Nonlinearities and Robustness in Growth Regressions Jenny Minier

Similar documents
Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis

Stock Market Anomalies and Model Uncertainty

The Short and Long-Run Implications of Budget Deficit on Economic Growth in Nigeria ( )

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

Inflation, Inflation Uncertainty, Political Stability, and Economic Growth

THE EFFECTIVENESS OF COMPETITION LAW IN PROMOTING ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Economic Growth and Financial Liberalization

h Edition Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

Government Consumption Spending Inhibits Economic Growth in the OECD Countries

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

Is Higher Volatility Associated with Lower Growth? Intranational Evidence from South Korea

Online Appendix (Not For Publication)

MBF1923 Econometrics Prepared by Dr Khairul Anuar

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

Summary of: Trade Liberalization, Profitability, and Financial Leverage

Macroeconomic Policy: Evidence from Growth Laffer Curve for Sri Lanka. Sujith P. Jayasooriya, Ch.E. (USA) Innovation4Development Consultants

Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta

Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK. Seraina C.

The Determinants of Capital Structure: Analysis of Non Financial Firms Listed in Karachi Stock Exchange in Pakistan

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

Social Security and Saving: A Comment

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth?

THE DETERMINANTS OF SECTORAL INWARD FDI PERFORMANCE INDEX IN OECD COUNTRIES

Regional convergence in Spain:

FDI and economic growth: new evidence on the role of financial markets

Taxes, Government Expenditures, and State Economic Growth: The Role of Nonlinearities

Econometrics and Economic Data

The Impacts of State Tax Structure: A Panel Analysis

The data definition file provided by the authors is reproduced below: Obs: 1500 home sales in Stockton, CA from Oct 1, 1996 to Nov 30, 1998

Acemoglu, et al (2008) cast doubt on the robustness of the cross-country empirical relationship between income and democracy. They demonstrate that

Wage Gap Estimation with Proxies and Nonresponse

A Closer Look at High-Frequency Data and Volatility Forecasting in a HAR Framework 1

PERUVIAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION. From Inflation Targeting to achieving. Economic Growth

Deep Determinants. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () Deep Determinants 1 / 65

Conditional Convergence: Evidence from the Solow Growth Model

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

Do Value-added Real Estate Investments Add Value? * September 1, Abstract

A Regression Tree Analysis of Real Interest Rate Regime Changes

Convergence Patterns in Financial Development: Evidence from Club Convergence

Comment on Rodríguez and Rodrick, Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic s Guide to the Cross-National Evidence

Aid Effectiveness: AcomparisonofTiedandUntiedAid

International Journal of Advance Research in Computer Science and Management Studies

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom

FISCAL CONSOLIDATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN. Ahmed Waqar Qasim Muhammad Ali Kemal Omer Siddique

The Effect of the Internet on Economic Growth: Evidence from Cross-Country Panel Data

The persistence of regional unemployment: evidence from China

13034, Liberal Arts Building, PO Box 3323, Kuwait b School of Economics, Finance and Marketing, RMIT, 239 Bourke Street, Melbourne, Victoria

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

Time Invariant and Time Varying Inefficiency: Airlines Panel Data

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

Impact of Stock Market, Trade and Bank on Economic Growth for Latin American Countries: An Econometrics Approach

Equality and Fertility: Evidence from China

Capital structure and profitability of firms in the corporate sector of Pakistan

THE BEHAVIOUR OF GOVERNMENT OF CANADA REAL RETURN BOND RETURNS: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY

Growth, Convergence and Public Investment A Bayesian Model Averaging Approach

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004

CEPAL FISCAL POLICY SEMINAR Blanca Moreno Dodson World Bank

The Effect of Exchange Rate Risk on Stock Returns in Kenya s Listed Financial Institutions

An Evaluation of the Relationship Between Private and Public R&D Funds with Consideration of Level of Government

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

The Vasicek adjustment to beta estimates in the Capital Asset Pricing Model

The Decreasing Trend in Cash Effective Tax Rates. Alexander Edwards Rotman School of Management University of Toronto

I JUST RAN FOUR MILLION REGRESSIONS. Xavier X. Sala-i-Martin. Columbia University. and. Universitat Pompeu Fabra. January 17, 1997.

