Supplementary Material to: Free Distribution or Cost-Sharing: Evidence from a Randomized Malaria Control Experiment

Similar documents
Free Distribution or Cost Sharing?

Free Distribution or Cost-Sharing?: Evidence from a Randomized Malaria Prevention Experiment

Online Appendix for Why Don t the Poor Save More? Evidence from Health Savings Experiments American Economic Review

User fees for health care can sometimes help the poor. Mead Over Center for Global Development

CÔTE D IVOIRE 7.4% 9.6% 7.0% 4.7% 4.1% 6.5% Poor self-assessed health status 12.3% 13.5% 10.7% 7.2% 4.4% 9.6%

NEPAL. Public Disclosure Authorized. Public Disclosure Authorized. Public Disclosure Authorized. Public Disclosure Authorized

Planning Sample Size for Randomized Evaluations

Intervention costing in OneHealth: Concepts related to Population in Need, Target Population and Coverage

Home Energy Reporting Program Evaluation Report. June 8, 2015

Full Web Appendix: How Financial Incentives Induce Disability Insurance. Recipients to Return to Work. by Andreas Ravndal Kostøl and Magne Mogstad

Contents: Appendix 3: Parallel Trends. Appendix

Chapter 8 Estimation

The data definition file provided by the authors is reproduced below: Obs: 1500 home sales in Stockton, CA from Oct 1, 1996 to Nov 30, 1998

Online Appendix. Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: Do Dynamic Incentives Matter? by Aron-Dine, Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen

Web Appendix for: Medicare Part D: Are Insurers Gaming the Low Income Subsidy Design? Francesco Decarolis (Boston University)

Saving Constraints and Microenterprise Development

baby bank dedicated maternal savings program via M- Pesa Eva Hoffmann, David Rizk, Amber Saloner

Population Economics Field Exam September 2010

An Evaluation of the Impact of Medicaid Expansion in New Hampshire

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports *

Student Loan Nudges: Experimental Evidence on Borrowing and. Educational Attainment. Online Appendix: Not for Publication

Financial Economics. Runs Test

Previously, when making inferences about the population mean, μ, we were assuming the following simple conditions:

Bargaining with Grandma: The Impact of the South African Pension on Household Decision Making

Percentage of foreclosures in the area is the ratio between the monthly foreclosures and the number of outstanding home-related loans in the Zip code

Data and Methods in FMLA Research Evidence

Your Name (Please print) Did you agree to take the optional portion of the final exam Yes No. Directions

School Attendance, Child Labour and Cash

Growing your family. Pregnancy/Adoption Parental Leave

ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables

PROJECT INFORMATION DOCUMENT (PID) CONCEPT STAGE. Health Service Delivery Project (HSDP) Region

Chapter 8 Statistical Intervals for a Single Sample

KENYA DYNAMIC HEALTH SERVICE COSTING MODEL

The Effect of the Working Income Tax Benefit on Labour Supply in Canada. Kourtney Koebel Dionne Pohler

TABLE OF CONTENTS. Paid Parental Leave Cost Estimates based on drafting of the Bill... 3

Online Appendix: Revisiting the German Wage Structure

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

7 Analyzing the Results 57

MEASURING TRADED MARKET RISK: VALUE-AT-RISK AND BACKTESTING TECHNIQUES

OHIO MEDICAID ASSESSMENT SURVEY 2012

Using survival models for profit and loss estimation. Dr Tony Bellotti Lecturer in Statistics Department of Mathematics Imperial College London

Web Appendix. Banking the Unbanked? Evidence from three countries. Pascaline Dupas, Dean Karlan, Jonathan Robinson and Diego Ubfal

The Simple Regression Model

Abstract. Family policy trends in international perspective, drivers of reform and recent developments

MED 146 Deliverable 1.24 Five Year Florida Medicaid Maternal and Child Health Status Indicators Report:

Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data

Financial Literacy, Social Networks, & Index Insurance

Approximating the Confidence Intervals for Sharpe Style Weights

Web Appendix for: Medicare Part D: Are Insurers Gaming the Low Income Subsidy Design? Francesco Decarolis (Boston University)

Scaling up interventions in the Eastern Mediterranean Region. What does it take and how many lives can be saved?

