Lecture Notes on. Liquidity and Asset Pricing. by Lasse Heje Pedersen

Similar documents
Liquidity and Risk Management

THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS

Portfolio Investment

Discussion of Instability of Centralized Markets by Ahmad Peivandi and Rakesh Vohra

Should Norway Change the 60% Equity portion of the GPFG fund?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LIQUIDITY AND RISK MANAGEMENT. Nicolae B. Garleanu Lasse H. Pedersen. Working Paper

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Options and Limits to Arbitrage. Introduction. Options. Bollen & Whaley GPP EGMR. Concluding thoughts. Christopher G. Lamoureux.

How Much Can Marketability Affect Security Values?

Lecture 3 Asset liquidity

Corporate Bond Specialness

INVENTORY MODELS AND INVENTORY EFFECTS *

Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982

In real economies, people still want to hold fiat money eventhough alternative assets seem to offer greater rates of return. Why?

Liquidity. Why do people choose to hold fiat money despite its lower rate of return?

Financial Economics. A Concise Introduction to Classical and Behavioral Finance Chapter 1. Thorsten Hens and Marc Oliver Rieger

The Liquidity-Augmented Model of Macroeconomic Aggregates FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS

Dynamic Market Making and Asset Pricing

An Academic View on the Illiquidity Premium and Market-Consistent Valuation in Insurance

Institutional Finance Financial Crises, Risk Management and Liquidity

Institutional Finance Financial Crises, Risk Management and Liquidity

Leverage and Liquidity Dry-ups: A Framework and Policy Implications

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

Background Risk and Trading in a Full-Information Rational Expectations Economy

Are Security Lending Fees Priced? Theory and Evidence from the U.S. Treasury Market

Systemic Illiquidity in the Federal Funds Market

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Asset Pricing(HON109) University of International Business and Economics

identifying search frictions and selling pressures

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 7

Lasse Heje Pedersen. Copenhagen Business School, NYU, CEPR, AQR Capital Management

Foundations of Asset Pricing

MERTON & PEROLD FOR DUMMIES

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

LIMITED ARBITRAGE AND SHORT SALES RESTRICTIONS: EVIDENCE FROM THE OPTIONS MARKETS

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Citation for published version (APA): Oosterhof, C. M. (2006). Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging s.n.

SHORT SELLING. Menachem Brenner and Marti G. Subrahmanyam

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

FE501 Stochastic Calculus for Finance 1.5:0:1.5

Funding Value Adjustments and Discount Rates in the Valuation of Derivatives

Introduction The Story of Macroeconomics. September 2011

Market Transparency Jens Dick-Nielsen

Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint

LECTURE 12: FRICTIONAL FINANCE

Chapter 3 Domestic Money Markets, Interest Rates and the Price Level

Comparative Analysis of NYSE and NASDAQ Operations Strategy

Market Liquidity. Theory, Evidence, and Policy OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS THIERRY FOUCAULT MARCO PAGANO AILSA ROELL

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 22 Sep 2014

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Forwards, Futures, Options and Swaps

David Skeie Federal Reserve Bank of New York Bank of Canada Annual Economic Conference on New Developments in Payments and Settlement

FINANCIAL OPTIMIZATION. Lecture 5: Dynamic Programming and a Visit to the Soft Side

Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation

On the Risk Capital Framework of Financial Institutions

Outline. Equilibrium prices: Financial Markets How securities are traded. Professor Lasse H. Pedersen. What determines the price?

Online appendix for Price Pressures. Terrence Hendershott and Albert J. Menkveld

Transparency: Audit Trail and Tailored Derivatives

Principal Listing Exchange for each Fund: Cboe BZX Exchange, Inc.