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index

Moderate Inflation and the Deflation-Depression Link

DOES MONEY GRANGER CAUSE INFLATION IN THE EURO AREA?*

Cross- Country Effects of Inflation on National Savings

Population Aging, Economic Growth, and the. Importance of Capital

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports *

Any Willing Provider Legislation: A Cost Driver?

An Analysis of the Effect of State Aid Transfers on Local Government Expenditures

Omitted Variables Bias in Regime-Switching Models with Slope-Constrained Estimators: Evidence from Monte Carlo Simulations

THE EFFECTS OF THE EU BUDGET ON ECONOMIC CONVERGENCE

Fiscal Divergence and Business Cycle Synchronization: Irresponsibility is Idiosyncratic. Zsolt Darvas, Andrew K. Rose and György Szapáry

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

Working Paper No. 2032

Regions: Sub-Saharan Africa

The relationship amongst public debt and economic growth in developing country case of Tunisia

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

Impact of Weekdays on the Return Rate of Stock Price Index: Evidence from the Stock Exchange of Thailand

Dan Breznitz Munk School of Global Affairs, University of Toronto, 1 Devonshire Place, Toronto, Ontario M5S 3K7 CANADA

Statistical Evidence and Inference

Military Expenditures, External Threats and Economic Growth. Abstract

Yafu Zhao Department of Economics East Carolina University M.S. Research Paper. Abstract

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

Cross Sectional Analysis of Financial Development on Economic Growth. Jeremy Carmack Hari Krishnam Haidan Zhou

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

An Estimated Fiscal Taylor Rule for the Postwar United States. by Christopher Phillip Reicher

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Budgetary Trade-offs Between Social Services, Development Services and Defense* in Jordan

Review of Recent Evaluations of R&D Tax Credits in the UK. Mike King (Seconded from NPL to BEIS)

Board of Director Independence and Financial Leverage in the Absence of Taxes

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

Transcription:

Nonlinearities and Robustness in Growth Regressions Jenny Minier Much economic growth research has been devoted to determining the explanatory variables that explain cross-country variation in growth rates. A frequently cited problem with this literature is that the number of potential growth regressors is vast, potentially exceeding the number of countries available for study. Thus, researchers are faced with the task of arbitrarily specifying which explanatory variables to include in their growth regressions, raising concerns about how confident we can be in their results. These concerns were magnified by the influential paper of Ross Levine and David Renelt (1992), in which they employ a variation of Edward E. Leamer s (1983) extreme bounds analysis to test the robustness of conventional growth regression coefficients to changes in the set of conditioning variables. They conclude that the results of this literature are extremely fragile, with the only robust determinants of growth being physical capital investment, initial income, and secondary school enrollment. In contrast, they demonstrate the fragility of a host of fiscal, monetary, and trade policy variables, as well as measures of political and economic stability and economic distortions. There have been two main responses to their findings. The pessimistic response has been to conclude, given the lack of a reliable statistical relationship between conventional macroeconomic indicators and growth, that cross-country growth regressions cannot tell us anything about growth. The more optimistic response has been to argue that the extreme bounds analysis of Leamer (1983) is excessively stringent, requiring the coefficient estimate of interest to be statistically significant in all specifications. Thus, other researchers have proposed alternative, less stringent, approaches to robustness in the growth context (e.g., Xavier X. Sala-i- Martin (1997) and Gernot Doppelhofer, Ronald I. Miller, and Sala-i-Martin (2004)).

