Download the full paper»

Similar documents
Chapter 2 Executive Summary: More work past age 60 and later claims for Social Security benefits

CAN EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT EXPLAIN THE RISE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION AT OLDER AGES?

The Growing Longevity Gap between Rich and Poor and Its Impact on Redistribution through Social Security

The Growing Longevity Gap between Rich and Poor and Its Impact on Redistribution through Social Security

Income Progress across the American Income Distribution,

IMPACT OF THE GREAT RECESSION ON RETIREMENT TRENDS IN INDUSTRIALIZED COUNTRIES. Gary Burtless and Barry P. Bosworth

The 2008 Statistics on Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage by Gary Burtless THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION

ICI RESEARCH PERSPECTIVE

Redistribution under OASDI: How Much and to Whom?

Removing the Disincentives for Long Careers in Social Security

PREVENTING AGEING UNEQUALLY

WATER SCIENCE AND TECHNOLOGY BOARD

Labor Force Participation Rates by Age and Gender and the Age and Gender Composition of the U.S. Civilian Labor Force and Adult Population

RETIREMENT PLAN COVERAGE AND SAVING TRENDS OF BABY BOOMER COHORTS BY SEX: ANALYSIS OF THE 1989 AND 1998 SCF

Distributional Impact of Social Security Reforms: Summary

The Material Well-Being of the Poor and the Middle Class since 1980

CEPR CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH

The Trend in Lifetime Earnings Inequality and Its Impact on the Distribution of Retirement Income. Barry Bosworth* Gary Burtless Claudia Sahm

Statement of Donald E. Fuerst, MAAA, FSA, FCA, EA Senior Pension Fellow American Academy of Actuaries

Removing the Disincentives for Long Careers in the Social Security and Medicare Benefit Structure

Discussion of The Growing Longevity Gap between Rich and Poor, by Bosworth, Burtless and Gianattasio

Fixing the Payroll Tax and Improving Unemployment Insurance Reserves

Notes Unless otherwise indicated, the years referred to in this report are calendar years. Fiscal years run from October to September 3 and are design

THE RISING AGE AT RETIREMENT IN INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES. Gary Burtless* CRR WP Released: April 2008 Draft Submitted: January 2008

More & More Americans Having to Work Past Age 70

THE EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM ON SAVING, INVESTMENT, AND THE LEVEL AND DISTRIBUTION OF WORKER WELL-BEING. Barry Bosworth* Gary Burtless

Retirement Behavior and the Global Financial Crisis

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

Productivity and Wages

Global Aging and Financial Markets

Why Do Boomers Plan to Work So Long? Gordon B.T. Mermin, Richard W. Johnson, and Dan Murphy

The Economy: Growth Has Been Weak But Long-Lasting

Changing patterns of wealth accumulation and decumulation across cohorts

Prospects for the Social Safety Net for Future Low Income Seniors

POLICY BRIEF Social Security: Experts Discuss Funding Issues and Options

Ready or Not... The Impact of Retirement-Plan Design

REPLACING WAGE INDEXING WITH PRICE INDEXING WOULD RESULT IN DEEP REDUCTIONS OVER TIME IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS

Proportion of income 1 Hispanics may be of any race.

Are you prepared for retirement?

2 TRENDS IN THE DISTRIBUTION OF HOUSEHOLD INCOME BETWEEN 1979 AND 27 Summary Figure 1. Growth in Real After-Tax Income from 1979 to L

Aging Seminar Series:

Enhancing Future Retirement Income through 401 (k)s

MONITORING POVERTY AND SOCIAL EXCLUSION IN SCOTLAND 2015

Fast Facts & Figures About Social Security, 2005

Medicaid Insurance and Redistribution in Old Age

Defining the problem: the difference between current deficit and long-term deficits

Income and Poverty Among Older Americans in 2008

Life expectancy: A statistical measure of the average length of life from birth to death.

shortfalls in perpetuity. 3 The 2003 Trustees report, for example, pushes the insolvency date back by assuming that older

The State of Working Florida 2011

Pension policy where have we been, where are we going?