Health Equity and Financial Protection Datasheets. South Asia

Assessing the reliability of regression-based estimates of risk

Strategies for Assessing Health Plan Performance on Chronic Diseases: Selecting Performance Indicators and Applying Health-Based Risk Adjustment

Evaluation Report: Home Energy Reports

Alternate Specifications

NEW JERSEY VOTERS SUPPORT FEDERAL AND STATE FUNDING FOR LOW-INCOME WOMEN S HEALTH, INSURANCE COVERAGE FOR WOMEN S REPRODUCTIVE HEALTH SERVICES

LECTURE: MEDICAID HILARY HOYNES UC DAVIS EC230 OUTLINE OF LECTURE: 1. Overview of Medicaid. 2. Medicaid expansions

Statistical Evidence and Inference

House Bill 1279 (2009) Maryland Medicaid Program Family Planning Eligibility

Internet Appendix for Heterogeneity and Persistence in Returns to Wealth

Health Microinsurance Education Project Evaluation Northern Region, Ghana. Final Endline Report October 2012

Sensitivity Analysis for Unmeasured Confounding: Formulation, Implementation, Interpretation

Thirty-Second Board Meeting Corporate KPIs Narrative

THE CONSUMPTION AGGREGATE

Final Exam, section 1. Thursday, May hour, 30 minutes

Obesity, Disability, and Movement onto the DI Rolls

Service coverage within universal health coverage: how large is the gap?

Empirical Tools of Public Economics. Part-2

Quantitative Techniques Term 2

C A R I B B E A N A C T U A R I A L A S S O C I A T I O N

Using the OneHealth tool for planning and costing a national disease control programme

The Simple Regression Model

Potential impacts of climate change on $2-a-day poverty and child mortality in Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia

Risk in Agriculture Credit Applications: A New Approach

Internet Appendix. The survey data relies on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey,

1 Payroll Tax Legislation 2. 2 Severance Payments Legislation 3

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation

Point Estimation. Some General Concepts of Point Estimation. Example. Estimator quality

Context Power analyses for logistic regression models fit to clustered data

Data Appendix. A.1. The 2007 survey

The Status of BadgerCare Cost-Cutting Initiatives Proposed by the Department of Health Services

Supplementary Appendix

Stamp duty: its impact and the benefits of its abolition

KEY WORDS: Microsimulation, Validation, Health Care Reform, Expenditures

Relation between Income Inequality and Economic Growth

Tests for One Variance

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. EUI Working Papers ECO 2009/02 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. A Test of Narrow Framing and Its Origin.

Gender Disparity in Faculty Salaries at Simon Fraser University

Lazard Insights. The Art and Science of Volatility Prediction. Introduction. Summary. Stephen Marra, CFA, Director, Portfolio Manager/Analyst

Methods and Data for Developing Coordinated Population Forecasts

America s Uninsured Population

Multiple-Choice Questions

Subsidy Policies and Insurance Demand 1

Module 4: Point Estimation Statistics (OA3102)

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

Online Appendix to The Impact of Family Income on Child. Achievement: Evidence from the Earned Income Tax Credit.

Sean Howard Econometrics Final Project Paper. An Analysis of the Determinants and Factors of Physical Education Attendance in the Fourth Quarter

Does It Pay to Move from Welfare to Work? A Comment on Danziger, Heflin, Corcoran, Oltmans, and Wang. Robert Moffitt Katie Winder

How should funds for malaria control be spent when there are not enough?

