Deficits and Institutional Theorizing About Households and the State

Similar documents
Policy Note DEBT AND LENDING: A CRI DE COEUR. The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. wynne godley and gennaro zezza

Flows between sectors. Over a given period of time, income flows and spending flows run within each sector and between sectors.

ECO 6183: EXPLORATIONS IN MONETARY ECONOMICS. Course Outline and Reading List

Working Paper No A Note on the Hicksian Concept of Income

Whither IMF Reform? Barry Eichengreen January So too, predictably, is the debate over whether that institution does more to enhance or

GOVERNMENT DEBT RESTRUCTURE PRINCIPLES

Design Failures in the Eurozone. Can they be fixed? Paul De Grauwe London School of Economics

Policy Note. dimitri b. papadimitriou and l. randall wray. Employment and Price Stability. The authors thank Yeva Nersisyan for research assistance.

ABRIEF HISTORY OF MACROECONOMICS NOVEMBER 2, 2011 BUILDING BLOCKS OF MODERN MACRO THEORY. Macro Fundamentals

A(BRIEF AND PARTIAL) HISTORY OF MACROECONOMICS AUGUST 30, 2010 THE BIRTH OF MACROECONOMICS. The Evolution of Macroeconomics: Phase I

Running Head: The Value of Human Life 1. The Value of Human Life William Dare The University of Akron

By! O Wog wja.l~j~j~j 9PHXS Y9PY'

FALLACY OF THE MULTIPLIER EFFECT: CORRECTING THE INCOME ANALYSIS

Public Sector Economics Test Questions Randall Holcombe Fall 2017

SUMMARY OF THE DOCTORAL THESIS PUBLIC DEBT AND SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS

THE PRIVATE AND PUBLIC PENSION SYSTEMS IN RELATION TO SAVING, INVESTMENT AND GROWTH

Chapter 3 Domestic Money Markets, Interest Rates and the Price Level

We Need Chapter 14 And We Need Title II

Payment Economics and the Role of Central Banks Bank of England Payments Conference London, England May 20, 2005

IT S HARD BEING A BEAR (PART SIX) GOOD ALTERNATIVE THEORY?

INTEREST RATES Overview Real vs. Nominal Rate Equilibrium Rates Interest Rate Risk Reinvestment Risk Structure of the Yield Curve Monetary Policy

Fixing Sovereign Debt Restructuring

2006 / 5 THE BURDEN OF AGING: MUCH ADO ABOUT NOTHING, OR LITTLE TO DO ABOUT SOMETHING?

SNEAK PREVIEW: Death of a Theory

SHORT-RUN EQUILIBRIUM GDP AS THE SUM OF THE ECONOMY S MULTIPLIER EFFECTS

Presented at REBELLIOUS MACROECONOMICS: MARX, KEYNES & CROTTY A conference in honor of James Crotty. Marx, Minsky, and Crotty on Crises in Capitalism

FRAMEWORKS FOR SOVEREIGN DEBT RESTRUCTURING

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY

working paper Fiscal Policy, Government Institutions, and Sovereign Creditworthiness By Bernardin Akitoby and Thomas Stratmann No.

Summary of Bankruptcy Reform Conference Report

Defining the problem: the difference between current deficit and long-term deficits

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

1 of 15 12/1/2013 1:28 PM

WHAT ARE MY OPTIONS? An outline of your available debt options MCCAMBRIDGE DUFFY INSOLVENCY PRACTITIONERS

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

ECONOMIC FACTORS ASSOCIATED WITH DELINQUENCY RATES ON CONSUMER INSTALMENT DEBT A. Charlene Sullivan *

Narrowing the Scope of Auditor Duties

Is demand for money the same as demand for liquidity?

9 Right Prices for Interest and Exchange Rates

Policy Note 1999/ Levy Institute Survey of Small Business: An Impending Cash Flow Squeeze? Jamee K. Moudud

Bankruptcy 1. WHAT IS A DISCHARGE IN BANKRUPTCY?

MINISTRY OF EDUCATION AND SCIENCE OF UKRAINE NATIONAL TECHNICAL UNIVERSITY KHARKIV POLYTECHNIC INSTITUTE

Indicators of Insolvency

Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental-Economic Accounting

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman

Money and the Economy CHAPTER

C A S E S I R U I C O U R T S

Texas Christian University. Department of Economics. Working Paper Series. Keynes Chapter Twenty-Two: A System Dynamics Model

Student Loans & Bankruptcy CAASLAR

Objectives of Macroeconomics ECO403

THE ESTATE TAX: MYTHS AND REALITIES

From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

dimitri b. papadimitriou, anwar m. shaikh, claudio h. dos santos, and gennaro zezza

How Much Defense Can We Afford?