However, a third possible interpretation of the Levine and Renelt (1992, henceforth L-R) results is that the extreme sensitivity of the coefficient estimates is due to unreasonably strict assumptions about the form of the growth regression. In particular, L-R employ the common specification common that explanatory variables enter the growth regression linearly and independently. This reflects an ad hoc assumption that the marginal effect of a change in an explanatory variable is constant, both across different levels of the variable and across different economies. In fact, much of the empirical growth literature documents the existence of multiple growth regimes and parameter heterogeneity (see, among numerous others, Steven N. Durlauf and Paul A. Johnson (1995)). The apparent fragility of conventional growth regressions could reflect a rejection of the conventional assumptions of linearity and independence. I. Robustness Tests The traditional approach to economic growth regressions is to assume linearity and independence of the control variables and estimate an equation of the form: (1) Y = β m M + β z Z + u where Y is per capita GDP growth, M is the variable of interest, and Z is an arbitrarily chosen set of control variables. The obvious concern with this approach is that the choice of the set of control variables, Z, can influence the estimate of β m. To test the robustness of the coefficient estimates generated by such an approach, L-R adapt the extreme bounds analysis of Leamer (1983). L-R systematically vary the subset of Z variables included in the regressions, where the Z variables are chosen from a pool of variables commonly used as indicators of the fiscal, trade or monetary environment or as measures of economic or political instability, and always include the investment share of GDP, initial GDP per capita, initial secondary-school enrollment rate,

and the average annual rate of population growth. 1 L-R estimate regressions adding all possible combinations of up to three additional control variables, and define the extreme upper (lower) bound as the highest (lowest) value of the estimate β m plus (minus) two standard deviations. A variable is considered robust if the estimate of β m remains statistically significant and of the same sign at the bounds. For complete details of the procedure, see Levine and Renelt (1992). Their basic conclusion is that the results of cross-country regressions are highly sensitive to small changes in the conditioning set. The only variables found to be robustly correlated with per capita GDP growth come from the set of variables included in each regression: initial income, investment, and secondary school enrollment rate. Of more than 30 other variables common to the growth literature, they find that none is robustly correlated with growth. However, as in the traditional literature, L-R impose an assumption of linearity and independence on their specification, raising the question of whether the perceived fragility of such growth regressions reflects a rejection of these conventional assumptions. In the following sections, I allow for several simple types of nonlinearities in the L-R framework to see if the pessimistic conclusions that have been drawn from their work are specific to the linear case. II. Nonlinearities and Parameter Sensitivity In what follows, I repeat the L-R robustness procedure, allowing for three types of nonlinearities for each of the variables that they consider. 2 To demonstrate the difference between their results and their procedure allowing for nonlinearities, I use the L-R data two cross-sectional samples covering 1960-89 or 1974-89, depending on data availability. 3 II.A. Squared Terms

One possibility is that the partial effect of a variable on per capita growth varies over different levels of the variable itself. For example, government expenditure on education may have a positive effect on growth, but with diminishing marginal returns. In that case, a linear specification could mask the positive correlation, since the slope of the parameter estimate tends toward zero as expenditure increases. Thus, I repeat the L-R procedure by including a squared term for the variable of interest in the regression specification: (2) Y = β m M + β m2 M 2 + β z Z + u The question of interest is whether the coefficient estimate β m becomes robust when a squared term is included (a secondary question is whether β m2 is itself robust). Allowing for the inclusion of a squared term, three of these variables become robust: the ratio of total government expenditure to GDP, the share of central-government individual income tax revenue to GDP, and the ratio of total trade to GDP. In addition, the squared terms for two of these variables are also robust. Results for the (robust) linear terms are presented in Panel A of Table 1. Two of the variables that become robust are indicators of fiscal policy, and indicators of government expenditure and income taxes are both negatively correlated with growth over low values of expenditure and taxes, respectively. The positive squared term in both cases suggests that this correlation attenuates at higher values of the variables. The third robust variable is trade volume, which is robustly negatively correlated with growth at low levels of trade volume, but the estimate of the marginal effect is statistically significant and positive at high values of trade volume. II.B. Interaction Terms A second possibility is that the partial effect of a variable on growth varies over different levels of development. For example, the marginal effect of economic uncertainty on growth

