Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

Similar documents
Bennett S. LeBow College of Business

Growth Rate of Domestic Credit and Output: Evidence of the Asymmetric Relationship between Japan and the United States

Asian Economic and Financial Review MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION AND BANK LENDING IN SOUTH KOREA AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. Yu Hsing

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Exchange Rate Pass-through in India

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Available online at ScienceDirect. Procedia Economics and Finance 32 ( 2015 ) Andreea Ro oiu a, *

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

An Estimated Fiscal Taylor Rule for the Postwar United States. by Christopher Phillip Reicher

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND UNEMPLOYMENT RATE OF THE TRANSITION COUNTRY THE CASE OF THE CZECH REPUBLIC

Test of the bank lending channel: The case of Hungary

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They?

What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU?

Global macro matters Rising rates, flatter curve: This time isn t different, it just may take longer

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

The Kalman Filter Approach for Estimating the Natural Unemployment Rate in Romania

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

Vanguard commentary April 2011

The Real Business Cycle Model

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Is Higher Volatility Associated with Lower Growth? Intranational Evidence from South Korea

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

Inflation and inflation uncertainty in Argentina,

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

Effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries

E-322 Muhammad Rahman CHAPTER-3

THE CREDIT CYCLE and the BUSINESS CYCLE in the ECONOMY of TURKEY

The Credit Cycle and the Business Cycle in the Economy of Turkey

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

Volume 29, Issue 2. A note on finance, inflation, and economic growth

Outline. 1. Overall Impression. 2. Summary. Discussion of. Volker Wieland. Congratulations!

Lecture 4. Extensions to the Open Economy. and. Emerging Market Crises

Futures Contracts Rates as Monetary Policy Forecasts

Banking Globalization, Monetary Transmission, and the Lending Channel

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Measuring the Channels of Monetary Policy Transmission: A Factor-Augmented Vector Autoregressive (Favar) Approach

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Calibrating Macroprudential Policy to Forecasts of Financial Stability

Government Spending, Distortionary Taxation and the International Transmission of Business Cycles

Bank Lending Shocks and the Euro Area Business Cycle

There is poverty convergence

Monetary Policy Shock Analysis Using Structural Vector Autoregression

Macro News and Exchange Rates in the BRICS. Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Fabio Spagnolo and Nicola Spagnolo. February 2016

Business Cycles. Trends and cycles. Overview. Trends and cycles. Chris Edmond NYU Stern. Spring Start by looking at quarterly US real GDP

Business Cycles. (c) Copyright 1998 by Douglas H. Joines 1

Keywords: Monetary Policy, Bank Lending Channel, Foreign Banks.

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Macro Notes: Introduction to the Short Run

Monetary Policy, Asset Prices and Inflation in Canada

Structural budget balance and fiscal policy stance in Tunisia

Financial Liberalization and Money Demand in Mauritius

Bank Profitability, Capital, and Interest Rate Spreads in the Context of Gramm-Leach-Bliley. and Dodd-Frank Acts. This Draft Version: January 15, 2018

IV SPECIAL FEATURES THE IMPACT OF SHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES ON BANK CREDIT RISK-TAKING

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

RISK SPILLOVER EFFECTS IN THE CZECH FINANCIAL MARKET

MONETARY POLICY EXPECTATIONS AND BOOM-BUST CYCLES IN THE HOUSING MARKET*

Capital Structure and the 2001 Recession

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Box 1.3. How Does Uncertainty Affect Economic Performance?

BANK LOAN COMPONENTS AND THE TIME-VARYING EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY SHOCKS

Business cycle fluctuations Part II

Monetary Policy and Market Interest Rates in Brazil

Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH

Financial Econometrics Notes. Kevin Sheppard University of Oxford

Vanguard: The yield curve inversion and what it means for investors

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

A Threshold Multivariate Model to Explain Fiscal Multipliers with Government Debt

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Switching Costs for Bank-Dependent Borrowers: Do They Matter for the Bank Lending Channel of Monetary Policy?

Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia?

Asian Economic and Financial Review, 2016, 6(4): Asian Economic and Financial Review. ISSN(e): /ISSN(p):

Asian Economic and Financial Review EMPIRICAL TESTING OF EXCHANGE RATE AND INTEREST RATE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS IN CHINA

Modeling and Forecasting the Yield Curve

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

Exchange Rates and Inflation in EMU Countries: Preliminary Empirical Evidence 1

FIW Working Paper N 58 November International Spillovers of Output Growth and Output Growth Volatility: Evidence from the G7.

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Bank Capital, Profitability and Interest Rate Spreads MUJTABA ZIA * This draft version: March 01, 2017

Explaining procyclical male female wage gaps B

Test of the Bank Lending Channel: The Case of Poland

Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S.

Hazardous Times for Monetary Policy: What do 23 Million Bank Loans Say About the Effects of Monetary Policy on Credit Risk?

Transcription:

Economics Letters 108 (2010) 167 171 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Economics Letters journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolet Is there a financial accelerator in US banking? Evidence from the cyclicality of banks' price cost margins Roger Aliaga-Díaz a,1, María Pía Olivero b, a The Vanguard Group, Inc. P.O. Box 2600, V36, Valley Forge, PA 19482-2600, USA b Department of Economics, LeBow College of Business, Drexel University, 3141 Chestnut Street, Philadelphia, PA, 19104, USA article info abstract Article history: Received 6 June 2008 Received in revised form 23 July 2009 Accepted 26 April 2010 Available online xxxx We show that price cost margins for US banks are consistently countercyclical, even after controlling for credit risk, the term structure of interest rates and monetary policy. This evidence supports the existence of a financial accelerator in US banking. 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: E32 E44 Keywords: Banks' price cost margins RBC Financial accelerator 1. Introduction Bernanke and Gertler (1989) and Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1996, 1998) (hereafter BGG) first studied the role of an endogenously countercyclical price cost margin in financial markets (a countercyclical external finance premium) as an amplifier of business fluctuations. After their seminal work, a large body of literature in macroeconomic theory studies this issue. However, empirical research has not devoted much attention to testing a direct implication of this theory, namely, the countercyclicality of margins in credit markets. In this paper we start filling this gap. We study the cyclical behavior of banks' price cost margins (calculated as the difference between the interest rate on loans and the marginal cost of funds for banks) in the United States using quarterly data for the period 1984 2005. We equate banks' price cost margins to the BGG external finance premia on the basis of banks' marginal costs of funds being a good proxy for firms' marginal costs of internal funds. With this goal, we apply the VAR forecast error-based methodology proposed by den Haan (2000) to measure comovement between variables. We document the countercyclicality of margins, a fact about business cycles that has received no attention before. Corresponding author. Tel.: +215 895 4908; fax: +215 895 6975. E-mail addresses: roger_aliaga-diaz@vanguard.com (R. Aliaga-Díaz), maria.olivero@drexel.edu (M.P. Olivero). 1 Tel.: +610 669 4671. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of The Vanguard Group, Inc. Using the methodology in den Haan (2000), as opposed to standard regression analysis, allows us to better control for the cyclical pattern of credit risk, the term structure of interest rates and monetary policy. These could be suggested as the only determinants of the cyclical behavior of margins, and failing to account for them would make the exercise almost trivial. Presenting evidence supporting the financial accelerator requires showing that there is an independent relationship between business cycles and margins, and that the comovement between them is not entirely explained by the cyclical pattern of these variables. 2 Our key finding is that this comovement remains negative and statistically significant even after controlling for these determinants. 2. Data We use bank-level balance sheet quarterly data for 1984 2005 from the Call Reports on Condition and Income. Price cost margin measures are the asset-weighted averages over all banks. Two alternative business cycle measures are used in this study: GDP and total loans. Loans reflect better than GDP the behavior of aggregates such as investment, which depend critically on bank financing. Four alternative definitions are used for margins. Margin 1 is calculated as the ratio of the difference between interest income and 2 The countercyclicality is a necessary but not sufficient condition for the existence of the accelerator. It does not guarantee that margins exacerbate the effects of aggregate shocks. 0165-1765/$ see front matter 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2010.04.037