Budgeting and Accounting Perspectives

Book review The Philosophy of Debt

As shown in chapter 2, output volatility continues to

Taxing Risk* Narayana Kocherlakota. President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Economic Club of Minnesota. Minneapolis, Minnesota.

The chartalist modern monetary theory and Marx

Remarks by James K. Galbraith at the Economists for Peace and. Security Bernard Schwartz Symposium on Jobs, Investment and Energy.

Deficit Spending and Economic Growth: A Feder Growth Model Approach

EC3115 Monetary Economics

Testimony by. Alan Greenspan. Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. before the. Senate Finance Committee. United States Senate

A key characteristic of financial markets is that they are subject to sudden, convulsive changes.

A Note on the Economic Recovery in the 1930s. 1

Causes of the Trade Deficit. Written Statement of. Barry K. Rogstad, President American Business Conference. The Trade Deficit Review Commission

Structural changes of Romanian economy

James Bullard. 13 January St. Louis, Missouri

10. The interest rate quoted in the financial markets for borrowing and lending transactions is the: A. real interest rate. B. prime lending rate. C.

We Need a Bigger "Deficit" by William Vickrey* Working Paper No. 2. January 2000

Macro Notes: Fiscal Deficits

Suppose you plan to purchase

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

EXHIBIT 7 1 Flow Chart for Chapter 12

ECON. 7500: Advanced Monetary Theory

NEW CONSENSUS MACROECONOMICS AND KEYNESIAN CRITIQUE. Philip Arestis Cambridge Centre for Economic and Public Policy University of Cambridge

17.2 U.S. Government Spending and Revenue Introduction. Chapter 17 The Government and the Macroeconomy. In 2008, federal spending

TWO PRINCIPLES OF DEBT AND NATIONAL INCOME DYNAMICS IN A PURE CREDIT ECONOMY. Jan Toporowski

Discussion of paper: Quantifying the Lasting Harm to the U.S. Economy from the Financial Crisis. By Robert E. Hall

3. Financial Markets, the Demand for Money and Interest Rates

International Finance

Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development

MONETARY POLICY: DOMESTIC TARGETS AND INTERNATIONAL CONSTRAINTS

Treasury Select Committee Inquiry into Credit Rating Agencies Memorandum by the Investment Management Association 1

MEASUREMENT OF MARKET MECHANISM, HOW BIG IS GOVERNMENT?

The Economic Effects of the Estate Tax

The role of public pensions and reform options

International Macroeconomics

Economic Theories & Debt Driven Realities

The economic situation in a wide range of economies in the wake of the crisis that began

Chapter 11: The Effects of General Fluctuations in Wages on the Prices of Production

10. Fiscal Policy and the Government Budget

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Marx s reproduction schemes and the Keynesian multiplier: a reply to Sardoni

Solvency and Affordability in Medicare Testimony for Health Subcommittee, Committee on Energy and Commerce

Needed in the Context of the Renewed Popularity of Keynes s Ideas: An Analysis of his Errors Brian P. Simpson

11/3/2011. Debt & Taxes

1. The real risk-free rate is the increment to purchasing power that the lender earns in order to induce him or her to forego current consumption.

Transcription:

JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC ISSUES Vol. XLI No. 2 June 2007 Deficits and Institutional Theorizing About Households and the State Zdravka Todorova In a pecuniary economy, households spending is limited by the stock of state money and the flow of income received in the form of state money. Thus, households are subject to liquidity constraint as they incur debts in the established unit of account, and consequently need to obtain the widely accepted medium of exchange (Wray 1998; Bell 2001). Even when households borrowing is unlimited, there is liquidity constraint to the extent that various interest rates and fees are administered by banks and business enterprises upon different households. Consequently, households are concerned with sound finance or balancing their budgets at some point (albeit not at all times). The state s spending, on the other hand, is not limited by a stock of money, since the state spends by issuing its own IOU (Knapp 1924). Thus, there is no instrumental reason why a sovereign state should follow sound finance (Lerner 1943; 1947; Wray 1998). The idea that a sovereign government or nation faces financial burden due to federal deficits is based on a state-household budget analogy, according to which, in much the same way a household goes bankrupt if its debt continuously exceeds its income flow, continuous government deficits are also unsustainable. The view of government sound finance holds that there is some prudent government deficitto-gdp ratio in the same fashion that there are sensible household debt-to-earnings ratios that are used in reasonable lending practices. Under such an analogy, in the same manner that households have a time line for repaying their debts (even if they are rolled over) the state eventually will have to face the retirement of government debt. Thus, according to this view continuous government deficits are wasteful and constitute a burden for future generations. The household-state analogy does not differentiate households and the state as distinct institutions with specific characteristics, powers and liabilities. An Institutionalist discussion of this analogy with reference to household and The author is an Assistant Professor in the Department of Economics in the Raj Soin College of Business at Wright State University in Dayton, OH. This paper was prepared for the Annual ASSA/AFEE conference in Chicago, January 2007. 1 2007, Journal of Economic Issues