The effect of Medicaid on Children s Health: a Regression Discontinuity Approach

Transcription:

Supplementary Material to: Free Distribution or Cost-Sharing: Evidence from a Randomized Malaria Control Experiment Jessica Cohen and Pascaline Dupas This document provides supplementary material to our paper Free Distribution or Cost-Sharing: Evidence from a Randomized Malaria Control Experiment. Appendix 1 shows evidence of the robustness of our main results to restricting our sample to pre-existing clients of the prenatal clinics where the experiment was conducted. Table A1, A2, and A3 reproduce the findings in Tables IV, V and VIII, respectively, on this restricted sample. The results are unchanged. We then present in Appendix 2 the details of the costeffectiveness calculations briefly outline in the main text and presented in Table IX. Finally, in Appendix 3 we present the clinic-level data on the three main outcomes of interest (ITN sales, ITN take-up and ITN usage) as well as one baseline characteristic (prenatal attendance in 2006) for the 16 clinics involved in the ITN distribution program.

Appendix 1: Robustness Checks It is likely that our experiment generated some crowd-out of prenatal clients at non-program clinics in the vicinity, particularly in the case of free nets. Since these switchers are driven by price differences in ITNs that would not exist in a nation-wide distribution program, we should look at the demand response of those prenatal clients who, at the time of the interview, were attending the same clinic that they had in the past. In Table A1, we replicate Table IV for this sub-sample of prenatal clients that did not switch clinics (i.e. attended the same prenatal clinic after our program was introduced as before it). The results are nearly unchanged, suggesting that the same degree of price sensitivity would prevail in a program with a uniform price across all clinics. In Table A2, we replicate Table V on the sub-sample of women who did not switch clinics. Again, the results are not different from those found for the sample as a whole. In Table A3, we replicate Table VIII on the sub-sample of women who did not switch clinics. Again, the results are not substantially different from those found for the sample as a whole.

Table A1. Demand for ITNs Across Prices: Individual-level Data. Sample restricted to existing clients of the clinic. Bought/Received an ITN during Prenatal Visit (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) ITN Price in Kenyan Shillings (Ksh) -.016 -.017 -.018 -.012 -.016 (.002) *** (.003) *** (.005) *** (.005) ** (.005) *** ITN Price = 10 Ksh ($0.15) -.087 -.001.120 (.022) *** (.095) (.172) ITN Price = 20 Ksh ($0.30) -.183 -.156 -.060 (.043) *** (.083) * (.172) ITN Price = 40 Ksh ($0.60) -.644 -.653 -.565 (.075) *** (.091) *** (.153) *** Time Controls X X X X X X Clinic Controls X X X X X X Restricted Sample: First Prenatal Visit X Restricted Sample: First Pregnancy X Restricted Sample: Did not receive free ITN previous year X X Observations 262 262 262 262 77 60 153 153 R-Squared 0.26 0.28 0.34 0.33 0.55 0.22 0.32 0.33 Mean of Dep. Var 0.82 0.82 0.82 0.82 0.71 0.87 0.86 0.86 Intra-Cluster Correlation 0.20 Notes: Data is from clinic-based surveys conducted in April-June 2007, throughout the first 6 weeks of the program. All regressions include district fixed effects. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the clinic level. Given the small number of clusters (16), the critical values for T-tests were drawn from a t-distribution with 14 (16-2) degrees of freedom; ***, **, * indicate significance at 1, 5, and 10% levels, respectively. All specifications are OLS regressions of an indicator variable equal to one if the respondent bought or received an ITN for free on the price of the ITN, except Columns 4 and 8 in which regressors are indicator variables for each price (price=0 is excluded). Time controls include fixed effects for the day of the week the survey was administered and a variable indicating how much time had elapsed between the day the survey was administered and the program introduction. Clinic controls include total monthly first prenatal care visits between April-June of 2006, the fee charged for a prenatal care visit, whether or not the clinic offers voluntary counseling and testing for HIV or prevention-of-mother-to-child-transmission of HIV services, the distance between the clinic and the closest other clinic or hospital and the distance between the clinic and the closest other clinic or hospital in the program.