ON UNANIMITY AND MONOPOLY POWER

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

Dynamic Asset Pricing Model

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Return to Risk Limited website: Swing Options Structure & Pricing

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

Donald L Kohn: Asset-pricing puzzles, credit risk, and credit derivatives

Subject CA1 Paper1 Core Applications Concepts

M.I.T Financial Engineering

Distant Speculators and Asset Bubbles in the Housing Market

ECO 328 SUMMER Sample Questions Topics I.1-3. I.1 National Income Accounting and the Balance of Payments

Methodology for assessment of the Nordic forward market

Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LIMITED ARBITRAGE AND SHORT SALES RESTRICTIONS: EVIDENCE FROM THE OPTIONS MARKETS

RATIONAL BUBBLES AND LEARNING

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Validation of Nasdaq Clearing Models

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Research Summary and Statement of Research Agenda

Appendix: Basics of Options and Option Pricing Option Payoffs

Determining Exchange Rates. Determining Exchange Rates

Working Paper October Book Review of

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Introduction to Real Options

Optimal Portfolios under a Value at Risk Constraint

10. Dealers: Liquid Security Markets

A Model of a Vehicle Currency with Fixed Costs of Trading

Introduction to Forwards and Futures

EXCHANGE TRADED CONCEPTS TRUST. REX VolMAXX TM Long VIX Futures Strategy ETF. Summary Prospectus March 30, 2018, as revised April 25, 2018

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

The Norwegian Government Pension Fund s potential for capturing illiquidity premiums

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Economics and Finance

Transcription:

Lecture Notes on Liquidity and Asset Pricing by Lasse Heje Pedersen Current Version: January 17, 2005 Copyright Lasse Heje Pedersen c Not for Distribution Stern School of Business, New York University, 44 West Fourth Street, Suite 9-190, New York, NY 10012-1126, email: lpederse@stern.nyu.edu, http://www.stern.nyu.edu/ lpederse/

1 Overview This class discusses how market liquidity affect security prices. Liquidity is, as we shall see, a complex concept. Said simply, liquidity is the ease of trading a security. A security can be illiquid because it has high exogenous transaction costs such as brokerage fees or the fees paid to a real estate agent. Hence, every time such a security is traded, the buyer and/or seller incurs a transaction cost, and the buyer anticipates further costs upon a future sale, and so on. Another source of illiquidity is demand pressure and inventory risk. Demand pressure arises because not all agents are present in the market at all times, which means that if an agent needs to sell a large block of securities quickly, then the natural buyers may not be immediately available. In this case, the seller may trade with a market maker who will buy in anticipation of being able to later lay off the position. The market maker is exposed to the risk of price changes in the meantime, however, and the market maker must be compensated for this risk. Also, a security can be illiquid because the traders of the security have private information. E.g. the buyer of a stock may be afraid that a potential seller has private information that the company is loosing money, and the seller may be afraid the buyer has private information that the company will do well because of a drug is about to be approved or because the company is about to be taken over. In addition to such private information about the fundamentals of the security, agents can also have private information about order flow. For instance, if a trading desk knows that a hedge fund needs to liquidate a large position and that this liquidation will depress prices, then the trading desk can sell early at relatively high prices and buy back later at lower prices. Another source of illiquidity is that it is simply difficult to locate a counterparty who is willing to trade a particular security, and, once a counterparty is located, the agents must negotiate the price in a less than perfectly competitive environment since alternative trading partners are not immediately available. This search friction is particularly relevant in over-the-counter OTC) markets in which there is no central market place. Finally, a security market can be affected by short sale constraints. Certain assets cannot be shorted at all e.g. real estate) while most financial securities can in principle be shorted, but institutional arrangements sometimes make this difficult. 1

