinery Investment. J.C. Hadrich, R. A. Larsen, and F. E. Olson, North Dakota State University.

U.S. & Missouri Economic Outlook

3 The leverage cycle in Luxembourg s banking sector 1

Farmers Aren t Immune to Interest Rate Risk: A Duration Gap Analysis of Farm Balance Sheets

Farm Level Impacts of a Revenue Based Policy in the 2007 Farm Bill

Stagnation and Institutional Structures

THE IMPACT OF TRADING ACTIVITY ON AGRICULTURAL FUTURES MARKETS

International Journal of Business and Economic Development Vol. 4 Number 1 March 2016

b. Financial innovation and/or financial liberalization (the elimination of restrictions on financial markets) can cause financial firms to go on a

Adjusted Gross Revenue Pilot Insurance Program: Rating Procedure (Report prepared for the Risk Management Agency Board of Directors) J.

When Do Farm Booms Become Bubbles?

Part III. Cycles and Growth:

AGRICULTURAL LENDER SURVEY RESULTS

THE IMPACT OF LENDING ACTIVITY AND MONETARY POLICY IN THE IRISH HOUSING MARKET

Bank Risk Ratings and the Pricing of Agricultural Loans

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

SRC Annual Summary of Agricultural Conditions

MODELING CHANGES IN THE U.S. DEMAND FOR CROP INSURANCE DURING THE 1990S

Purdue Agricultural Economics Report

THE U.S. ECONOMY IN 1986

SPECIAL REPORT. TD Economics CONDITIONS ARE RIPE FOR AMERICAN CONSUMERS TO LEAD ECONOMIC GROWTH

Brady Brewer, Allen Featherstone, Christine Wilson, and Brian Briggeman Department of Agricultural Economics Kansas State University

Macroeconomic Effects from Government Purchases and Taxes. Robert J. Barro and Charles J. Redlick Harvard University

Forecasting Volatility in the Chinese Stock Market under Model Uncertainty 1

The Global Financial Crisis and the double recession in Spain

Future of the Agricultural Sector: Purdue Extension and Financial Markets

Finance Implications of Intergenerational Transfer of US Farms. Freddie Barnard and Elizabeth Yeager. Introduction

The Long View Rates, GDP & Challenges

Corporate and Household Sectors in Austria: Subdued Growth of Indebtedness

Second Quarter 2010 Earnings Conference Call. 19 May 2010

Information Content of USDA Rice Reports and Price Reactions of Rice Futures

AGRICULTURAL LENDER SURVEY. Spring 2018 Report

ALVAREZ & MARSAL READINGS IN QUANTITATIVE RISK MANAGEMENT. The Excess Capital Hypothesis and the Experience of Spanish Banks from 1999 to 2016

Evaluating the Use of Futures Prices to Forecast the Farm Level U.S. Corn Price

A Long Slog Ahead for US Agriculture

Chapter 10. The Great Recession: A First Look. (1) Spike in oil prices. (2) Collapse of house prices. (2) Collapse in house prices

Information Content of USDA Rice Reports and Price Reactions of Rice Futures. Jessica L. Darby and Andrew M. McKenzie

Testing the Effectiveness of Using a Corn Call or a Feeder Cattle Put for Feeder Cattle Price Protection. Hernan A. Tejeda and Dillon M.

Debt vs Growth: Correlation or Causation

AGRICULTURAL LENDER SURVEY

Greece. Eurozone rebalancing. EY Eurozone Forecast June Portugal Slovakia Slovenia Spain. Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Malta Netherlands

80 Solved MCQs of MGT201 Financial Management By

Theme Overview: Will Rising Interest Rates Lead to Intensifying Risks for Agriculture?

Module 12. Alternative Yield and Price Risk Management Tools for Wheat

Are Agricultural States Able to Absorb Economic Declines Better Than Their Counterparts?

Optimal Market Contracting In the California Lettuce Industry

A Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City July 16-17, Session 1: When Do Farm Booms Become Bubbles?