2 Author government deficits would reveal some questions of importance for theorizing about households and the state as institutions in a pecuniary culture. Government Deficits and Households Financial Positions The state-household deficit analogy is not merely a rhetorical device and an example of fallacy of composition; it is a habit of thought. The analogy enters the process of valuation in policy analysis and formulation, and is engrained in common everyday understanding of public finance and the relation between state and households. The following main issues emerge as a result of the household-state analogy with respect to deficits. First, the special place of the state as a monopoly issuer of money is ignored, which obscures the importance of households place at the bottom of the debt pyramid (Bell 2001). In addition, the way in which the state deficit spends and prints money is misconstrued (Wray 1998; Bell 2000). Furthermore, the householdstate debt analogy obscures the effect of government deficit on the household sector, as well as its role in generating household sector net savings. We are going to focus on the last point. The government budget deficit offsets the private (business and households) sector s surplus. This means that the private sector as a whole can save only when the government runs a deficit. Alternatively, while it is true that one household can spend less than its income, and thus can save, another would have to go in debt. Thus, the government deficit represents private sector saving. The private sector saving equals the sum of the government sector deficits, which equals the outstanding government debt (assuming a balanced foreign sector). In such a case, if the government runs a surplus, the private sector will be deficit spending and reducing its net financial wealth at the aggregate level (although some households may still be able to save) (Wray 2006; Galbraith 2006). Consequently, the household-state analogy that undergirds the doctrine of sound finance results in a paradox. Concerns about sustainability of government debt necessary assume that households can run indefinitely deficits, as balancing the government budget would mean that household wealth decreases. On the other hand, in order for the economy to grow, the household sector must become indebted. Yet, when it is argued that the government should balance its budget just as a prudent household, there is a presumption that households indeed are not indebted. In the case of the U.S. economy, where recent borrowing by the household sector has reached unprecedented levels and debt-service burden has reached record heights, there are warnings that household borrowing relative to income cannot continue indefinitely. Furthermore, these studies show that current economic growth is driven by consumer borrowing, and thus is vulnerable to a decrease in consumer spending (Papadimitriou, Chilcote, and Zezza 2006; Galbraith 2006; Wray 2006). If households are to run indefinitely deficits so that the economy continues to grow, it must be true that households have indefinite access to credit, are not concerned about interest charges, fees, and credit ratings, and thus are willing to continue borrowing. Also, there is an assumption that household consumption expenditure is not going to

Title 3 be affected by the growing indebtedness and deterioration of the financial positions of households, which at present in the U.S. case, is enhanced due to decreasing housing prices (Papadimitriuou, Chilcote, and Zezza 2006). By ignoring the possibility of decreased household sector consumption, the significance of effective demand for the level of output, employment and growth is forgotten. Rather than insolvency of a sovereign state, the major concern in a monetary production economy under such conditions should be the possible negative effect of a growing household financial burden on household consumption expenditures, and consequently on future expectations of business enterprises and banks, and thus on investment and growth. Of course, within this line of reasoning saving is a residual of investment. Consequently, concerns about government deficits crowding-out private investment and absorbing savings are unfounded since investment is not financed by loanable funds, and loans create deposits (Wray 1989; Nell 1996, 100). Indeed, the concerns about a supposed negative economic effect of continuous deficits 1 that undergird sound finance are grounded in the commodity view of money and loanable funds theory of investment. Value Structure and Government Deficits as Tools A pecuniary culture is constituted by institutions that have ceremonial and instrumental aspects, such as households, business enterprises, and the state. Consequently, the culture can be dominated by either ceremonial or instrumental methods of valuation. The household-state analogy, with regards to deficits, is a habit of thought based on ceremonial methods of valuation, and is a part of the value structure of the pecuniary culture. A value structure is a combination of the predominant methods of valuation. Together with tools (skills, practices, and devices), a value structure constitutes a given state of technology. Government deficits can be viewed as tools that permit the economy to function at full employment, as well as to achieve other goals that are in correspondence with the predominant value structure within the culture. Thus, the recognition and application of the principles of functional finance in place of the doctrine of sound finance would constitute a change in the value structure. Consequently, a combination between the tool of government deficit and the principles of functional finance would represent a new state of technology in the broader Institutionalist sense. However, the availability of a tool does not mean that its application is socially acceptable. Only tools that can be reconciled with the existing value structure of the community would be sanctioned for problem-solving purposes. Thus, there is a ceremonial feasibility that is determined by the predominance of ceremonial methods of valuation in the structure of valuation. On the other hand, instrumental feasibility is determined by the tools available to the community. However, only the tools that meet ceremonial adequacy (Bush 1988, 141) will be permissible for usage. Consequently, even though government deficits are available to the community, at the present state of the value structure, they are not accepted as a normal part of the