Illiquidity gives rise to a bid-ask spread, that is, to a difference between the price at which one can buy or sell. In addition, illiquidity affects the level of prices and the required return. Cross-sectional differences in securities liquidity have implications for relative prices. Needless to say, understanding how liquidity affects pricing is important, for instance, because asset pricing affect corporations cost of capital and, hence, the allocation of the economy s real resources. 1.1 Background: Standard Asset Pricing Standard asset pricing is based on the assumption of frictionless or, perfectly liquid) markets, that is, every security can be traded at no cost all of the time, and agents take prices as given. This assumption is combined with one of the following three assumptions: no arbitrage, agent optimality, and equilibrium. No arbitrage means that one cannot make money in one state of nature without paying money in at least one state of nature. In a frictionless market, the assumption of no arbitrage is essentially equivalent to the existence of a stochastic discount factor m t, and a martingale measure or risk-neutral measure) Q such that the price process p t of any security with dividend process d t satisfies p t = E t p t+1 + d t+1 ) m ) t+1 1) m t ) = E Q 1 t p t+1 + d t+1 ) 2) 1+r f t where r f t is the riskfree rate of interest. Equation 1) is the main building block of standard asset pricing theory. It can also be derived by agent optimality. In particular, if an insatiable investor trades in a frictionless market, his optimal portfolio choice problem only has a solution in the absence of arbitrage otherwise he will make an arbitrarily large profit and consume an arbitrarily large amount. Further, the first-order condition to the investor s problem has the form 1). In particular, if the investor s preferences are represented by an additively separable utility function E t s uc s) for a consumption process c, then m t = u c t ) is the marginal utility of consumption. Finally, in a competitive equilibrium with complete markets and agents i =1,...,I with separable utility functions u i, 1) is satisfied with m t = 2

u λ c t), where u λ = i λi u i is the utility function of the representative investor and λ i are the Pareto weights that depend on the agents endowments. 1.2 On the Impossibility of Frictionless Markets One could argue that, if there were a friction that lead to large costs for agents, then there would be an institutional response to profit by alleviating this friction. According to this view, there cannot be any important) frictions left in equilibrium. Alleviating frictions is costly, however, and the institutions who alleviate frictions may be able to earn rents. For instance, setting up a market requires computers, trading systems, clearing operations, risk and operational controls, legal documentation, marketing, information systems, and so on. Hence, if frictions did not affect prices then the institutions that alleviated the frictions would not be compensated for doing so. Therefore, no one would have an incentive to alleviate frictions, and, hence, markets cannot be frictionless. 1 1.3 Liquidity and Asset Pricing: The Point of Departure If markets are not frictionless, that is, if market are plagued by some form of illiquidity, then the main building blocks of standard asset pricing are shaken. First, the equilibrium aggregation of individuals utility function to a representative investor may not apply. Second, individual investor optimality may not imply that 1) holds with m t = u c t ) at all times and for all securities. This is because an investor need not be marginal on any security if trading frictions make it suboptimal to trade it. Hence, illiquidity implies that we cannot easily derive the stochastic discount factor from consumption, much less from aggregate consumption. Then, what determines asset pricing? Some people might argue that the key cornerstone of standard asset pricing is the mere existence of a stochastic discount factor, not necessarily its relation to consumption. Indeed, powerful results such as the theory of derivative pricing follow from the simple and almost self-evident premise 1 Grossman and Stiglitz 1980) use this argument to rule out informationally efficient markets. 3