(F6' The. ,,42, ancy of the. U.S. Wheat Acreage Supply Elasticity. Special Report 546 May 1979

FALL 2018 AGRICULTURAL LENDER SURVEY RESULTS

Chapter URL:

Presidential and Congressional Vote-Share Equations: November 2018 Update

Producer-Level Hedging Effectiveness of Class III Milk Futures

Is Full Employment Sustainable?

The Farm Safety Net: The Good and Not So Good Michael Boehlje and Michael Langemeier Center for Commercial Agriculture Purdue University

Climate Policy Initiative Does crop insurance impact water use?

Comparison of Hedging Cost with Other Variable Input Costs. John Michael Riley and John D. Anderson

Transcription:

Ability to Pay and Agriculture Sector Stability Erin M. Hardin John B. Penson, Jr. Texas A&M University Department of Agricultural Economics 600 John Kimbrough Blvd 2124 TAMU College Station, TX 77843-2124 Emails: ehardin@tamu.edu; jpenson@tamu.edu Phone: (979) 845-5913 Selected Paper Presented at the Southern Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, Mobile, AL; February 4-7, 2017 Copyright 2016 by Erin M. Hardin and John B. Penson. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided this copyright notes appears on all such copies.

Ability to Pay and Agriculture Sector Stability Introduction In the past century the agriculture sector has witnessed three major boom and bust cycles, all following a relatively similar pattern. Profits increase due to a growth in exports and prices received, then with the larger cash flow, deleveraging and an expansion in capital expenditures occurs. Once profits begin to fall, capital expansion tends to continue for a period of time and debt grows to manage the increase leveraged positions. 1 In the recent agriculture boom, various aspects of this pattern have emerged yet again. Beginning in the late 1990 s, net farm income in U.S. agriculture began to expand from a little over two million dollars in Iowa to over twelve and a half million in 2012, a percent increase of close to 450%. 2 This increase in net cash farm income is largely due to increases in crop prices during that time (corn, + 300% and wheat, + 226%) 3, increases in yield per acre and increases in demand both domestically and internationally. Demand increases have been attributed to several factors. Firstly, the emergence of multiple free trade agreements in the mid to late 1990 s and 2000 s that have made exporting goods to the other countries easier. Secondly, expansions in both the population and income of developing countries have increased demand for U.S. exports; and finally, the boom in biofuels have increased domestic demand for grains. Comparing the recent boom in agriculture to that of the 1970 s, there are similarities in terms of the expansion of demand due to increases in international trade and higher prices. Farm operators have expanded operations increasing capital expenditures as well as their debt 1 Henderson and Kauffman, 2013, Farm Investment and Leverage Cycles: Will This Time Be Different? 2 USDA NASS Data 3 USDA NASS Data

positions. All cycles have also seen similar rapid increases in farmland prices. The changes in farmland value during these cycles are an important factor as it is the largest use for collateral for these loans. In the 1970 s, the average yearly increase of land in Iowa was 10% and increased overall 178% from 1971 to 1985. 4 Today, there have also been substantial increases in the market prices of farmland with the Midwest witnessing the largest. In 1987, following the downturn in the agriculture sector, farmland prices in Iowa averaged $1,311.42 in real terms. In 2015, farmland prices were $7,463.64 an increase of nearly 500%. In the past decade, farmland prices have increased on average, 128% in Iowa, reaching a maximum of $8,050 per acre. 5 Graph 1 6 shows the historical changes in farmland prices seen in Iowa, a representative state for the Midwest region where farmland prices have been the most affected. Graph 1. Iowa Farmland Prices 9000 8000 7000 6000 5000 4000 3000 2000 1000 0 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010 2030 Land Price 4 USDA NASS Data 5 USDA NASS Data 6 USDA NASS Data