Table A2. ITN Usage Rates Across Prices, Conditional on Ownership. Sample restricted to existing clients of the clinic. Respondent is currently using the ITN acquired through the program ITN is Visibly Hanging (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) ITN Price.004.005.006 (.005) (.003) (.005) ITN Price = 10ksh -.115 -.020 -.162 (.152) (.152) (.173) ITN Price = 20ksh -.143 -.111 -.123 (.135) (.140) (.148) ITN Price = 40ksh.133.243.181 (.168) (.144) (.174) Time Controls X X Clinic Controls X X Obs 125 125 125 125 125 125 Sample Mean of Dep. Var 0.59 0.59 0.59 0.59 0.54 0.54 R-Squared 0.01 0.15 0.04 0.17 0.02 0.06 Intra-Cluster Correlation 0.05 Joint F-Test 1.21 3.30 1.61 Prob > F 0.34 0.05 0.23 Notes: Data is from home visits to a random sample of patients who bought nets at each price or received a net for free. Home visits were conducted for a subsample of patients roughly 3-6 weeks after their prenatal visit. Each column is an OLS regression of the dependent variable indicated by column on either the price of the ITN or an indicator variable for each price. All regressions include district fixed effects. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the clinic level. Given the small number of clusters (16), the critical values for T-tests were drawn from a t-distribution with 14 (16-2) degrees of freedom. The specifications in Column (2) and (4) control for the number of days that have elapsed since the net was purchased, the number of days that have elapsed since the program was introduced at the clinic in which the net was purchased and whether the woman has given birth already, is still pregnant, or miscarried, as well as the clinic controls in table 3.

Table A3. Characteristics of Prenatal Clients Buying/Receiving Nets Relative to Control Clients. Sample restricted to existing clients of the clinic. Mean in Control Clinics (1) 0 Ksh (FREE) (2) Differences with Control Clinics 10 Ksh 40 Ksh ($0.15) 20 Ksh ($0.30) ($0.60) (3) (4) (5) Panel A. Characteristics of Visit to Prenatal Clinic First Prenatal Visit for Current Pregnancy 0.37-0.16-0.08-0.10-0.14 0.48 (0.05) *** (0.08) (0.10) (0.15) Walked to the clinic 0.76-0.16 0.06 0.04-0.06 0.43 (0.16) (0.07) (0.08) (0.11) If took transport to clinic: price paid (Ksh) 4.50 3.04-0.13-0.43 4.67 11.21 (3.57) (1.59) (1.60) (2.97) Can Read Swahili 0.87 0.07 0.07-0.02-0.02 0.34 (0.03) ** (0.04) (0.02) (0.05) Wearing shoes 0.66-0.02 0.02-0.20 0.03 0.48 (0.15) (0.15) (0.17) (0.26) Respondent Owns Animal Assets 0.17 0.05-0.02 0.13 0.14 0.38 (0.08) (0.07) (0.09) (0.08) Panel B. Health Status Hemoglobin Level (Hb), in g/dl 10.45 1.08 0.70 0.49 0.17 1.67 (0.23) *** (0.54) (0.38) (0.44) Moderate Anemia (Hb < 11.5 g/dl) 0.71-0.23-0.11-0.13 0.14 0.46 (0.05) *** (0.15) (0.09) (0.09) Severe Anemia (Hb 9 g/dl) 0.15-0.11-0.04 0.01 0.00 0.36 (0.05) * (0.06) (0.06) (0.11) Obs 82 64 80 59 13 Notes: For each variable, Column 1 shows the mean observed among prenatal clients enrolling in control clinics; the standard deviations are presented in italics. Column 2 (3, 4, 5) shows the differences between "buyers" in the clinics providing ITNs at 0 (10, 20, 40) Ksh and prenatal clients enrolling in control clinics. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the clinic level; given the small number of clusters (16), the critical values for T-tests were drawn from a t-distribution with 14 (16-2) degrees of freedom.

