OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY FOR

Similar documents
OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY FOR

O PTIMAL M ONETARY P OLICY FOR

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME P UNISH S AVERS?

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME H ARM S AVERS? James Bullard President and CEO

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

James Bullard Aarti Singh. This version: 13 February 2017

Discussion of Berentsen/Monnet, "Channel Systems"

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Charles Engel University of Wisconsin

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Economic Inequality and Possible Policy Responses

A Primer on Price Level Targeting in the U.S.

Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy

A New Characterization of the U.S. Macroeconomic and Monetary Policy Outlook 1

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE CONFERENCE AGREEMENT FOR H.R. 1, THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

Perspectives on the Current Stance of Monetary Policy

ECON 3020: ACCELERATED MACROECONOMICS. Question 1: Inflation Expectations and Real Money Demand (20 points)

Monetary Policy Options in a Low Policy Rate Environment

Microeconomic Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Shocks

R-Star Wars: The Phantom Menace

Global Imbalances and Structural Change in the United States

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

WEALTH AND VOLATILITY

International Macroeconomic Comovement

An Illustrative Calculation of r

Ageing Population and Implications for Monetary Policy. By Sirawit Woramongkhon (Blink)

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE TAX CUT AND JOBS ACT AS ORDERED REPORTED BY THE SENATE COMMITTEE ON FINANCE ON NOVEMBER 16, 2017

Comments on Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy, by Cúrdia and Woodford

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 3

Unconventional Monetary Policy and the Great Recession:

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Exploding Bubbles In a Macroeconomic Model. Narayana Kocherlakota

Discussion of Kaplan, Moll, and Violante:

Government spending shocks, sovereign risk and the exchange rate regime

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

ADVANCED MODERN MACROECONOMICS

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation

Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy

Some Considerations for U.S. Monetary Policy Normalization

U.S. Monetary Policy and the Path to Normalization

Money, Inflation, and Interest Rates

Monetary Policy, Capital Flows, and Exchange Rates. Part 2: Capital Flows and Crises

Two Views of International Monetary Policy Coordination

MONETARY POLICY ACCORDING TO HANK

Should the Monetary Policy Rule Be Different in a Financial Crisis? By Monika Piazzesi i

Global Imbalances and Structural Change in the United States

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle?

Benjamin D. Keen. University of Oklahoma. Alexander W. Richter. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. Nathaniel A. Throckmorton. College of William & Mary

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

A Theory of Leaning Against the Wind

Endogenous employment and incomplete markets

Oil Shocks and the Zero Bound on Nominal Interest Rates

Topics in Macroeconomics with Heterogeneous Households and Firms

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification

Foreign Ownership of US Safe Assets. Good or Bad?

Agent-based modeling and General Equilibrium

UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program. Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

The Macroeconomics e ects of a Negative Income Tax

Discussion of Do taxes explain European employment? Indivisible labor, human capital, lotteries and savings, by Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas Sargent

Does Low Inflation Justify a Zero Policy Rate?

Risk shocks and monetary policy in the new normal

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

Devaluation Risk and the Business Cycle Implications of Exchange Rate Management

Human Capital Risk in Life Cycle Economies

International Monetary Stability: A Multiple Equilibria Problem?

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Movements on the Price of Houses

A Singular Achievement of Recent Monetary Policy

The International Transmission of Credit Bubbles: Theory and Policy

Downside Risk at the Zero Lower Bound

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

Chapter 19. What Macroeconomics Is All About. In this chapter you will learn to. Key Macroeconomic Variables. Output and Income

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

On Linking Microsimulation and Computable General Equilibrium Models Using Exact Aggregation of Heterogeneous Discrete-choice choice Making Agents

SURVEY OF PRIMARY DEALERS

Financial Factors in Business Cycles

Business Cycles II: Theories

More on Modern Monetary Policy Rules

Housing Markets and the Macroeconomy During the 2000s. Erik Hurst July 2016

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

James Bullard President and CEO Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. SNB Research Conference Zurich 27 September 2014

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Transcription:

OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY FOR THE MASSES James Bullard (FRB of St. Louis) Riccardo DiCecio (FRB of St. Louis) University of Birmingham Birmingham, United Kingdom Aug. 9, 2018 Any opinions expressed here are our own and do not necessarily reflect those of the FOMC.

Introduction

INEQUALITY AND MONETARY POLICY Interest in income, financial wealth, and consumption inequality has increased in the last decade. Can monetary policy be conducted in a way that benefits all households even in a world of substantial heterogeneity? The answer in this paper is yes. Material has been posted online and previously presented at the Norges Bank, the St. Louis Fed, the Dallas Fed, the Texas Monetary Conference, and the Barcelona Workshop on Monetary Policy and Central Banking.

SOME RECENT LITERATURE Kaplan, Moll, and Violante (AER, 2018): NK macro with heterogeneous households ( HANK ); reasonable Gini coefficients. The monetary policy transmission mechanism is substantially altered relative to standard model. Bhandari, Evans, Golosov, and Sargent (Working paper, NYU, 2018): Incomplete markets, nominal friction, heterogeneous households ( HAIM ); reasonable Gini coefficients. Optimal monetary-fiscal policy (Ramsey) substantially altered relative to standard model. See A. Bhandari, D. Evans, M. Golosov, and T. Sargent, "Inequality, Business Cycles, and Monetary-Fiscal Policy," Working Paper, New York University, June 6, 2018, available at http://www.tomsargent.com/research/begs2.pdf.

