Capital Allocation Principles

Similar documents
Lecture 3 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia.

Lecture 1 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia.

Optimal capital allocation principles

Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments

Chapter 3 Common Families of Distributions. Definition 3.4.1: A family of pmfs or pdfs is called exponential family if it can be expressed as

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

An application of capital allocation principles to operational risk

SOLVENCY AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION

Capital allocation: a guided tour

Two hours. To be supplied by the Examinations Office: Mathematical Formula Tables and Statistical Tables THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER

Mathematics in Finance

Conditional Value-at-Risk: Theory and Applications

Lecture 4 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia.

Lecture 7: Computation of Greeks

The mean-risk portfolio optimization model

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory

Pricing and risk of financial products

Economic capital allocation derived from risk measures

Lecture 10: Performance measures

Pareto-optimal reinsurance arrangements under general model settings

Financial Risk Management

Risk measures: Yet another search of a holy grail

Lecture 10: Point Estimation

A new approach for valuing a portfolio of illiquid assets

Financial Risk Forecasting Chapter 4 Risk Measures

Risk, Coherency and Cooperative Game

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2011, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam.

Capital requirements, risk measures and comonotonicity

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers

The Use of the Tukey s g h family of distributions to Calculate Value at Risk and Conditional Value at Risk

Study Guide on Non-tail Risk Measures for CAS Exam 7 G. Stolyarov II 1

Conditional Value-at-Risk, Spectral Risk Measures and (Non-)Diversification in Portfolio Selection Problems A Comparison with Mean-Variance Analysis

Risk Measurement in Credit Portfolio Models

Definition 9.1 A point estimate is any function T (X 1,..., X n ) of a random sample. We often write an estimator of the parameter θ as ˆθ.

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO. Please make sure that your copy of the problem set is complete before you attempt to answer anything.

2.1 Random variable, density function, enumerative density function and distribution function

MLEMVD: A R Package for Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Multivariate Diffusion Models

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Risk based capital allocation

Exam STAM Practice Exam #1

Backtesting Expected Shortfall: the design and implementation of different backtests. Lisa Wimmerstedt

STAT/MATH 395 PROBABILITY II

Point Estimation. Stat 4570/5570 Material from Devore s book (Ed 8), and Cengage

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Order book resilience, price manipulations, and the positive portfolio problem

The rth moment of a real-valued random variable X with density f(x) is. x r f(x) dx

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 8

Financial Risk Forecasting Chapter 9 Extreme Value Theory

Portfolio Optimization with Higher Moment Risk Measures

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

EVA Tutorial #1 BLOCK MAXIMA APPROACH IN HYDROLOGIC/CLIMATE APPLICATIONS. Rick Katz

Outline. 1 Introduction. 2 Algorithms. 3 Examples. Algorithm 1 General coordinate minimization framework. 1: Choose x 0 R n and set k 0.

Comparative Analyses of Expected Shortfall and Value-at-Risk (2): Expected Utility Maximization and Tail Risk

Chapter 7: Estimation Sections

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

A generalized coherent risk measure: The firm s perspective

Lecture 22. Survey Sampling: an Overview

Optimal retention for a stop-loss reinsurance with incomplete information

Statistics for Business and Economics

Optimal reinsurance strategies

Robustness of Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) for Measuring Market Risk

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management

Reducing risk by merging counter-monotonic risks

Financial Risk Management and Governance Beyond VaR. Prof. Hugues Pirotte

Version A. Problem 1. Let X be the continuous random variable defined by the following pdf: 1 x/2 when 0 x 2, f(x) = 0 otherwise.

A Convenient Way of Generating Normal Random Variables Using Generalized Exponential Distribution

Modeling of Price. Ximing Wu Texas A&M University

1. You are given the following information about a stationary AR(2) model:

KURTOSIS OF THE LOGISTIC-EXPONENTIAL SURVIVAL DISTRIBUTION

Lecture 6: Risk and uncertainty

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

Optimal reinsurance for variance related premium calculation principles

Measures of Contribution for Portfolio Risk

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers

Much of what appears here comes from ideas presented in the book:

On an optimization problem related to static superreplicating

Portfolio selection with multiple risk measures

Notes on Differential Rents and the Distribution of Earnings

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory

A Multivariate Analysis of Intercompany Loss Triangles

A Comparison Between Skew-logistic and Skew-normal Distributions

EE365: Risk Averse Control

EXCHANGEABILITY HYPOTHESIS AND INITIAL PREMIUM FEASIBILITY IN XL REINSURANCE WITH REINSTATEMENTS

ELEMENTS OF MONTE CARLO SIMULATION

MEASURING PORTFOLIO RISKS USING CONDITIONAL COPULA-AR-GARCH MODEL

Probability and Statistics

Lecture Notes 6. Assume F belongs to a family of distributions, (e.g. F is Normal), indexed by some parameter θ.

Multiproduct Pricing Made Simple

Statistical Methods in Financial Risk Management

Technical Appendix. Lecture 10: Performance measures. Prof. Dr. Svetlozar Rachev

A Computational Study of Modern Approaches to Risk-Averse Stochastic Optimization Using Financial Portfolio Allocation Model.