168 R. Aliaga-Díaz, M.P. Olivero / Economics Letters 108 (2010) 167 171 Table 1 Sample correlations of margins with business cycle measures. GDP Total loans Margin 1 0.237 0.395 (0.029) (0.000) Margin 2 0.306 0.657 (0.004) (0.000) Spread BP-FF 0.322 0.339 (0.003) (0.002) Spread survey-ff 0.214 0.203 (0.066) (0.081) p-values shown in parentheses. Hodrick Prescott filtered series. Table 2 Characteristics of the estimated VARs. Business cycle indicator (in logs) Margin No. lags Bivariate GDP 1 2 2 Loans 1 2 2 GDP 2 2 2 Loans 2 2 2 GDP Spr BP-FF 2 2 Loans Spr BP-FF 3 2 GDP Spr survey-ff 3 2 Loans Spr survey-ff 2 2 Multivariate expenses to banks' assets. Margin 2 is calculated as the ratio of the difference between interest income and expenses to loans. The third measure is the spread between the bank prime and the federal funds rate, and the fourth is the spread between the lending rate taken from the Survey of Terms of Business Lending and the federal funds rate. Following Coleman (1995) among others, we use the federal funds rate as a proxy for banks' marginal cost of funds. A data appendix is available upon request. Table 1 provides a first insight on the cyclicality of margins, showing the sample unconditional correlations between margins and business cycle indicators. These are always negative and significant. 3. Model specification To measure the comovement between variables at business cycle frequencies we use the methodology proposed by den Haan (2000), based on correlations of VAR forecast errors at various horizons. This approach is better than a standard regression analysis for two reasons. First, even conditional correlations fail to capture important information about the dynamic aspects of the comovement of variables (Rotemberg, 1996; den Haan, 2000). Second, given that the correlation coefficients obtained from a regression analysis are defined only for stationary series, the data must be transformed, which makes the correlations sensitive to the detrending methods used. In the den Haan (2000) method the VAR can contain any combination of stationary processes and processes integrated of arbitrary order. Thus, there is no need for detrending the data. The VAR we estimate is: X t = α + μ 1 t + μ 2 t 2 L + β l X t l l =1 2 + δ i R it i =1 3 + θ i Q it + t ð1þ i =1 where t denotes time, L is the total number of lags included in the equations, and X t is a vector of variables which includes the margin measure and the business cycle indicator. The R matrix includes dummy variables to control for two important regulatory changes that took place in the United States banking sector during the period covered by this study. First, in 1994 the Riegle Neal Interstate Banking Act allowed national banks to operate branches across states after June 1, 1997. Second, the Gramm Leach Bliley Act enacted in November of 1999 increased the number of activities allowed for banks. The Q matrix includes quarterly dummy variables to control for seasonality in the bank data. By estimating this VAR, we compute the K-period ahead forecast of the variables (E t X t + K ). We then obtain the K-period ahead forecast ue ue errors (X t + K,t )asx t + K,t X t + K,t E t X t + K and their variance covariance matrix as a function of the coefficients β and Var(). Using this variance covariance matrix, we can compute the correlation coefficient between the K-period ahead forecast errors of the two random variables in X (i.e. a measure of margins and a business cycle indicator). We denote it by COR(K). Last, we construct bootstrapped confidence bands for COR(K) based on 2500 replications of the system. 3 3.1. Multivariate specification The cyclicality of credit risk, the term structure of interest rates and monetary policy could be suggested as the only determinants of the cyclicality of margins. Therefore, in a second step we want to assess whether we have uncovered a truly independent relationship between business cycles and margins. To do so we include the following two additional endogenous variables in the X matrix. 3.1.1. Credit risk The net charge-off rate (defined as loan charge-offs net of loan recoveries as a percentage of total loans) is used as a measure of aggregate risk. If a higher credit risk and hence higher margins are associated with recessions, the countercyclicality of risk is an important candidate to explain that of margins. 3.1.2. The term structure of interest rates and monetary policy The cyclicality of margins could also be explained by maturity mismatches in banks' balance sheets. If bank assets are of longer maturity than their liabilities, and with recessions typically driving short-term rates down by more than long-term rates, banks' expenses might fall by more than their income. Then, ex-post margins (calculated using the difference between interest income and expenses) might increase in recessions. Therefore, in the multivariate VAR the matrix X includes the slope of the yield curve (the spread between the ten-year and the one-year rate). This slope is affected by monetary policy (see Bernanke and Blinder, 1992), so that including it allows us to control for the effects of monetary policy on margins. Table 2 summarizes the characteristics of the estimated VARs. 4. Results Figs. 1 and 2 plot COR(K) for various K forecast horizons and the 10% and 5% confidence bands. First, we estimate a bivariate VAR where X t includes only a measure of margins and a business cycle indicator. The countercyclicality of price cost margins is documented here with negative and significant correlation coefficients for most K and for all the specifications (see Fig. 1). Second, we estimate a multivariate VAR. Results indicate that margins and economic activity are negatively and significantly correlated even after controlling for the cyclicality of credit risk, the term structure of interest rates and monetary policy (see Fig. 2). Our results are robust to using alternative measures of risk and the term 3 Our codes for the construction of confidence bands in bivariate and multivariate VARs are available upon request.