SOME RECENT LITERATURE Bullard and DiCecio (Working paper, St. Louis Fed, 2018): Incomplete markets, nominal friction, heterogeneous households ( HAIM ); reasonable Gini coefficients. Optimal monetary policy repairs the distortion caused by the friction for all households. See also the conference on Monetary Policy and the Distribution of Income and Wealth, held at the St. Louis Fed on Sept. 11 12, 2015. Program available at https://research.stlouisfed.org/ conferences/monetary_policy_conf/program.

WEALTH, INCOME, AND CONSUMPTION INEQUALITY There is a lot of financial wealth, income, and consumption inequality in this stylized model. The role of credit markets, if they work correctly, is to reallocate uneven income across the life-cycle into perfectly equal consumption shares by cohort, appropriately scaled by life cycle productivity. The model equilibrium generates realistic Gini coefficients.

OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY The role of monetary policy in this model is to make sure credit markets are working correctly (i.e., complete). Practically speaking, this optimal monetary policy looks like nominal GDP targeting. This result continues to hold even when there is massive heterogeneity enough heterogeneity to approximate income, financial wealth, and consumption inequality in the U.S. Hence, the main result is that NGDP targeting constitutes optimal monetary policy for the masses in this environment.

Environment

LIFE-CYCLE MODELS General-equilibrium life-cycle economy. Each period, a new cohort of households enters the economy, makes economic decisions over the next 241 periods, then exits the economy. The model is therefore quarterly. Households have log preferences defined over consumption and leisure. Households are assigned a personal productivity profile when they enter the model. The profile is symmetric it begins low, rises and peaks exactly in the middle of life, then declines back to the low level. There will be many of these, as discussed below. Productivity units determine the value of an hour worked in a competitive labor market. There is no population growth in this version.

HOUSEHOLD CREDIT The overlapping-generations structure creates a large private credit market essential to good macroeconomic performance. Relatively young households want to borrow to move consumption forward in the life cycle, while middle-aged households wish to save for retirement. So households in the middle of life lend to the relatively young. The key variable is therefore privately issued household debt. Household debt outstanding in the U.S. is on the order of GDP, around $20 trillion. As practical motivation, think of privately issued debt = mortgage-backed securities.

NON-STATE CONTINGENT NOMINAL CONTRACTING There is a friction in the credit market: Non-state contingent nominal contracting (NSCNC). NSCNC: Loans are dispersed and repaid in the unit of account that is, in nominal terms and are not contingent on income realizations. There are two aspects to this friction: The non-state contingent aspect means that real resources are misallocated via this friction. The nominal aspect means that the monetary authority may be able to fix the distortion to the equilibrium.

LINEAR PRODUCTION TECHNOLOGY Output is produced using a technology that is linear in the labor input. In the equilibrium we study, the labor input (hours worked) will be constant. The level of technology (aka aggregate productivity ) grows at a stochastic rate. The technology growth rate is bounded so that the ZLB is avoided. The real wage grows at the same stochastic rate as aggregate productivity.

TIMING PROTOCOL At the beginning of every date, nature moves first and chooses the growth rate of aggregate productivity, which therefore implies a value for the real wage. The policymaker moves next and chooses a value for the price level. Households then decide how much to work, consume, and save.

NOMINAL INTEREST RATE DETERMINATION Households meet in a competitive market for nominally denominated, non-state contingent loans. The non-state contingent nominal interest rate, the contract rate, that clears this market is given by expected nominal GDP growth. In the equilibrium we study, this expectation is the same for all households, even those born at different dates or with different levels of personal productivity.

THE EQUILIBRIUM MONETARY POLICY CREATES The monetary policymaker follows a nominal GDP targeting rule that delivers complete-markets consumption allocations. 1 That is, low inflation in response to a high realization of the aggregate productivity growth rate, and vice versa. Given this policy rule, households consume equal amounts of available production, given their productivity, equity share contracting, which is optimal under homothetic preferences. This means that any two households that share the same personal productivity profile will consume the same amount at each date. The nominal GDP targeting rule perfectly insures the household against future shocks to income. Income, consumption, and asset holdings fluctuate from period to period but in proportion to the value of the real wage. 1 Similar to Sheedy (BPEA, 2014) and Koenig (IJCB, 2013):

THE WICKSELLIAN NATURAL REAL RATE OF INTEREST The equilibrium we study has the following property: The real interest rate is exactly equal to the output growth rate at every date, even in the stochastic economy. One could think of this as the Wicksellian natural real rate of interest. This in turn creates a set of easy-to-understand baseline results for this stylized economy.