4 Author growth of the economy, and thus their usage for addressing most problems of livelihood is ceremonially inadequate. Ceremonial adequacy determines the legitimacy of the implementation of specific tools as a part of problem solving. Legitimacy is in terms of conceiving the effectiveness, feasibility, and desirability of the implementation of a specific tool. In other words, ceremonial adequacy determines the conditions of the possibility for implementing the tools available to the community in problem solving. Running government deficits consistent with full employment is technically achievable but is ceremonially inadequate. The interface between tools and the structure of valuation defines the space of institutional change. We can envision the following types of institutional change: ceremonial encapsulation; progressive; and regressive, which represent various permutations of ceremonial (non)feasibility and instrumental (non)feasibility (Bush 1988, 141-142). Progressive change occurs when a change in the value structure in the culture occurs in a manner that ceremonial dominance gives way to instrumental dominance. The opposite is true for regressive change. In the case of ceremonial encapsulation, the value structure does not change, but some innovations are introduced. Ceremonial Encapsulation vs. Progressive Institutional Change Ceremonial encapsulation is a situation where innovation is both ceremonially and instrumentally feasible. A problem-solving tool will be incorporated into the predominant habits of thought to the extent that the community believes that the existing ceremonial aspects of a given institution (e.g. the business enterprise) will not be disrupted. Any disruption from the implementation of new tools for problem solving will be offset by simultaneous reinforcement of the existing myths, which encapsulate the introduction of the instrumentally warranted tools. Thus, variants of gender budgets and green budgets are examples of such quasi-institutional change, since they refer only to the distribution of outlays of a given government expenditures. While these innovations are manifestations of agency, and composition of the government deficit is immensely important, these tools are usually implemented within the existing value structure that embodies the habit of thought of sound finance without questioning the notion of a prudent deficit-to-gdp ratio. Progressive institutional change on the other hand is a process characterized by instrumental feasibility and ceremonial non-feasibility. Progressive institutional change is an enhancement of the application of instrumental methods of valuation. Such change occurs when the community allows for ceremonial inadequacy and implements the habitual use of a tool in problem-solving (Bush 1988, 144). Thus, if we view government deficit as a tool, the implementation of functional finance would be an example of progressive institutional change. 2 On the other hand, the adoption of balanced budget rules would be an example of a regressive institutional change, as it puts forward the application of ceremonial methods of valuation.