How Do Lifetime Social Security Benefits and Taxes Differ by Earnings?

Introduction.

THIRD EDITION. ECONOMICS and. MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman Robin Wells. Chapter 18. The Economics of the Welfare State

Testimony before the Equal Employment Opportunity Commission. Heather Boushey, Senior Economist, Center for American Progress Action Fund

Equal pay for breadwinners

Article from. The Actuary. August/September 2015 Volume 12 Issue 4

Gender Pay Differences: Progress Made, but Women Remain Overrepresented Among Low- Wage Workers

If the Economy s so Bad, Why Is the Unemployment Rate so Low?

Incomes and inequality: the last decade and the next parliament

LIFETIME EARNINGS PATTERNS, THE DISTRIBUTION OF FUTURE SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS, AND THE IMPACT OF PENSION REFORM

Widening socioeconomic differences in mortality and the progressivity of public pensions and other programs

Understanding Social Security

It is now commonly accepted that earnings inequality

A REVISED MINIMUM BENEFIT TO BETTER MEET THE ADEQUACY AND EQUITY STANDARDS IN SOCIAL SECURITY. January Executive Summary

The Real Deal 2018 Retirement Income Adequacy Study

Pension Sponsorship and Participation: Summary of Recent Trends

PENSION REFORM IN THE PRESENCE OF FINANCIAL MARKET RISK. Barry Bosworth and Gary Burtless* CRR WP July 2002

NASI Event, Chicago 5 September 2018 Henry J. Aaron

Age, Demographics and Employment

RETIREMENT TRENDS AND POLICIES TO ENCOURAGE WORK AMONG OLDER AMERICANS

The labor market in South Korea,

Lawrence H. Thompson DISTRIBUTING THE GAINS FROM ECONOMIC GROWTH. Brief Series No. 11 August 2000

Understanding Social Security

Social Security Reform and Benefit Adequacy

MINIMUM WAGE INCREASE COULD HELP CLOSE TO HALF A MILLION LOW-WAGE WORKERS Adults, Full-Time Workers Comprise Majority of Those Affected

The Impact of Recent Pension Reforms on Teacher Benefits: A Case Study of California Teachers

AFRICAN AMERICAN PERSPECTIVES ON THE SOCIAL SECURITY SYSTEM 1998 AND 2009

Critical Demographics: Rapid Aging and the Shape of the Future in China, South Korea, and Japan

STATE PENSIONS AND THE WELL-BEING OF

The Impact of Income Distribution on the Length of Retirement

Comment on Gary V. Englehardt and Jonathan Gruber Social Security and the Evolution of Elderly Poverty

Income Inequality is Hurting Arkansas Investments in our people will make it better

THE FINANCIAL SITUATIONS OF OLDER ADULTS

Retirement Annuity and Employment-Based Pension Income, Among Individuals Aged 50 and Over: 2006

Social Security: Is a Key Foundation of Economic Security Working for Women?

HOW EARNINGS AND FINANCIAL RISK AFFECT PRIVATE ACCOUNTS IN SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM PROPOSALS

Table 1 Annual Median Income of Households by Age, Selected Years 1995 to Median Income in 2008 Dollars 1

The Canada We Want in 2020 Reducing Income Disparities and Polarization

Learn about your Social Security benefits. Investor education

Social Security: Raising or Eliminating the Taxable Earnings Base

Gender Retirement Gap

CZECH REPUBLIC. 1. Main characteristics of the pension system

The Hartford partnered with the MIT AgeLab to conduct original research on couples and their financial planning to:

PPI response to the Work and Pensions Committee s inquiry: Understanding the new State Pension

Gender Inequality in US and Japanese Businesses. Akin Can Akdogan Liliya Temes Jieun Yang

Retirement Savings and Household Wealth in 2007

Week Thirty: The Elderly and the Economy

Toshiko Kaneda, PhD Population Reference Bureau (PRB) James Kirby, PhD Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality (AHRQ)

Progress. Economic Performance Under Presidents. Bill Clinton and George W. Bush

Transcription:

Download the full paper» The U.S. Social Security system, which established old age benefits, is designed to be highly progressive by redistributing income from workers with high average lifetime earnings to workers and their dependents who have low lifetime earnings. Under the basic benefit formula, workers that make less over the course of their lifetime will see a higher percentage of their monthly earnings replaced through Social Security benefits than workers with high lifetime earnings. The program is one reason America s senior citizens, when taken as a whole, have fared so well even throughout the Great Recession. While the average income (adjusted for inflation) of households with a head below the age of 65 fell by 4 percent between 2003 and 2013, the income of those with a head 65 and over rose by 15 percent. But new research from Barry Bosworth, Gary Burtless, and Kan Zhang finds evidence that some of the program s progressivity is being offset due to a growing gap in life expectancy between the rich and the poor. That gap, when taken together with the rise in average retirement ages since the early 1990s, means the gap between lifetime benefits received by poor and less educated workers and the benefits received by high-income and well educated workers is widening in favor of the higher income workers.

Why Americans are working longer Labor for participation rates have been falling slowly for decades. After the early 1990s, however, the pattern reversed for workers over age 60. For older men, the labor force participation rate increased by nearly one-third from 26 percent in 1995 to 35 percent today. Rates for older women have also increased, from 15 percent in 1995 to 25 percent in 2014. So why are Americans working longer? One reason is education. Men and women with more education tend to have higher-paying, usually more-rewarding, jobs that provide greater incentives to continue working. In 1985, 42 percent of 60-74 year-olds had less than a high school diploma. In 2013, only 12 percent did. There are other policy-related reasons, as well. An increase in the age at which workers can claim full benefits from 65 to 66 creates more incentives to delay claiming a pension and possibly to keep working. The shift from private defined-benefit (DB) pension plans to defined-contribution (DC) plans means the longer someone works, the more money they accumulate in their retirement savings accounts, no matter how long they continue working. Then there s health care: the elimination of many employer-funded retiree health plans makes it riskier for workers to leave their jobs if they aren t yet eligible for Medicare. In addition to the fact that more Americans are working longer, there has been a notable shift in the proportion of older Americans continuing to work full time as opposed to part time. Since 1995, the relationship between full and part time work among America s aged has completely reversed.

Americans who earn lower wages retire earlier than those earning high wages But a closer look at who s retiring when shows big differences based on income. Fifty-six percent of men and women in the bottom third of the mid-career income distribution and with a full-retirement age of 66 begin claiming Social Security at or before age 62. Only 13.8 percent delay claiming a pension until they're 66 years old. We know that the longer a person works, the more money they receive from Social Security each month once they start claiming retirement benefits. What this means, then, is that early benefit claiming by low-wage workers when combined with delayed claiming by high-wage workers magnifies the difference in monthly benefit payments received by low- and highwage workers. For retirees with a full retirement age of 66, delaying the age of benefit claiming from age 62 to age 70 increases their basic monthly benefit by at least 76 percent. Social Security helps combat rising inequality but what if people retire later?

Income inequality has increased noticeably since 1979, and there are many reasons and theories as to why. One reason is that workers at the bottom of the earnings distribution have seen negligible or even negative changes in their real earnings since 1980, while workers at the top have seen their real earnings climb. Nowhere has the ascent been faster than among the top 1 percent of earners. Because wages and self-employment earnings compose the majority of income for families headed by working-age men and women, inequality among the working age has soared. But what about inequality among families headed by men and women that are older or retired? While rising earnings inequality has contributed to some growth in inequality among the aged (because more lifetime earnings means more savings and bigger pensions), the gap between high- and low-income families headed by seniors hasn t grown as quickly as the gap between other high-and low-income working-age families. How come? Social security and other government transfer benefits. When a birth cohort transitions from ages when labor income provides the bulk of family income to ages when Social Security and pensions provide most family income, families at the bottom of the income distribution see some improvement in their spendable incomes compared with the median family in their age group. The reason is that Social Security provides a floor on retirement income for America's low-income elderly. Delayed retirement, however, has changed things. As more Americans who earn high incomes continue to work longer, the gap between high- and low-income seniors tends to widen, pushing up inequality among America's seniors, although more slowly than has been the case among working-age adults. Evidence of growing gaps in life expectancy Retiring earlier means workers' monthly Social Security checks will be less than if they continued working until full retirement age. But there s another factor at play when we consider how much lifetime income a person receives from Social Security: how long they live. A growing number of studies suggest recent gains in life expectancy have been greater at the top of the income and education distributions than at the bottom. Bosworth, Burtless and Zhang find, for example, that the average life expectancy of man born in 1920 in the top 10 percent of the mid-career income distribution is 79.3 years. The same man in the bottom 10 percent of the distribution has an average life expectancy 5 years lower.