One of the major differences between previous boom-and-bust cycles and the current boom is the leverage position of the producers. Graph 2 7 shows the evolution of the debt-to-asset ratio overtime. In 1985, the debt-to-asset ratio peaked at 22%. 2015 recorded a sector-wide debt-to-asset ratio of 12%. At face value, this figure indicates a significantly less risky market. Graph 2. Debt-to-Asset Ratio 0.250 0.230 0.210 0.190 0.170 0.150 0.130 0.110 0.090 0.070 0.050 1950.00 1960.00 1970.00 1980.00 1990.00 2000.00 2010.00 2020.00 Debt-to-Asset Ratio Yet, in previous cycles, debt accumulation continues following signals of downturns in the sector. As seen in Graph 3, capital expenditures tend to continue to increase following repeated decreases in net farm income. Previous busts in the agriculture sector have largely been fueled by the producers inability to support their over-leveraged position with cash flow. Yet as the graph shows, as sources of cash flow diminish, the market continues to increase their debt. There are two sides to the debt accumulation of the market. Firstly, the producer is willingly 7 USDA NASS Data

adding risk to their financial position by continuing to expand their debt positions. On the other hand, lenders are also allowing and possibly encouraging the risky behavior of the borrowers. 140000 120000 100000 80000 60000 40000 20000 Graph 3. Net Farm Income and Capital Expenditures 0 0 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 60000 50000 40000 30000 20000 10000 Net farm income Capital Expenditures This paper will serve to model capital expenditures as a way to better understand changes in the risk positions of the market participants and assess whether the credit market is outpacing the borrowers ability to repay. Background In 2013, Henderson and Kauffman of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City wrote a paper, Farm Investment and Leverage Cycles: Will This Time Be Different? addressing a pattern that has arisen in the past three expansion and contraction periods. The three periods addressed are 1910-1940, 1940-1960 and 1970-1980. The progression of events begins with an expansion in profits, caused by varying factors related usually to increases in trade, exports and prices

received. As cash flow increases, producers decrease their leveraged positions and the debt-toasset decreases. As less cash flow is required for debt services, the wealth of farmers increases. Following the increase in wealth, capital expenditures increase. A downturn in the agriculture economy causes profits to decrease, reducing their cash flow to cover the debt positions created from the capital expansion yet capital expansion tends to continue to grow. Finally, farm operators are forced to expand or restructure their debt positions to manage their inability to service their debt positions. 8 1910-1940 The 1910 s were already experiencing increases in food demand. As World War I occurred, demand for US agricultural exports doubled. As a result, crop and livestock prices also increased causing large upward movements in profits for the US agriculture sector. 9 This time period was also a time of mechanization of farming. Producers were adopting the use of tractors and other farm machinery equipment leading to surges in the level of yield produced. In 1917, farm spending on vehicles, machinery and equipment increased 33% and continued to expand through the decade. 10 By 1921, exports had decreased and the onset of a recession suppressed prices and profits. Real net returns to operators decreased 53% therefore as a way to provide liquidity to their operations, farmers expanded and restructured their debt positions. By 1923 farm bankruptcies began to increase. Following the initial recessionary period, the onset of the Depression in the 1930 s caused farm profits to collapse again, creating another series of farm bankruptcies. 11 8 Henderson and Kauffman, 2013, Farm Investment and Leverage Cycles: Will This Time Be Different? 9 Henderson and Kauffman, 2013, Farm Investment and Leverage Cycles: Will This Time Be Different? 10 Henderson and Kauffman, 2013, Farm Investment and Leverage Cycles: Will This Time Be Different? 11 Henderson and Kauffman, 2013, Farm Investment and Leverage Cycles: Will This Time Be Different?

1940-1960 As for the economy, overall, World War II spurred an increase in prices and demand for US agricultural exports and brought the sector out of the recession it had been in. Net farm income for the sector more than doubled from 1940 to 1943. 12 Following the increase in income, capital expenditures from 1943 to 1949 increase more than 3 times. 13 By 1947 non-real estate investment increased by 73%. 14 From 1950 to 1956, profits were suppressed and debt was expanded to finance previous capital expenditures. Between 1950 and 1960, average farm debt rose close to 10% each year for both real estate and non-real estate transactions. 15 Debt levels, overall, remained below historical averages and therefore, the sector avoided a bust following the expansion in the 1940 s. 16 1970-1980 The boom in the 1970 s was largely a result of an increase in exports and prices following a trade agreement with the Soviet Union in 1972. The year following the trade deal, U.S. agricultural exports and net farm income nearly doubled. 17 Profits returned to near previous levels following that initial spike in returns but remained 44% higher than the previous decade. 18 The substantial increase in profits caused an expansion in both non-real estate investments and land improvements. Capital spending began to rise faster than incomes increasing debt levels by about 5% per year. The substantial leveraged positions and decreases in farm profits lead to the development of the second financial crisis. 12 USDA NASS Data 13 USDA NASS Data 14 Henderson and Kauffman, 2013, Farm Investment and Leverage Cycles: Will This Time Be Different? 15 Henderson and Kauffman, 2013, Farm Investment and Leverage Cycles: Will This Time Be Different? 16 Henderson and Kauffman, 2013, Farm Investment and Leverage Cycles: Will This Time Be Different? 17 USDA NASS Data 18 USDA NASS Data