Title 5 Regressive Institutional Change Bankruptcy Reform Regressive institutional change exhibits elements of ceremonial feasibility and instrumental non-feasibility. There is an attempt to achieve outcomes that are represented as instrumentally feasible, but in reality are pursued by means of ceremonially warranted methods regressive institutional change (Bush 1988, 148-149). The recent U.S. bankruptcy reform is an example of a regressive institutional change with respect to households financial positions. The reform makes it much more difficult and costly for individuals to file for bankruptcy and requires debtors to try to work out repayment plans through counseling agencies before they go into bankruptcy court. Legislation approved by the House (HR 333 on March 1, 2006 by a vote of 306-108) and Senate (S 420 approved on March 15, 2006 by a vote of 83-15) prevents individuals from using liquidation under Chapter 7 (under which the debtors estate is sold by a court appointed trustee and remaining unpaid debts are discharged) if they have the ability to pay $10,000 or 25 % of their debts, whichever is less, in three to five years following their request for debt relief. The ability to repay debts is determined after individuals have paid attorneys fees, monthly living costs and other miscellaneous expenses approved by a judge. The most cited purpose of the bankruptcy reform is to prevent deadbeats who can pay back their loans to declare bankruptcy. In effect, the reform precludes debtors from liquidating their assets in order to repay some or all of their debts and get a fresh start. While not as harsh as debtor s prison, this bankruptcy reform ensures that debtors keep on working and making payments to their creditors. The effect of the bill is that it secures continuous payments to the financial sector while contributing to the deterioration of the instrumental aspects of financially bankrupt households. Driven by the vested interests of creditors, the bankruptcy reform is not concerned with the underlying causes for indebtedness. 3 The most common reasons for filing for bankruptcy are high medical bills in the household, loss of a job, or a divorce resulting in alimony and child support payments. From the point of view of the highly indebted household, one problem is that in order to secure payments, debtors must work for wages, (usually under conditions below full employment) while at the same time they need to secure access to child-care services. Under these circumstances, the possibility of one person staying in the home and providing childcare may not even be an option, as the major concern of the household becomes of a pecuniary nature. Bankruptcy reform is a regressive institutional change ceremonially feasible and instrumentally infeasible because it secures the pecuniary interests of creditors, and further inhibits the instrumental aspects of households, material provisioning and care. Thus, there is a net loss for the community in terms of instrumental efficiency with respect to the development of human resources. A more general consequence of the reform is the reinforcement of the self-help habit of thought and more specifically the canon and practice that child-rearing, and workers health

6 Author are solely a private responsibility of households, rather then being part of the macroeconomy. Under the absence of accessible child-care and health care, there must be a presumption of an altruistic behavior within the household. This altruism/ labor power, which is supposed to secure the survival of the household as a going concern, then must somehow be immune to financial restrictions. Conclusion: Disembodied Households and a Personified State In accordance with sound financial principles, the government is supposed to balance its budget like a responsible household. At the same time, bankruptcy reform is introduced on the grounds that bankruptcy filings have been steadily increasing, and that there are too many irresponsible individuals/households. The reform is a good example of dealing with symptoms by killing the patient. The problem should be reformulated and the medicine that the indebted household sector needs is a larger federal budget deficit with an adequate composition that addresses the major points of households vulnerability. However, these vulnerabilities are obscured, while unreal problems such as balancing the federal budget and Social Security trust fund solvency are focused on by vested interests. The obsession with sustainability of government deficits ignores the role of net government expenditures in a monetary production economy, and specifically its effect on households financial positions. Implicitly, if balancing the federal budget is the end-in-view in policy formulation if economic growth is to occur, there is a presumption that growing household debt is sustainable. Such an assumption, however, treats the state as an entity with a life span. On the other hand, households are treated as some kind of entities with no biological life span. Within this view, the state in effect, is personified while households are disembodied. First, the notion that a sovereign state eventually has to pay down the debt, and that it can go bankrupt, cannot be logically defended (Wray 1998; Galbraith 2006). Invoking the term bankruptcy when discussing looming government debt is of course legally inaccurate (Galbraith 2006) and can be viewed as an emotional reference to some notion of moral bankruptcy. Such reasoning personifies the state and gives it a kind of biological status: after all, according to the Institutionalist tradition it is inadequate to see morals as separated from body/nature (Dewey [1922] 1983). This embodiment/personification of the state is not without consequences for the political process and ideology. Second, there is a simultaneous disembodiment of households they are viewed as inorganic entities whose financial positions are somehow separate from nature. If households are presumed to run indefinitely deficits, they are treated as if they have an indefinite life span, which means that members of the households do not die, nor are they born or give birth. Consequently, the household-state analogy obscures the biological/social vulnerabilities of households by virtue of disassociating households financial positions from their biological and social character. Thus, an Institutionalist critique of the household-state analogy with regards to deficits brings two major questions with respect to theorizing about households