R. Aliaga-Díaz, M.P. Olivero / Economics Letters 108 (2010) 167 171 169 Fig. 1. Bivariate VARs: Correlations of Forecast Errors. The x-axis measures the forecast horizon in quarters. Estimated correlation coefficients (thick lines). 5%, 95% (thin lines), 10% and 90% (dash lines) bootstrapped confidence bands using a one-sided test.

170 R. Aliaga-Díaz, M.P. Olivero / Economics Letters 108 (2010) 167 171 Fig. 2. Multivariate VARs: Correlations of Forecast Errors.

R. Aliaga-Díaz, M.P. Olivero / Economics Letters 108 (2010) 167 171 171 structure. Showing how the countercyclicality survives to the inclusion of these controls is a key contribution of this paper. 5. Conclusions We provide evidence for a financial accelerator à la BGG working in the United States. In bad times credit becomes more expensive than in an economy with constant margins, and firms may delay investment and production. This makes recessions worse. Our study complements the extensive literature in macroeconomic theory that uses countercyclical margins and the accelerator as a mechanism for the propagation of aggregate shocks. From a policy perspective, the documented countercyclicality may provide additional grounds for stabilization. References Bernanke, B., Blinder, A., 1992. The federal funds rate and the channels of monetary transmission. American Economic Review 82, 901 921. Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., 1989. Agency costs, net worth and business fluctuations. American Economic Review 79, 14 31. Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., Gilchrist, S., 1996. The financial accelerator and the flight to quality. Review of Economics and Statistics 78, 1 15. Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., Gilchrist, S., 1998. The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. NBER Working Paper, 6455. Coleman, W., 1995. Comment on inside money, outside money, and short-term interest rates. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking Vol. 27 (4), 1387 1396 Part 2. den Haan, W., 2000. The comovement between output and prices. Journal of Monetary Economics 46, 3 30. Rotemberg, J., 1996. Prices, output and hours: an empirical analysis based on a sticky price model. Journal of Monetary Economics 37, 505 534. Acknowledgements We are grateful to Joseph Davis, Bang Jeon, Pietro Peretto, John Seater and Martín Uribe for helpful comments.