In the beginning of 1980, farm exports and price declines lead to a collapse in farm profits. Net farm income decreased from about $67 billion to $36 billion in 1980. All capital expansion was halted to minimize the accumulation of more debt but the over-leveraged positions of the market had already been realized. The sector witnessed another decrease in profit in 1983 to $26.5 billion. The massive decline in cash flow coupled with increasing interest rates made servicing debt even more difficult for farmers. By the mid-1980 s the sector witnessed 2.3 bankruptcies per 1000 farms and 30 bank closings on average, per year. Between 1985 and 1988, debt per farm decreased 10% annually as lenders wrote off existing debt. 19 The crashing of the sector reverberated throughout the agriculture sector causing massive declines for all including local economies and input suppliers such as John Deere. Today Exports and prices rebounded in the 1990 s and early 2000 s from the bust of the 1970 s and 1980 s bubble. This recent boom saw two major drivers of demand exports and biofuels. International demand has been supported by growing populations and rising incomes in developing countries such as China. In 2011, China was 20% of U.S. exports. 20 Secondly, the demand garnered from The Renewable Fuel Standard established in 2005 has driven demand for grains and oilseed domestically. Crop prices have also been increasing reaching all-time highs in 2012. Corn reached its highest price in 2012 at $6.92. In 1999, the price of corn was $1.72. Soybeans increased from $4.35 to $14.40 from 2001 to 2012. Wheat was $2.15 in 2000 and increased to $7 in 2012. Net farm income reached a peak of $116 billion in 2013, an increase of 60% from 2002 levels. The market is saturated with product and as a result, beginning in 2014, 19 Henderson and Kauffman, 2013, Farm Investment and Leverage Cycles: Will This Time Be Different? 20 Henderson, Gloy and Boehlje, 2011, Agriculture s Boom and Bust Cycles: Is This Time Different?

prices have started to decline. Corn, soybean and wheat prices are currently at $3.50, $8.65 and $3.70, respectively. Additionally, net farm income has declined for the third year in a row. One of the primary differences constantly noted in this time period from others, is the lack of debt accumulation and the over-leveraged positions of the entire agriculture sector. In the early part of the decade, 2000-2005, debt levels remained stable and accumulation was minimal. During that time, the average debt accumulation year over year was about 1.5%. In 2007 and 2008, debt levels increased 9% and 6%, respectively. Recently, debt levels have seen larger percentage increases. In 2013 and 2014, debt increased 4.5% and 8%, respectively. The average debt-to-asset ratio has also remained around 12% with a maximum for the decade being in 2002 at 15%. While these lower levels of the debt ratio prove promising, previous cycles have shown that capital expenditures increase well past decreases in net farm income which have just begun. If this cycle is consistent with past ones, the debt accumulation stage may just be beginning. Data Data used are largely from the USDA Economic Research Service (ERS), Farm Income and Wealth Statistics (FIWS) and the USDA National Agricultural Statistics Service (NASS). The FIWS data source accumulates data observations on income and balance sheet measure for individual states and the United States as a whole. Data is collected and released in February, August and November. Historical data included is annual and spans from 1974 to 2015. All values are deflated using the same method implemented by USDA NASS. The deflator is the GDP chain-type price index published by FRED. All data is deflated to comparable 2009 levels.