Appendix 2: Cost-Effectiveness Calculations Quantifying Differences in Costs The analysis presented in Table 9 assumes that the only difference in cost per ITN between free distribution and cost-sharing is the difference in the subsidy. That is, we assume that an ITN given for free costs only 40Ksh more to the social planner than an ITN sold for 40Ksh. This assumption could be wrong for two reasons. First, given the demand effect, many more ITNs need to be delivered to clinics when they are distributed for free; this decreases the cost of distribution (per net), given economies of scale. In addition, cost-sharing introduces the need for additional supervision and accounting to ensure that the proceeds of the sales are not captured by clinic staff. This will tend to increase the logistical cost of cost-sharing. We do not have sufficient evidence on the importance of these two possible effects to quantify the differences in costs more precisely, and therefore make the conservative assumption that the delivery cost is similar across subsidy groups. Quantifying Differences in Benefits An important dimension to keep in mind in the cost-effectiveness analysis is the non-linearity in the health benefits associated with ITN use: high-density ITN coverage reduces overall transmission rates and thus positively affects the health of both non-users and users. The results of a recent medical trial of ITNs in Western Kenya imply that in areas with intense malaria transmission with high ITN coverage, the primary effect of insecticide-treated nets is via area-wide effects on the mosquito population and not, as commonly supposed, by simple imposition of a physical barrier protecting individuals from biting (Hawley et al, 2003). In this context, we propose the following methodology to measure the health impact of each ITN pricing scheme: we create a protection index for non-users (a logistic function of the share of users in the total population) and a protection index for users (a weighted sum of a physical barrier effect of the ITN and the externality effect, the weights depending on the share of users). This enables us to compute the health impact of each pricing scheme on both users and non-users and to (roughly) approximate the total number of child lives saved, as well as the cost per life saved. 1 Because the relative importance of the physical barrier effect and of the externality are uncertain, we consider three possible values for the 1 Randomized controlled trials in different malaria transmission settings have shown insecticide-treated bed nets (ITNs) reduce all cause mortality in children less than five years old by 17 percent (Phillips-Howard et al., 2003). We follow these results, under the assumption that the baseline under-five mortality rate (in the absence of ITN coverage) is 50 deaths per 1000 child-years. To compute the number of lives saved in Table 9, we assume that for 1000 households with a newborn, 42.5 child lives will be saved if all 1000 households are fully protected (100 percent protection index) for five years, but only (42.5 x p/100) child lives will be saved if the protection index among those households is only p (p between 0 and 100). These figures might be too rough, but they don t affect the outcome of the cost-effectiveness comparisons. The costs per life saved in Table 9 are only provided to enable these comparisons, but their absolute values should be taken with caution.

parameter of the logistic function predicting the protection index for non-users (the threshold externality parameter ) and three possible values for the effectiveness of ITNs as physical barriers. This gives us a total of 3 x 3 = 9 different scenarios and 9 different cost-per-life-saved estimates for each of the 4 pricing strategies. Figure A1 illustrates how the protection indices vary with the share of users in the entire population, and shows the 3 options we consider for each parameter. Panel A of Figure A1 shows that under the low threshold assumption the protection index for non-users reaches 0.7 for a share of users as low as 35 percent; whereas under the medium and high threshold assumption the protection index for nonusers doesn t reach 0.5 until the share of users is 50 and 65 percent, respectively. 2 Given the importance of the externality effect, another key parameter in the cost-effectiveness analysis is the share of ITN users in the total population. In Table A4, we assume that distribution programs would last for five years and estimate the share of ITN users in the entire population that would result under each price scenario at the end of the five years. This number depends on three factors: the share of ITN owners among households eligible for the program (i.e. households with a pregnancy), the share of users among owners, and the share of eligible households in the total population. 3 While we estimated the first two factors in our experiment, we do not know the last factor with certainty. We thus propose three possibilities (where the share of eligible households in a five year period is 65, 75 or 85 percent) and compute the resulting share of ITN users in the entire population. As discussed in the previous section, we find that cost-sharing considerably reduces the share of ITN users. With the conservative estimate of only 65 percent of households experiencing a pregnancy, we see that none of the schemes manages to reach the 50 percent coverage threshold that has been discussed in the epidemiology literature with respect to the importance of the externality effect. Mechanically, in the presence of an ITN distribution program through prenatal clinics, the share of ITN users in the entire population increases as the share of households experiencing a pregnancy within five years increases. Since the share of users plays an important role in the cost-effectiveness estimates, we will restrict ourselves to the most conservative assumption (only 65 percent of households experiencing a pregnancy within five years). Making a less conservative assumption would increase the cost-effectiveness of distribution programs that generate a higher coverage rate (i.e. free distribution compared to costsharing). 2 The latest literature suggests that the threshold is around 50 percent (Hawley et al, 2003). Therefore the medium case seems the most realistic. 3 A distribution scheme such as the one explored in this paper will depend on the share of pregnant women who receive prenatal care, this rate is very high in Kenya (nearly 90 percent) and would likely be increased even more by the incentive effect of low priced ITNs.