2 Modeling Credit Risk

Asset Allocation Model with Tail Risk Parity

CSCI 1951-G Optimization Methods in Finance Part 00: Course Logistics Introduction to Finance Optimization Problems

Capital requirements, market, credit, and liquidity risk

Master s in Financial Engineering Foundations of Buy-Side Finance: Quantitative Risk and Portfolio Management. > Teaching > Courses

Outline for today. Stat155 Game Theory Lecture 19: Price of anarchy. Cooperative games. Price of anarchy. Price of anarchy

Transcription:

Capital Allocation Principles Maochao Xu Department of Mathematics Illinois State University mxu2@ilstu.edu

Capital Dhaene, et al., 2011, Journal of Risk and Insurance The level of the capital held by a bank or an insurance company is a key issue for its stakeholders. The regulator, primarily sharing the interests of depositors and policyholders, establishes rules to determine the required capital to be held by the company. The level of this capital is determined such that the company will be able to meet its financial obligations with a high probability as they fall due, even in adverse situations. Rating agencies rely on the level of available capital to assess the financial strength of a company. Shareholders and investors alike are concerned with the risk of their capital investment and the return that it will generate.

Risk measures Artzner et al., 1999, Mathematical Finance Risk measure ρ defined on a probability space (Ω, F, P). A coherent risk measure: 1 Monotonicity X 1 X 2 ρ(x 1 ) ρ(x 2 ); 2 Positive homogeneity ρ(cx) = cρ(x), c 0; 3 Translation invariance ρ(x + c) = ρ(x) + c, c 0; 4 Subadditivity ρ(x + Y ) ρ(x) + ρ(y ).

Capital allocation Assume we have n risks X 1,..., X n. Then, the aggregate loss is S = X i, where this aggregate loss S can be interpreted as: 1 the total loss of a corporate, e.g. an insurance company, with the individual losses corresponding to the losses of the respective business units; 2 the loss from an insurance portfolio, with the individual losses being those arising from the different policies; or 3 the loss suffered by a financial conglomerate, while the different individual losses correspond to the losses suffered by its subsidiaries.

Capital allocation S is the aggregate loss faced by an insurance company and X i the loss of business unit i. Assume that the company has already determined the aggregated level of capital and denote this total risk capital by l: l = l 1 + l 2 +... + l n. What is the optimal allocation strategy?

Allocation formulas Haircut allocation It is a common industry practice, driven by banking and insurance regulations, to measure stand alone losses by a VaR for a given probability level p. Assume that l l i = n j=1 F 1 j (p) F 1 i (p); Quantile allocation-dhaene et al., 2002, IME The comonotonic sum is S c = F 1 i (U), where U is a uniform random variable on (0, 1). Then, l i = F 1 i (F S c(l));

Allocation formulas Covariance allocation-overbeck, 2002 CTE allocation l i = l i = l Var(S) Cov(X i, S); l ( ) CTE p (S) E X i S > F 1 S (p), where ( ) CET p (S) = E S S > F 1 S (p).

Optimal capital allocation Decision criterion: Capital should be allocated such that for each business unit the allocated capital and the loss are sufficiently close to each other. Dhaene, et al. (2011) proposed the following optimization problem to model the capital allocation problem: min l A [ v i E ζ i D ( Xi l i v i )], s.t. l i = l where v i are nonnegative real numbers such that n v i = 1, and the ζ i are non-negative random variables such that E[ζ j ] = 1.

The non-negative real number v j is a measure of exposure or business volume of the j-th unit, such as revenue, insurance premium, etc; The terms D quantify the deviations of the outcomes of the losses X j from their allocated capital K j ; The expectations involve non-negative random variables ζ j with E[ζ j ] = 1 that are used as weight factors to the different possible outcomes D (X i l i ).

Quadratic optimization D(x) = x 2. Consider the following optimization: [ ] (X i l i ) 2 min E ζ i, s.t. l A v i l i = l. Then, the optimal solution is (Dhaene, et al., 2002) l i = E (ζ i X i ) + v i l E(ζ j X j ), i = 1,..., n. j=1

Convex loss function We consider how the different capital allocation strategies affect the loss function under the general setup. Specifically, the loss function is defined as L(l) = φ i (X i l i ), l A for some suitable convex functions φ i, where { } A = (l 1,..., l n ) : l i = l.

Convex loss function We also discuss the the following optimisation problem: or equivalently, min l A P (L(l) t), t 0; min E[Φ (L(l))], l A for some increasing function Φ, which could be interpreted as a utility function.

Stochastic orders Assume random variables X and Y have distribution functions F and G, density functions f and g, respectively. X is said to be smaller than Y in the 1 likelihood ratio order, denoted by X lr Y, if g(x)/f (x) is increasing in x for which the ratio is well defined. 2 usual stochastic order, denoted by X st Y, if F(x) G(x) for all x, or equivalently Eφ(X) Eφ(X) for all increasing function. 3 increasing and convex order, denoted by X icx Y, if Eφ(X) Eφ(X) for all increasing convex function φ.