of no arbitrage. It is, however, important to recognize that the standard no-arbitrage pricing theory relies not only on the absence of arbitrage, but also on the assumption of frictionless market. To see why the assumption of frictionless market is crucial, consider the basic principle of standard asset pricing: securities, portfolios, or trading strategies with the same cash flows must have the same price. This simple principle is based on the insight that, if securities with identical cash flows have different prices, then an investor could buy with no trading costs the cheaper security and sell with no trading costs the more expensive security, and, hence, realize an immediate arbitrage profit at no risk. Another way to see this is to iterate 1) to get ) m s p t = E t d s 3) m t s=t+1 which shows that the price p t only depends on the pricing kernel and the cash flows d. With trading costs, however, this principle need not apply. Indeed, with transaction costs, securities with the same cash flows can have different prices without introducing arbitrage opportunities. Do real-world securities with the same cash flows have the same price? Perhaps surprisingly, the answer is no, certainly not always. For instance, on-the-run i.e. newly issued) Treasuries often trade at lower yields than almost identical off-the-run Treasuries. Shares that are restricted from trade for a two years trade at an average discount of about 30% relative to shares of the same company with identical dividends that can be traded freely Silber 1991)). Chinese restricted institutional shares, which can be traded only privately, trade at a discount of about 80% relative corresponding exchangetraded shares in the same company Chen and Xiong 2001)). Options than cannot be traded over their life trade at large discounts relative to identical tradable options M. Brenner and Hauser 2001)). The put-call parity is sometimes violated when it is difficult to sell short, implying that a stock trades at a higher price than a synthetic stock created in the option market Ofek, Richardson, and Whitelaw 2004)). Further, in so-called negative stub value situations, a security can trade at a lower price than another security, which has strictly lower cash flows e.g. Lamont and Thaler 2003)). The existence of securities with identical cash flows and different prices implies that there does not exist a stochastic discount factor m that prices all securities, that is, there does not exist an m such that 3) holds for all 4

securities. Another important difference between standard asset pricing and liquidity asset pricing is that the latter sometimes relaxes the assumption of price taking behavior. Indeed, if prices are not always at fundamentals and are affected by the nature of the trading activity, then agents may take this into account. For instance, if an agent is so large that his trades significantly affect prices, he will take this into account, or if agents trade in a bilateral over-the-counter market then prices are privately negotiated. 1.4 Liquidity and Asset Pricing: Where it will Take Us in This Class) The prices of securities are determined by the general equilibrium of the economy. Hence, the price p j t of a security j is some function, say f, of the security s cash flow d j, the cash flows of other securities d k ) k j, the utility functions of all agents u i ) i I, and the agents endowments e i ), p j t = f t d j, d k ) k j, u i ), e i ) ) 4) The strength of a frictionless economy is that a security s cash flows d j and the pricing kernel m are sufficient statistics for this pricing operation as described by Equation 1). This means that the pricing kernel summarizes all the needed information contained in utility functions, endowments, correlations with other securities, etc. In an economy with frictions, prices depend additionally on the liquidity l k ) of all securities, p j t = f t d j,l j, d k ) k j, l k ) k j, u i ), e i ) ) 5) In some models of illiquidity, prices would be arbitrage free even without frictions, and, hence, there exists a pricing kernel m such that 1) holds. In this case, the illiquidity affects m, but the pricing of securities can still be summarized using a pricing kernel. This is the case in models in which certain agents can trade all securities without costs. For instance, in the models of demand pressure and inventory risk that follow?), competitive market makers can trade all securities at no cost which ensures the absence of arbitrage. Garleanu, Poteshman, and Pedersen 2004) show explicitly how m depends on demand pressure in a multi-asset model. 5

In other models of liquidity, however, there is no pricing kernel such that 1) applies. For instance, in the transaction cost models, securities with the same dividend streams have different prices if they have different transaction costs. Hence, a security s transaction costs not only affects the nature of the equilibrium, it is a fundamental attribute of the security. When there does not exist a pricing kernel, then the computation of equilibrium asset prices becomes more difficult. Indeed, the general equilibrium prices with illiquidity may depend on the fundamental parameters in a complicated way that does not have a closed-form expression. Nevertheless, we can derive explicit prices under certain special assumptions such as risk neutrality, specially rigged trading horizons, partial equilibrium, normally distributed dividends, and so on. While the difficulty of general equilibrium with frictions often forces us to use such special assumptions to get closedform results, we can still gain important insights into the main principles of how liquidity affects asset prices. This abstract way of thinking about asset pricing will be much clearer in the context of specific frictions and specific economies. In this class, we will explicitly derive asset prices in the context of fixed transaction costs, inventory risk, asymmetric information, search frictions, and short-sale constraints, and show how these frictions affect optimal trading decisions. Further, we will consider a variety of related topics such as derivative pricing in illiquid markets, and other topics that the participants are interested in. 6