Several data were used for the development of the regressions used. Capital expenditures (CE) and the return on investments (ROI) were obtained from the USDA FIWS. The regression estimations were divided into four measures of CE: real estate CE, non-real estate CE, CE on tractors and CE on machinery and equipment. The various CE measures are from the Gross Capital Expenditure data release. The FIWS data series provides a breakdown of each of these expenditure measures. Real estate capital expenditures include expenditures on buildings, land improvements and include operator dwellings. Non-real estate CE includes those on vehicles, tractors, machinery and equipment. The return to investment explanatory variable is calculated as revenue divided by total operating cost plus capital consumption. The revenue value is obtained from the Return to Operator data from the USDA FIWS data file identified as Gross Receipts of Farms. The total operating costs is available as Farm Production Expenses from the same source and includes capital consumption value. Methodologies Five models were developed to explain changes in capital expenditures. CE were broken down into real estate and non-real estate transactions. Further, non-real estate transactions were separated into expenditures on tractors, and expenditures on machinery and equipment. Two explanatory variables were used in each equation. Total ROI was included in every equation as an indicator of expected return to the investment in the varying capital expansions. Additionally, the lagged value of the CE associated with each dependent variable was also included as an explanatory variable. Initially, an ordinary least squares regression was used to estimate the

relationship between the total real estate, total non-real estate, tractor, and machinery and equipment variables and the independent variables: CE #$%&' )*&' +,%&%*,% = f(roi %, CE %$%&' )+,%45 ) CE #$%&' 7$84)*&' +,%&%*,% = f(roi %, CE #$%&' 7$84)+,%45 ) CE #9&:%$9,,% = f(roi %, CE #9&:%$9,,%45 ) CE ;&:<=8*9> & +@A=BC*8%,% = f(roi %, CE ;&:<=8*9> & +@A=BC*8%,%45 ) In addition, a seemingly unrelated regression equation was also run to determine if more information would be gained if it was assumed that the errors of the equations were contemporaneously correlated. Intuitively, it is likely that these equations errors would have some correlation. Following all estimations, several tests were implemented to ensure the robustness of each regression. The Bruesch-Godfrey test was used to test for serial correlation, White s general test for heteroscedasticity was used and the variance inflation factor was calculated to determine the existence of multicollinearity between exogenous variables. All tests show no signs of time-series related issues for any of the final regressions. Two years of ex-post forecasts were estimated for each dependent variable. The insample forecast period for calibrating the models were from 1975 to 2013. The CE measures were forecasted for the years 2014 and 2015. Two forecast evaluation measures were considered to evaluate the strength of the model and its ability to forecast the out-of-sample observations of the forecast objects. These evaluations primarily measure the ability capture magnitude changes. Both measures weight the forecast observations equally and the objective of each calculation is to minimize the outputs.

The root mean squared error (RMSE) is the average unit amount the forecast is incorrect over the entire forecast period. The equation for calculating the RMSE is as follows: ; RMSE = 1 M (F % A % ) J %K5 where M is the number of periods included in the forecast; F t is the forecasted value and A t is the actual value. 5 J The second measure of forecast accuracy is the mean absolute percent error (MAPE) which is the average percentage error the out-of-sample forecast is from the actual observed values or the average percent that the forecast is incorrect. The following equation is used to calculate the MAPE of a forecasted series: MAPE = 1 M ; %K5 F % A % A % 100 Empirical Results The regression results proved promising in terms of statistical significance as well as each model s ability to capture the dependent variables variation. The Table 1 shows the results for the in-sample OLS and SUR models.

Table 1. Adjusted R 2 ROI Lagged Dependent Variable Total Real Estate Capital Expenditures 0.85 8,708,679 (0.029) 0.979 (0.000) OLS Total Non-Real Estate Capital Expenditures Capital Expenditures on Tractors 0.81 0.80 20,400,000 (0.009) 5,147,986 (0.044) 0.969 (0.000) 0.936 (0.000) Capital Expenditures on Machinery & Equipment 0.85 13,000,000 (0.003) 1.002 (0.000) Total Real Estate Capital Expenditures 0.85 6,894,255 (0.055) 0.917 (0.000) SUR Total Non-Real Estate Capital Expenditures Capital Expenditures on Tractors 0.82 0.81 17,500,000 (0.009) 4,738,772 (0.040) 0.918 (0.000) 0.899 (0.000) Capital Expenditures on Machinery & Equipment 0.86 10,040,000 (0.004) 0.918 (0.000) *Numbers in parenthesis are the p-values associated with each coefficient. In all models, the adjusted r-squares are greater than 0.80 meaning the models explain at least 80% of the variation in the dependent variables. Additionally, all variables except for the ROI measure in the SUR modeling of the total real estate CE model were significant at the 5% level and most were significant at the 1% level. The SUR model, overall, performed better in terms of the adjusted R 2. The signs of the coefficients are also as expected. As an investment becomes more profitable, or as the ROI increases, it is expected that the amount invested will