Title 7 and the state. First, what are the consequences of ignoring the anthropogenic character of households? Second, what is the relevance of a personified notion of the state for ideology and institutional change? The answers to these questions could be developed in the context of existing discussions in these areas (Dugger 1992; Jennings 1992; Eichner 1985; O Hara 2000; Danby 2004). Notes 1. For a more detailed exposition and critique of these arguments, see Lerner 1943; Eisner 1986; Wray 1998; Vickrey 2000; Bougrine 2000; Forstater and Nell 2003; and Shaikh et al. 2003. 2. Another example of a progressive institutional change would be the establishment of the Social Security program. On the other hand, the establishment of a Social Security trust fund is an example of a regressive institutional change, as it puts forward pecuniary methods of valuation and foregoes the instrumental function of the program to assure entitlements to goods and services to anybody in their old age. 3. Banks, credit card companies and credit unions have been leading the drive to rewrite the U.S. bankruptcy laws. In 1998, the American Financial Services Association, the trade group that represents the major credit card companies, joined other financial industry trade associations, Visa and Master Card, to form the National Consumer Bankruptcy Coalition. In addition to the financial sector, the gambling industry, car dealers, and retail stores are those who pushed for consumer bankruptcy reform. Consequently, we have to note that theorizing about the institutions of the household and the state is interwoven with the theory of the business enterprise. Reference Bell, Stephanie. Do Taxes and Bonds Finance Government Spending? Journal of Economic Issues 34, 3 (2000): 603-620.. The Role of the State and the Hierarchy of Money. Cambridge Journal of Economics 25 (May 2001): 149-163. Bush, Paul. The Theory of Institutional Change. In Evolutionary Economics: Foundations of Institutional Thought, Vol. I, edited by Mark Tool. Armonk, NY and London, England: M. E. Sharpe, 1988. Bourgine, Hassan. The Economics of Public Spending: Debts, Deficits and Economic Performance. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 2000. Danby, Colin. Contested States, Transnational Subjects: Toward a Post Keynesianism without Modernity. In Postcolonialism Meets Economics edited by S. Charusheela and Eiman O. Zein- Elabdin, 253-270.New York: Routledge, 2004. Dewey, John. Human Nature and Conduct, The Middle Works. Carbondale and Edwardsville: Southern Illinois University Press, [1922] 1983. Dugger, William. An Evolutionary Theory of the State and the Market. In The Stratified State: Radical Institutionalist Theories of Participation and Duality edited by William Dugger, 87-117. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1992. Eichner, Alfred. Toward a New Economics: Essays in Post-Keynesian and Institutionalist Theory. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1985. Eisner, Robert. How Real is the Federal Deficit? New York: Free Press, Macmillan, 1986. Forstater, Mathew. Functional Finance and Full Employment: Lessons from Lerner for Today. In Reinventing Functional Finance edited by E. J. Nell and M. Forstater. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 2003. Galbraith, James. The Fiscal Facts: Public and Private Debts and the Future of the American Economy. Policy Note. The Levy Economics Institute, January 2006.

8 Author Jennings, Ann. Not the Economy: Feminist Theory, Institutional Change, and the State. In The Stratified State: Radical Institutionalist Theories of Participation and Duality edited by William Dugger 117-153. Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe, 1992. Knapp, George Friedrich. The State Theory of Money. Clifton: Austus M. Kelley, 1924. Lerner, Abba. Functional Finance and the Federal Debt. Social Research 10 (1943): 38-51.. Money as a Creature of the State. American Economic Review 37 (1947): 312-317. Nell, Edward. Making Sense of a Changing Economy: Technology, Markets and Morals. London and New York: Routledge, 1996. O Hara, Phillip. Marx, Veblen, and Contemporary Institutional Political Economy: Principles and Unstable Dynamics of Capitalism. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 2000. Papadimitriou, Dimitri; Edward Chilcote; Gennaro Zezza. Are Housing Prices, Household Debt, and Growth Sustainable? Strategic Analysis. Levy Economics Institute, January 2006. Shaikh, Anwar, Dimitri Papadimitriou, Claudio Dos Santos, and Gennaro Zezza. Deficits, Debts, and Growth: A Reprieve but Not a Pardon. Strategic Analysis. Levy Economics Institute, October 2003. Vickrey, William. Fifteen Fatal Fallacies of Financial Fundamentalism: A Disquisition on Demand Side Economics. In Commitment to Full Employment edited by Mathew Forstater, Sumner Rosen and Aaron Warner. White Plains, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, 2000. Wray, L. Randall. A Keynesian Presentation of the Relations Among Government Deficits, Investment, Saving, and Growth. Journal of Economic Issues 23, 4 (1989): 977-1002.. Understanding Modern Money: The Key to Full Employment and Price Stability. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton MA: Edward Elgar, 1998.. Twin Deficits and Sustainability. Policy Note. Levy Economics Institute, April 2006.