Review for Quiz #2 Revised: October 31, 2015

Similar documents
Fundamentals of Asset Pricing Revised: October 5, 2015

Point Estimation. Stat 4570/5570 Material from Devore s book (Ed 8), and Cengage

MA 1125 Lecture 05 - Measures of Spread. Wednesday, September 6, Objectives: Introduce variance, standard deviation, range.

Chapter 2. An Introduction to Forwards and Options. Question 2.1

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Point Estimation. Some General Concepts of Point Estimation. Example. Estimator quality

Modeling the Real Term Structure

Linear functions Increasing Linear Functions. Decreasing Linear Functions

Binomial Trees. Liuren Wu. Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Options Markets

The Black-Scholes Model

SOLUTION Fama Bliss and Risk Premiums in the Term Structure

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Both the quizzes and exams are closed book. However, For quizzes: Formulas will be provided with quiz papers if there is any need.

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Characterization of the Optimum

A Lower Bound for Calls on Quadratic Variation

Law of Large Numbers, Central Limit Theorem

Problem Set 4 Answers

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Numerical Descriptive Measures. Measures of Center: Mean and Median

Disasters Implied by Equity Index Options

Chapter 12 Module 6. AMIS 310 Foundations of Accounting

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets

Option Properties Liuren Wu

Predicting the Market

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

The Black-Scholes Model

Deriving the Black-Scholes Equation and Basic Mathematical Finance

Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Distributions B

Edgeworth Binomial Trees

Exchange Rate Fluctuations Revised: January 7, 2012

Final Exam YOUR NAME:. Your mail folder location (Economics, Booth PhD/MBA mailfolders, elsewhere)

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

How Do You Calculate Cash Flow in Real Life for a Real Company?

Chapter 6. y y. Standardizing with z-scores. Standardizing with z-scores (cont.)

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

STA Module 3B Discrete Random Variables

Problem Set 6. I did this with figure; bar3(reshape(mean(rx),5,5) );ylabel( size ); xlabel( value ); mean mo return %

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Problem Set #2. Intermediate Macroeconomics 101 Due 20/8/12

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

ECON Micro Foundations

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

Probability. An intro for calculus students P= Figure 1: A normal integral

Black Scholes Equation Luc Ashwin and Calum Keeley

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS

Interest Rates: Credit Cards and Annuities

Information Processing and Limited Liability

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

STA Rev. F Learning Objectives. What is a Random Variable? Module 5 Discrete Random Variables

Risk-neutral Binomial Option Valuation

Normal Model (Part 1)

ECO155L19.doc 1 OKAY SO WHAT WE WANT TO DO IS WE WANT TO DISTINGUISH BETWEEN NOMINAL AND REAL GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT. WE SORT OF

ELEMENTS OF MONTE CARLO SIMULATION

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

One-Period Valuation Theory

Some Characteristics of Data

5.7 Probability Distributions and Variance

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

October An Equilibrium of the First Price Sealed Bid Auction for an Arbitrary Distribution.

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

10/1/2012. PSY 511: Advanced Statistics for Psychological and Behavioral Research 1

Valuation of Asian Option. Qi An Jingjing Guo

Random Variables and Probability Distributions

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

Binomial Probabilities The actual probability that P ( X k ) the formula n P X k p p. = for any k in the range {0, 1, 2,, n} is given by. n n!

Module 3: Factor Models

[Image of Investments: Analysis and Behavior textbook]

18. Forwards and Futures

Basic Procedure for Histograms

The Two-Sample Independent Sample t Test

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Derivative Securities

CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II. Derivatives and Risk Management By Rajiv Srivastava. Copyright Oxford University Press

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices

Solutions for practice questions: Chapter 15, Probability Distributions If you find any errors, please let me know at

Lecture 11: The Demand for Money and the Price Level

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

Elementary Statistics Triola, Elementary Statistics 11/e Unit 14 The Confidence Interval for Means, σ Unknown

******************************* The multi-period binomial model generalizes the single-period binomial model we considered in Section 2.