Worse still is that the gap has grown over time. For men born 20 years later in 1940, the difference in average life expectancy is 12 years. The large and growing gap in life expectancy magnifies to an even greater degree the difference in lifetime Social Security benefits provided to low- and high-earnings workers. Even though the formula that determines monthly Social Security pensions is progressive, a growing share of the progressivity is offset on a lifetime basis by the growing difference between the post-retirement life spans of low- and high-wage workers. What growing gaps in life expectancy and emerging retirement trends mean for policy By many economic measures, America s seniors have fared very well over the past several decades. Today s seniors are more educated than their peers in previous generations, and many are working longer because they enjoy their jobs and want to stay in the workforce. When they do retire, America s elderly rich and poor alike have been able to supplement their income with retirement benefits from Social Security and other government transfer programs. As a group, they ve seen their incomes rise over time while the incomes of younger Americans have fallen. They ve also experienced less inequality, which has grown at slower rates among America s elderly than it has for America s younger workers.

Yet new trends are emerging that could lessen the positive effects of Social Security and policymakers should pay attention. While policy changes and other factors have encouraged many Americans to work longer and delay claiming Social Security benefits, the trends toward later retirement and delayed benefit claiming are much weaker among low-wage workers. Earlier retirement means low-income workers receive less money from Social Security each month compared with workers who delay their retirement and benefit application. Furthermore, later retirement by high-wage workers creates more inequality among the aged, as high-wage workers continue to receive big paychecks from their employers while less well paid workers only collect a pension. Finally, the growing gap in life expectancy between low- and high-income workers means that high-wage workers will collect pensions for progressively longer periods, even as low-wage workers see little improvement in life expectancy. These trends deserve scrutiny as policymakers consider how to reform Social Security in order to keep it adequate for retirees and sustainable for future generations. If benefits are trimmed to protect the program's solvency, workers experiencing gains in life expectancy would see cuts to their monthly benefits partially offset by the fact they live longer than previous generations and consequently receive pensions for a longer period. But voters should bear in mind that improvements in life expectancy have been highly unequal, and low-income workers have experienced much smaller gains in life expectancy when compared with workers further up the income scale. For those workers with the lowest lifetime earnings, a cut in monthly benefits results in a loss in lifetime benefits that is proportionately just as severe as the cut in their monthly pension. They will receive lower monthly payments from Social Security when compared with earlier generations of low-wage workers who retired at the same age. And, unlike high-wage workers, the gains in their life expectancy will not compensate them for the cut in their monthly benefit check. Download the full paper by Bosworth, Burtless and Zhang, titled "Later Retirement, Inequality in Old Age, and the Growing Gap in Longevity between Rich and Poor"» About the Authors Barry Bosworth

Barry Bosworth is a senior fellow in Economic Studies and the Robert V. Roosa Chair at the Brookings Institution. A former presidential advisor, Bosworth is an expert on fiscal and monetary policy, economic growth, capital formation, and Social Security. His recent projects include studies of U.S. saving behavior and economic growth in China and India. Gary Burtless Gary Burtless is a senior fellow in Economic Studies and the John C. and Nancy D. Whitehead Chair at the Brookings Institution. Burtless researches labor market policy, income distribution, population aging, social insurance, household saving, and the behavioral effects of taxes and government transfers. He was an economist with the U.S. Department of Labor. Kan Zhang Kan Zhang is a Ph.D. student in Public Policy and Public Administration and a senior research assistant at the George Washington University, and was a senior research assistant at the Brookings Institution. RELATED TOPICS