Life-Cycle Productivity

LIFE-CYCLE PRODUCTIVITY PROFILES Households entering the economy draw a scaling factor and receive a life-cycle productivity profile, which is a scaled version of the baseline profile. Life-cycle productivity profiles, once assigned, are deterministic. This process is a stand-in for the human capital development that takes place before age 20 in actual economies, including schooling, parenting, and any pre-age 20 job experience. Huggett, Ventura, and Yaron (AER, 2011) argue that differences in human capital initial conditions are more important than differences in shocks for life-cycle earnings.

BASELINE LIFE-CYCLE PRODUCTIVITY 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 0 60 120 180 240 quarters FIGURE: Baseline endowment profile. The profile is symmetric and peaks in the middle period of the life cycle.

THE MASS OF LIFE-CYCLE PRODUCTIVITY FIGURE: The mass of endowment profiles.

Characterizing the Equilibrium

LABOR/LEISURE 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0 60 120 180 240 quarters FIGURE: Cross section: Leisure decisions by age (green), labor supply by age (blue), and fraction of work time in U.S. data, 19% (red). The labor/leisure choices depend on age only. High-income households work the same hours as low-income households at each age.

LABOR INCOME MASS FIGURE: Cross section: Labor income profiles. Personal productivity peaks at the middle of the life cycle, and households work more at that time as well, making income even more concentrated in the peak earning years.

CONSUMPTION MASS FIGURE: Cross section: Consumption mass (red) and labor income mass (blue) along the complete-markets balanced growth path. Under optimal monetary policy, the private credit market reallocates uneven labor income into perfectly equal consumption for each productivity profile. The consumption Gini is 31.8%, similar to values calculated from U.S. data.

NET ASSET HOLDING MASS FIGURE: Cross section: Net asset holding mass. Borrowing, the negative values to the left, peaks at stage 60 of the life cycle (age ~35), while positive assets peak at stage 180 of life (age ~65). The financial wealth Gini is 72.7%, similar to values calculated in U.S. data.

THREE NOTIONS OF INCOME Three notions of income: 1 Labor income (Y 1 ). 2 Labor income plus non-negative capital income (Y 2 ). 3 The non-negative component of total income (Y 3 ). Gini coefficients of the various income distributions: G Y1 = 56.2%, G Y2 = 51.6%, G Y3 = 59.6%.

LABOR INCOME + NON-NEGATIVE CAPITAL INCOME FIGURE: Cross section: Profiles of labor income and non-negative capital income.

NON-NEGATIVE TOTAL INCOME FIGURE: Cross section: Profiles of non-negative total income.

Inequality

DATA ON INEQUALITY IN THE U.S. Consumption (Heathcote, Perri, and Violante, RED, 2010): G C,U.S. = 32%. Income (CBO, 2016): pre-taxes/transfers G Y,U.S. = 51%; post-taxes/transfers G Y,U.S. = 43%. Financial wealth (Davies, Sandström, Shorrocks, and Wolff, EJ, 2011): G W,U.S. = 80%.

INEQUALITY IN THE MODEL Financial wealth is defined as the non-negative part of net assets. Model G W = 72.7% > G Y2 = 51.6% > G C = 31.8%, versus U.S. data G W,U.S. = 80% > G Y,U.S. = 51% > G C,U.S. = 32%.

Policy

INTERPRETING MONETARY POLICY The nominal GDP targeting rule characterizes policy by counter-cyclical price level movements. But the policy can also be interpreted more conventionally in interest rate terms. Nominal interest rates are determined in a private market, understanding policy... And policy is made understanding nominal interest rate determination... Nominal interest rate policy is a fixed point of this process.

POLICY CHARACTERIZATION The nominal rate is determined one period in advance as the expected rate of nominal GDP growth. Wicksellian natural real rate = aggregate productivity growth rate. The nominal rate is always ratified ex post by the policymaker. This makes the real rate = aggregate productivity growth rate = Wicksellian natural real rate of interest. Just like the simple NK model.

NOMINAL GDP TARGETING How can we interpret these results as NGDP targeting? No persistence in productivity growth: The expected rate of NGDP growth never changes, and the economy never deviates from the NGDP path. Perfect NGDP targeting. Persistence in productivity growth: The expected rate of NGDP growth fluctuates persistently with the shock, and it takes longer to return to the balanced growth NGDP path. Nominal and real rates fall in a recession.

EFFECTS OF A SHOCK 1.02 1 1.4 1.2 1 0 5 10 quarters 0 5 10 quarters 1.06 1.04 1.02 1.06 1.04 1.02 0 5 10 quarters 0 5 10 quarters FIGURE: Monetary policy responds to a decrease in aggregate productivity growth by increasing the inflation rate in the period of the shock. Subsequently, inflation converges to its BGP value from below. The nominal interest rate drops in the period after the shock.

Conclusions

SUMMARY This paper attributes observed levels of U.S. inequality to life-cycle effects in conjunction with heterogeneous life-cycle productivity profiles. All households in this model, regardless of their assigned life-cycle productivity profile, face a problem of smoothing life-cycle consumption in a world with a credit market friction, non-state contingent nominal contracting. The monetary authority can remove this impediment to life-cycle consumption smoothing for all households: optimal monetary policy for the masses. Does monetary policy affect inequality? Yes, it improves consumption allocations.