Figure A1. Scenarios Used in Cost-Effectiveness Analysis Panel A. Three hypothetical Scenarios on the Externality Threshold : How the Protection Index for Non-Users Varies with the Proportion of ITN Users in the Population Portection Index for Non Users 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 Low Threshold Medium Threshold High Threshold 0 0.00 0.08 0.17 0.25 0.33 0.42 0.50 0.58 0.67 0.75 0.83 0.92 1.00 Share of ITN Users in Total Population Panel B. For a Given Hypothesis on the Externality Threshold: How the Protection Index for Net Users Varies with Assumptions on the Effectiveness of ITNs as Physical Barriers for Users 1 0.9 Protection Index for ITN Users 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 High Physical Barrier Effectiveness Medium Physical Barrier Effectiveness Low Physical Barrier Effectiveness 0 0.00 0.08 0.17 0.25 0.33 0.42 0.50 0.58 0.67 0.75 0.83 0.92 1.00 Share of ITN Users in Total Population

ITN Price Subsidy per ITN Sold Share of Prenatal Clients Who get an ITN (Table 3, Table A4. Share of Households Using an ITN in Total Population Actual Cost (Ksh) % of ITN owners that are using it (Table 4, Effective Coverage Among Prenatal Subsidy Cost per User Household If 65% of HH experience a pregnancy within 5 years Share of Net Users in Total Population After 5 Years of Distribution If 75% of HH experience a pregnancy within 5 years If 85% of HH experience a pregnancy within 5 years (Ksh) (Ksh) Col. 2) Col. 4) Clients (Ksh) 0 455 0.98 446 0.65 0.64 697 0.42 0.48 0.54 10 445 0.93 414 0.53 0.49 843 0.32 0.37 0.42 20 435 0.83 361 0.64 0.53 684 0.34 0.40 0.45 40 415 0.40 166 0.75 0.30 553 0.20 0.23 0.26 This table estimates the share of ITN users in the entire population that would result under each price scenario assuming that distribution programs would last for 5 years. We propose three possibilities for the share of households with a pregnant woman in a 5 year period and compute the resulting share of ITN users in the entire population. Combining the estimation results of Tables 3 and 4 leads to overestimates of effective coverage at higher prices, compared to those observed in the sample (as presented in Table 5). Given the relatively large confidence intervals on the estimates in Table 5, however, in the cost-effectiveness calculations we choose to keep overestimates of the effective coverage rate under the cost-sharing scenarios in order to obtain a lower bound of the inefficiency of cost-sharing schemes, if there is any.

Appendix 3. Clinic-Level Data Clinic ID Average monthly attendance at the clinic prior to the program (2006) Average Weekly ITN sales over First 6 Weeks of Distribution Program Share of Prenatal Clients who Acquired Program ITN Share Using Program ITN at Follow-up (unconditional on take-up) ITN Price (in Ksh) 13 0 64 22 1.00 0.46 17 0 172 27 1.00 0.90 20 0 134 40 1.00 0.86 58 0 183 88 0.94 0.54 68 0 34 7 1.00 0.83 23 10 327 49 0.95 0.50 29 10 259 75 0.90 0.43 33 10 89 20 0.87 0.75 38 10 59 17 1.00 0.33 67 10 86 20 0.89 0.79 34 20 129 16 0.79 0.60 39 20 137 25 0.80 0.67 55 20 50 32 0.85 0.57 5 40 57 8 0.50 0.94 47 40 117 13 0.46 0.44 63 40 192 9 0.26 0.70