increase. Therefore, the positive coefficients associated with ROI are as expected. Additionally, it is expected that the capital expenditure in time (t 1) have some effect on the capital expenditure in the next time period. As seen from the results, this is the case with the positive and near one coefficient associated with the lagged dependent variables. The forecasts each model yielded were also promising in terms of the forecast evaluations used to measure the models ability to forecast the changes in magnitude. Table 2 shows the RMSE and MAPE of each forecast. In all cases except forecasting CE for tractors, the SUR model outperformed the individual OLS estimations. All MAPEs were less than 24% meaning that the models, on average, were incorrect by less than 24%. The MAPEs associated with the total real estate CE were the lowest at 11.51% and 11.31% for the OLS and SUR models, respectively. This is intuitively straight forward as these two variables have far less variation than the CE on non-real estate assets.

Table 2. RMSE MAPE OLS SUR Total Real Estate Capital Expenditures Total Non-Real Estate Capital Expenditures Capital Expenditures on Tractors Capital Expenditures on Machinery & Equipment Total Real Estate Capital Expenditures Total Non-Real Estate Capital Expenditures Capital Expenditures on Tractors Capital Expenditures on Machinery & Equipment $1,314,248.04 11.51% $5,893,161.89 23.11% $1,743,965.22 18.72% $2,548,531.66 20.12% $1,302,411.80 11.31% $1,666,054.72 18.46% $2,419,511.19 20.10% $5,655,034.40 22.65% Conclusions The timeline of events for the previous boom and bust cycles in agriculture are more alike than different. The series of events show that despite signals from the market that the sector may no longer be in a period of growth, expansion of capital expenditures is not impeded. The risk associated with continued growth in capital expenditures lies in the use of debt to finance these asset purchases. As the markets become tighter, cash flows will diminish and the ability to repay

debt requirements will become more difficult. The other side of this transaction, not developed in this paper, is the behavior and actions of the lenders. It is a question of whether they are not only allowing but encouraging this risky behavior. Future research will focus on better understanding and mapping the behavior of lenders in the expansion of capital expenditures and debt into riskier market periods. The Federal Reserve Banks of Chicago and Kansas City survey regional bankers about current lending conditions and their sentiments towards the future of the market. If it can be shown that they are in fact a driver of this risky behavior, there are policy implications or merely educational options for mitigating risk through focusing the attention of lenders on not only the past performance of a borrower but more importantly on macro factors that will affect the borrower in the future. The additional focus on future performance will hopefully prevent or mitigate crises in the future.

References Alston, Julian M. 1986. An Analysis of Growth of U.S. Farmland Prices, 1963 82. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 63.1: 1-9. Featherstone, Allen M. and Timothy G. Baker. 1987. An Examination of Farm Sector Real Asset Dynamics: 1910-85. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 69.3: 532-546 Henderson, Jason, Brent Gloy, and Michael Boehlje. "Agriculture's boom-bust cycles: is this time different?." Economic Review-Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City (2011): 83. Henderson, Jason, and Nathan Kauffman. "Farm investment and leverage cycles: will this time be different?." Economic Review-Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City (2013): 89. Penson, John B., Dean W. Hughes, and Glenn L. Nelson. "Measurement of capacity depreciation based on engineering data." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 59.2 (1977): 321-329. Penson, John B., Robert FJ Romain, and Dean W. Hughes. "Net investment in farm tractors: an econometric analysis." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63.4 (1981): 629-635.