could be quite different in Germany than in Mexico. One means of capturing such nonlinearities is to include an interaction term between the variable of interest and the country s level of development (proxied for here by initial GDP per capita) in the regression specification. Thus, I repeat the L-R procedure by estimating the following specification: (3) Y = β m M + β m2 M Y 0 + β z Z + u where Y 0 measures initial GDP. The key question is whether β m becomes robust when the interaction term is included. In fact, four additional variables become robust: the ratio of total government expenditure to GDP, the ratio of government educational expenditure to GDP, the ratio of central-government tax revenue to GDP, and the share of central-government individual income tax revenue to GDP. Panel B of Table 1 presents results from the L-R procedure for these variables. Interestingly, all four of the variables that become robust when interaction terms are included are indicators of fiscal policy, and the range of GDP over which each marginal effect is statistically significant is large, covering more than two-thirds of the sample in each case. Combined with the results of the previous section, this suggests some important nonlinearities in the correlations between fiscal policy and growth. 4 The coefficient estimates are of the traditionally hypothesized sign with indicators of both government expenditure and taxes negatively correlated with growth. However, the positive interaction terms indicate that fiscal policy has less of an effect at higher levels of development. II.C. Multiple Growth Regimes The final nonlinearity considered is the possibility of multiple growth regimes. The theoretical growth literature has documented how, in the presence of sizable spillovers, multiple

steady states and thus multiple growth regimes can emerge (e.g., see Costas Azariadis and Allan Drazen (1990)). I divide the full sample into subgroups based on initial income (Y 0 ), which seems to be the most likely split variable for determining multiple regimes (the primary theoretical justification for multiple regimes based on initial development is Azariadas and Drazen (1990); Durlauf and Johnson (1995), Jenny A. Minier (1998), Zhenjuan Liu and Thanasis Stengos (1999), among others, provide empirical justification). Thus, I estimate regressions of the form: (4) Y = β mk M + β zk Z + u k where k=1 if Y 0 < Y and k=2 otherwise. Since theory does not identify the appropriate subgroups, I arbitrarily divide the sample at two points based on initial income: the 25th and 75th percentiles. Despite the smaller sample sizes, each split results in a substantially higher number of robust variables. Panel C of Table 1 provides the results for the lowest 75 percent of the sample by income. Five variables that are not robust in the full sample become robust for the lowest 75% of countries by income: the ratio of central-government surplus/deficit to GDP, the ratio of government educational expenditure to GDP, the ratio of total government expenditure to GDP, the ratio of central-government tax revenue to GDP, and the standard deviation of domestic credit growth. 5 Of special interest is that four of these variables are indicators of fiscal policy. Thus, these results indicate that, while fiscal policy indicators might not be robust in the full sample, they are robust in a subsample of lower-income countries. These results are consistent with those of the previous section, in that the marginal effects of fiscal policy appear to be more strongly correlated with growth in low-income countries. Additionally, as in the previous sections, the coefficient estimates are consistent with the standard hypotheses in which indicators

of government expenditure and indicators of taxes are negatively correlated with growth. In addition, the size of the government surplus is robustly and positively correlated with growth. The fifth variable that becomes robust in the low-income subsample is the standard deviation of the growth rate of domestic credit, which is a standard indicator of economic variability or uncertainty, and the coefficient estimate is of the hypothesized sign: greater uncertainty is expected to be correlated with lower growth. The fact that this variable is only robust in the low-income subsample is also consistent with the intuitively plausible story that low-income countries are more sensitive to economic uncertainty than high-income countries. III. Conclusion A major concern with the empirical growth literature has been the sensitivity of the results to the choice of conditioning variables. This fragility may be at least partly due to the common assumption of linearity in growth regressions; when I generalize the specification of the growth regression to allow the marginal effect of explanatory variables to vary, the number of robust variables increases substantially. The most striking result of the paper is the robustness of fiscal policy variables when one controls for nonlinearities. The correlation between measures of fiscal policy and growth has been of primary concern to many researchers, dating back to the earliest cross-country studies (e.g., Roger Kormendi and Phillip Meguire (1985)). However, one of the primary conclusions of Levine and Renelt (1992) is that none of the fiscal indicators is robustly correlated with growth. In contrast, I find that a broad array of fiscal policy indicators (measuring government expenditure, government taxes and budget deficits) are robustly correlated with growth when potential nonlinearities are taken into account.