Probability Weighted Moments. Andrew Smith

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Quality Digest Daily, March 2, 2015 Manuscript 279. Probability Limits. A long standing controversy. Donald J. Wheeler

X ln( +1 ) +1 [0 ] Γ( )

19. CONFIDENCE INTERVALS FOR THE MEAN; KNOWN VARIANCE

Implied Volatility Surface

Government Debt and Deficits Revised: March 24, 2009

FX Smile Modelling. 9 September September 9, 2008

A Continuous-Time Asset Pricing Model with Habits and Durability

Econ 551 Government Finance: Revenues Winter 2018

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Transcription:

ECON-UB 233 Dave Backus @ NYU Review for Quiz #2 Revised: October 31, 2015 I ll focus again on the big picture to give you a sense of what we ve done and how it fits together. For each topic/result/concept, I recommend you construct a numerical example or two to remind yourself how it works. 1 Asset pricing: summary This is fundamental, worth repeating. The no-arbitrage theorem tells us that we can price assets using state prices: break an asset s payoff into state-contingent pieces, multiply each one by its state price, and add them up. That turns states and state prices from hopelessly abstract objects into objects with practical value. The no-abritrage theorem says: Consider a collection of assets j with prices q j that pay dividends d j (z) in state z. If there are no arbitrage opportunities in this collection of assets, then there are positive state prices Q(z) that price the assets: q j = z Q(z)d j (z) (1) for all assets j. There are two versions of this wonderful result that are more commonly used: same result, different notation. The first is based on a pricing kernel m, defined implicitly by Q(z) = p(z)m(z). (Solve for m if you like.) The pricing relation (1) becomes q j = z p(z)m(z)d j (z) = E(md j ) (2) or, if we divide by q j, 1 = E(mr j ). From this, we can show that risk premiums stem from covariances of returns with m. [Can you show this?] There s also has a nice link to representative agent models, where m is the agent s marginal rate of substitution. The second version is based on risk-neutral probabilities p, defined implicitly by Q(z) = p(z)m(z) = q 1 p (z). Here q 1 = z p(z)m(z) = E(m) is the price of a one-period riskfree bond. The pricing relation (1) now turns into q j = q 1 z p (z)d j (z) = q 1 E (d j ), (3)

where E means the expectation computed from the risk-neutral probabilities. Once we know p, it s a little simpler because we only need the expectation of d j, not the expectation of the product md j. The reason, of course, is that the product is built into p. This version is useful in pricing derivatives, because the risk-neutral distribution is the same for all of them. The generality of the no-arbitrage theorem is both a strength and a weakness. It s a strength because it requires so little: frictionless markets in which all of the arbitrage opportunities have been driven out. It s a weakness because it tells us so little about the state prices: they re positive numbers that exist. It s a standard issue with mysterious existence results in mathematics. That s led to two different approaches in applied work. In macroeconomics, we try to come up with a theoretical basis for the pricing kernel. A representative agent model is a familiar example. In finance, the goal instead is to treat m or p as a statistical object, and choose models that fit some feature of the data reasonably well. We ll see this in action when we value options (shortly) and bonds (later on). The two approaches are complementary, in my view; they give us different insights into the behavior of asset prices and returns. 2 Properties of pricing kernels Here are three applications of the pricing kernel. The first is to representative agent models, which provide a source of insight into which assets have the highest expected returns. The other two relate risk premiums to the dispersion of the pricing kernel. Application 1: representative agent. Here the pricing kernel m is the marginal rate of substitution of a representative agent. If g(z) is the growth rate of consumption and the agent has power utility, the pricing kernel is m(z) = βg(z) α. The classic example here is the equity premium. Define equity as a claim to a dividend tied to the same growth rate, such as d(z) = g(z) λ. If we choose a distribution for g and reasonable values for parameters, the question is whether a model of this sort can generate an equity premium similar to what we observe. The answer is, basically, no. We saw that for returns measured in levels, returns in logs, a two-state distribution, a lognormal distribution, and some others. Unless we have a very large value of α, we don t have a chance. One mechanism that made modest progress was to have strong negative skewness in (log) consumption growth, which tends to increase risk premiums. Application 2: HJ bound. The question is where we went wrong. The Hansen-Jagannathan bound suggests that a power utility pricing kernel doesn t have much of a chance to start with. We start with the Sharpe ratio, the ratio of the mean of an excess return to its standard deviation. If we look at returns on lots of assets, the idea is to look for the asset with the largest Sharpe ratio. Hansen and Jagannathan show that the largest Sharpe ratio places a lower bound on the ratio of the standard deviation of the pricing kernel to its mean: E(x) Std(x) Std(m) E(m). 2