It is known that in the literature: X lr Y = X st Y = X icx Y. Let x (1) x (2) x (n) be the increasing arrangement of components of the vector x = (x 1, x 2,, x n ). x is said to be majorized by y, denoted by x m y, if j x (i) j y (i) for j = 1,..., n 1, and n x (i) = n y (i).

A real-valued function Φ defined on a set A R n is said to be Schur-concave on A if, for any x, y A, x m y = φ(x) φ(y), and φ is log-concave on A = {x R n : φ(x) > 0} if, for any x, y A and α [0, 1], φ(αx + (1 α)y) [φ(x)] α [φ(y)] 1 α.

Most common univariate parametric densities are log-concave, such as the normal family, all gamma densities with shape parameter 1, all Weibull densities with exponent 1, all beta densities with both parameters 1, the generalized Pareto and the logistic density, see e.g. Bagnoli and Bergstrom (2005). A real function f : R n R is said to be arrangement increasing if for all i and j such that 1 i j n, (x i x j ) [ f (x 1,..., x i,..., x j,..., x n ) f (x 1,..., x j,..., x i,..., x n ) ] 0.

Log-concave Lemma (Prékopa, 1973; Eaton, 1982) Suppose that h : R m R k R + is a log-concave function and that g(x) = h(x, z)dz R k is finite for each x R m. Then g is log-concave on R m.

Theorem Let X 1, X 2,..., X n be independent random variables defined on R + with log-concave density function f. If φ i s are convex functions, then, Ex. (l 1,..., l n ) m (l 1,..., l n) φ i (X i l i ) st φ i (X i l i ). (1, 0,..., 0) m (1/2, 1/2,..., 0) m (1/n, 1/n,..., 1/n)

The optimal solution to the following problem [ ] min E φ i (X i l i ), l A is l = (l/n,..., l/n). Examples: 1 Let φ i (x) = k i x 2, then L(D) = D(X i l i ) = k i (X i l i ) 2, where k i could be interpreted as the weights attached to different units which reflect the relative importance of the different risks; 2 Let φ i (x) = k i x, then L(D) = D(X i l i ) = k i X i l i.

What about independent but not necessarily identically distributed random variables? Lemma Let X 1, X 2,..., X n be independent random variables defined on R + with arrangement increasing density function f. If φ is a convex function, then, (l 1,..., l n ) m (l 1,..., l n) implies φ(x i l (i) ) st φ(x i l (n i+1) ).

Lemma If g(x 1, x 2 ) is log-concave on R 2 + and g(x (2), x (1) ) g(x (1), x (2) ) for all (x 1, x 2 ) R 2 +, then (x 1, x 2 ) m (y 1, y 2 ) = g(x (1), x (2) ) g(y (1), y (2) ).

Theorem Let X 1, X 2,..., X n be independent random variables defined on R + with log-concave density functions f 1, f 2,..., f n, respectively. If X 1 lr X 2 lr... lr X n, then, for any convex function φ, (l 1,..., l n ) m (l 1,..., l n) implies φ(x i l (n i+1) ) st φ(x i l i ).

Theorem Let X 1, X 2,..., X n be independent random variables defined on R +. If X 1 lr X 2 lr... lr X n, then, for any convex function φ, (l 1,..., l n ) m (l 1,..., l n) implies φ(x i l (n i+1) ) icx φ(x i l i ).

Assume that l = (l1,..., l n) is a solution to the following problem: [ ( )] min E Φ φ(x i l i ), (1) l A where φ is a convex function, and Φ is an increasing function. Now, we are interested in the structure of l.

Theorem Let X 1, X 2,..., X n be independent random variables defined on R +. If l is a solution to Problem 1, then, for each pair (i, j), X i lr X j = l i l j. Example: Now, consider a portfolio containing m risk classes, and class i contains n i independent and identically distributed risks X i,1,..., X i,ni distributed as X i with gamma density function having parameters (k i, θ), where k i is the shape parameter and θ is the scale parameter. Then the aggregate loss is S = m S i = m n i X i,j. j=1

Hence, the loss function is L(l) = m φ (S i n i l i ), where l i is the capital allocated to each risk X i,j in class i. It is well-known that S i is a gamma random variable with parameters (n i k i, θ). It is easy to check that if k i k j, then X i lr X j. Hence, under the optimal capital allocation scheme, one should have n i k i n j k j = n i l i n j l j.

Optimal allocation of policy limits Assume that a policyholder has a total policy limit l = l 1 +... + l n, which can be allocated arbitrarily among the n risks X 1,..., X n. Then, the total retained loss of the policyholder is (X i l i ) +, where x + = max{x, 0}.

For example, the compensation package of many big companies includes a commonly called Flexible Spending Account Programme", which allows employees to allocate pre-tax dollars toward specific expenses such as healthcare, medical costs or dependent care. This is essentially a form of allocating policy limits.

If we choose φ i (x) = max{x, 0} = x +, which is a convex function, then the loss function becomes L(l) = D(X i l i ) = (X i l i ) +. Hence, the optimal allocation of policy limits becomes minimizing the loss function.

Thank you!