Table 1: Robust Results Lower Bound Upper Bound Panel A: Squared Terms Expenditure -19.8 (5.81) -13.0 (6.24) Income taxes -75.6 (22.8) -46.8 (22.5) Total trade -5.52 (1.84) -3.75 (1.52) Panel B: Interaction Terms Expenditure -11.0 (2.81) -7.39 (3.05) Education expenditures -72.7 (19.3) -55.1 (20.5) Total taxes -20.7 (4.53) -12.3 (5.22) Income taxes -56.5 (16.9) -33.3 (16.7) Panel C: Multiple Regimes (lowest 75% of GDP) Expenditure -10.7 (2.95) -7.22 (2.80) Deficit/surplus 22.5 (6.87) 26.6 (7.10) Education expenditures -57.8 (18.2) -40.9 (21.0) Total taxes -19.1 (5.11) -11.2 (5.39) Std dev of credit growth -0.01 (0.003) -0.01 (0.002) Notes: Results are the coefficient estimate (and standard error) on each variable listed from the growth regression at each bound generated by the robustness procedure described in the text. Only results with both bounds statistically significant at 95 percent or better are presented.

References Azariadis, Costas, and Allan Drazen. 1990. Threshold Externalities in Economic Development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(2): 465-90. Doppelhofer, Gernot, Ronald I. Miller, and Xavier X. Sala-i-Martin. 2004. Determinants of Long-Term Growth: A Bayesian Averaging of Classical Estimates (BACE) Approach. American Economic Review, 94(4): 813-35. Durlauf, Steven N., and Paul A. Johnson. 1995. Multiple Regimes and Cross-Country Growth Behaviour. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 10(4): 365-84. Kalaitzidakis, Pantelis, Theofanis P. Mamuneas, and Thanasis Stengos. 2000. A Non-linear Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions. Canadian Journal of Economics 33(3): 604-17. Kormendi, Roger and Phillip Meguire. (1985). Macroeconomic Determinants of Growth: Cross-Country Evidence. Journal of Monetary Economics 16: 141-63. Leamer, Edward E. 1983. Let s Take the Con out of Econometrics. American Economic Review 73: 31-43. Levine, Ross, and David Renelt. 1992. A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions. American Economic Review, 82(4): 942-63. Liu, Zhenjuan and Thanasis Stengos. 1999. Non-linearities in Cross-Country Growth Regressions: A Semiparametric Approach. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 14(4); 527-38. Minier, Jenny A. 1998. Democracy and Growth: Alternative Approaches. Journal of Economic Growth, 3(3): 241-66. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier X. 1997. I Just Ran Two Million Regressions. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 87(2): 178-83.

Footnotes Department of Economics, University of Kentucky, 335 Gatton College of Business & Economics, Lexington KY, 40506-0034. E-mail: jminier@uky.edu. I am grateful to Chris Bollinger, Josh Ederington, Brian Krauth, Chris Papageorgiou, Andreas Savvides, and Ken Troske for their comments on an earlier draft. Any errors are, of course, my own. 1 Investment, schooling, and initial GDP are the only variables confirmed as being robustly correlated with growth in L-R. 2 I do not allow for nonlinearities in the three variables found to be robust by L-R: investment, initial GDP, and secondary school enrollment. 3 In contrast, Pantelis Kalaitzidakis, Theofanis P. Mamuneas and Thanasis Stengos (2000) treat the variables of interest as entering the regression linearly, but allow for nonlinearities in the control variables. 4 Note that government expenditure and taxes are robust when either squared terms or interaction terms are included: this reflects the high positive correlation between GDP per capita and expenditures/taxes. When the linear term, squared term, and interaction term are all included, the interaction term remains statistically significant while the squared term is not, in both cases. 5 In the highest 75th percentile by income, three fiscal policy variables are robust: government consumption, less defense and education, as share of GDP, the ratio of centralgovernment corporate-income-tax revenue to GDP, and the ratio of central-government tax revenue to GDP.