Roughly speaking, large Sharpe ratios imply large standard deviations of the pricing kernel. One way to think about the representative agent model s failure with the equity premium is that it doesn t deliver enough variation in the pricing kernel. Application 3: entropy bound. Similar idea, somewhat different implementation. We define the entropy of the pricing kernel by H(m) = log E(m) E log m. This is a measure of dispersion or variation: it s nonnegative, and strictly positive unless m is constant. The bound here tells us that E log r j log r 1 H(m). The difficulty here with the representative agent model is that it doesn t generate enough entropy in the pricing kernel. One of the nice things about entropy as a measure is that it incorporates things like skewness and excess kurtosis naturally. We can think of the first term in entropy as the cgf of log m evaluated at s = 1: ( log E(m) = log E e log m) = k(1; log m) = κ 1 + κ 2 /2 + κ 3 /3! + κ 4 /4! +. When we subtract the mean, E log m = κ 1, we get entropy: H(m) = log E(m) E log m = κ 2 /2 + κ 3 /3! + κ 4 /4! +. In the lognormal case, only κ 2 is nonzero. Otherwise, the other cumulants play a role. 3 Option pricing We have several components that combine to give us a complete picture. below isn t self-contained, you may need to go back to the notes. The notation Options. Options are the right to buy or sell an asset (the underlying ) at a fixed price k (the strike ) at some future date. We ll label the dates t ( now ) and t + 1 (or t + τ) ( later ). The question is what that right is worth now. We re going to value it using risk-neutral probabilities. Option cash flows. A call option on the future value s t+1 at strike price k generates the cash flow d t+1 = max{0, s t+1 k} = (s t+1 k) +, where the second expression is simply more compact notation for the first. Similarly, put options generate the cash flow s t+1 = (k s t+1 ) +. For a given k, the cash flows are convex in the underlying s t+1. That means, among other things, that option prices are increasing in the uncertainty of the underlying. 3

Put-call parity. For European options, there s a connection between prices of put options (the right to sell) and call options (the right to buy): qt c buy call q p t sell put + q τ t k present value of strike = s t. buy stock This holds for every strike k. It works pretty well in practice, as we saw in Lab Report #6. BSM formula and implied volatility. The standard textbook formula for a call option is q c t = s t N(d) q τ t bn(d τ 1/2 σ) d = log(s t/qt τ k) + τσ 2 /2 τ 1/2. σ Everything is observable here except σ, which we can back out from the price. That is: given σ, we use the formula to compute the price. But if we know the price, we can reverse the process and compute what is commonly referred to as implied volatility: the value of σ for which the formula delivers the observed price. This works because the price is an increasing function of σ. One of the reliable facts about option prices is that volatility varies with the strike. The shape of the line in a graph of volatility against the strike price is referred to as the volatility smile. We ll think of it as a convenient way to summarize option prices. Risk-neutral pricing. We ve seen that any cash flow can be valued using (3). Options are no different. The question is what the risk-neutral distribution is. We need a risk-neutral distribution that prices both the underlying and options on the underlying. Let s be specific. The risk-neutral pricing relation (3) applied to the underlying gives us s t = q 1 t E (s t+1 ). Given a risk-neutral distribution, this gives us s t. Usually we observe s t, and this gives rise to a restriction on the risk-neutral distribution that we call the no-arbitrage condition. The classic example is the lognormal case. Suppose x = log s t+1 N (κ 1, κ 2 ) (remember: this is the risk-neutral distribution). Then the pricing relation implies s t = q 1 t E (e x ) = q 1 t e κ 1+κ 2 /2. Usually we choose κ 1 to satisfy the equation given information about the other components. The logic is the same with other distributions: we evaluate E (e x ) and choose the mean of x to satisfy s t = q 1 t E (e x ). BSM from lognormal risk-neutral underlying. With these ingredients, we can derive the BSM formula using a lognormal risk-neutral distribution of the underlying. A put price is at strike k is q p t = q 1 t E (k e x ) + = q 1 t log k (k e x )(2πκ 2 ) 1/2 exp[ (x κ 1 ) 2 /2κ 2 ]dx t+1. 4

Integrating gives us q p t = qt 1 kn(d) qt 1 e κ 1+κ 2 /2 N(d κ 1/2 2 ) d = (log k κ 1 )/κ 1/2 2. We get the BSM formula for τ = 1 by setting κ 2 = σ 2 and using the no-arbitrage condition to substitute for the mean κ 1. Beyond BSM. It s not hard to get option formulas that differ from BSM: we simply start with a risk-neutral distribution of the underlying that s not lognormal. There are lots of examples. We used normal mixtures, which have some of the analytical convenience of normality but more flexibility. c 2015 David Backus NYU Stern School of Business 5