SOLVENCY AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION

Similar documents
Mathematics in Finance

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments

Risk based capital allocation

COHERENT VAR-TYPE MEASURES. 1. VaR cannot be used for calculating diversification

Measures of Contribution for Portfolio Risk

Value at Risk, Expected Shortfall, and Marginal Risk Contribution, in: Szego, G. (ed.): Risk Measures for the 21st Century, p , Wiley 2004.

The Statistical Mechanics of Financial Markets

Risk, Coherency and Cooperative Game

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

A generalized coherent risk measure: The firm s perspective

Lecture 1 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia.

COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF SOME DISTRIBUTIONS ON THE CAPITAL REQUIREMENT DATA FOR THE INSURANCE COMPANY

Coherent Capital for Treaty ROE Calculations

2 Modeling Credit Risk

Maturity as a factor for credit risk capital

Statistical Methods in Financial Risk Management

Study Guide on Non-tail Risk Measures for CAS Exam 7 G. Stolyarov II 1

Financial Risk Forecasting Chapter 4 Risk Measures

Capital Allocation Principles

Value at Risk. january used when assessing capital and solvency requirements and pricing risk transfer opportunities.

Lecture 4 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia.

CAT Pricing: Making Sense of the Alternatives Ira Robbin. CAS RPM March page 1. CAS Antitrust Notice. Disclaimers

An Application of Extreme Value Theory for Measuring Financial Risk in the Uruguayan Pension Fund 1

SOLVENCY, CAPITAL ALLOCATION, AND FAIR RATE OF RETURN IN INSURANCE

A new approach for valuing a portfolio of illiquid assets

Financial Risk Management

Capital requirements, risk measures and comonotonicity

Section B: Risk Measures. Value-at-Risk, Jorion

Financial Risk Management and Governance Beyond VaR. Prof. Hugues Pirotte

Solvency, Capital Allocation and Fair Rate of Return in Insurance

Characterization of the Optimum

Pricing and risk of financial products

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright

Comparative Analyses of Expected Shortfall and Value-at-Risk (2): Expected Utility Maximization and Tail Risk

Financial Risk Measurement/Management

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

Risk management. VaR and Expected Shortfall. Christian Groll. VaR and Expected Shortfall Risk management Christian Groll 1 / 56

Conditional Value-at-Risk: Theory and Applications

Asset Allocation Model with Tail Risk Parity

Risk measures: Yet another search of a holy grail

Risk Reduction Potential

Budget Setting Strategies for the Company s Divisions

Executive Summary: A CVaR Scenario-based Framework For Minimizing Downside Risk In Multi-Asset Class Portfolios

THE UNIVERSITY OF TEXAS AT AUSTIN Department of Information, Risk, and Operations Management

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers

The mathematical definitions are given on screen.

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

A capital allocation based on a solvency exchange option

Optimal capital allocation principles

COMBINING FAIR PRICING AND CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS

Correlation and Diversification in Integrated Risk Models

Sensible and Efficient Capital Allocation for Credit Portfolios

Lecture notes on risk management, public policy, and the financial system. Credit portfolios. Allan M. Malz. Columbia University

Risk Measure and Allocation Terminology

Calculating VaR. There are several approaches for calculating the Value at Risk figure. The most popular are the

Lecture 3 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia.

Can a coherent risk measure be too subadditive?

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

Lecture 6: Risk and uncertainty

Lecture 8. The Binomial Distribution. Binomial Distribution. Binomial Distribution. Probability Distributions: Normal and Binomial

Risk Transfer Testing of Reinsurance Contracts

MEASURING PORTFOLIO RISKS USING CONDITIONAL COPULA-AR-GARCH MODEL

Long-Term Risk Management

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management

Allocation of Risk Capital and Performance Measurement

Minimization of the Total Required Capital by Reinsurance

Random Variables and Probability Distributions

Market Microstructure Invariants

Econ 424/CFRM 462 Portfolio Risk Budgeting

Risk Measurement in Credit Portfolio Models

Lecture 10: Performance measures

Implied Systemic Risk Index (work in progress, still at an early stage)

MODELLING OF INCOME AND WAGE DISTRIBUTION USING THE METHOD OF L-MOMENTS OF PARAMETER ESTIMATION

Aggregating Economic Capital

Economic capital allocation derived from risk measures

Equal Contributions to Risk and Portfolio Construction

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

Operational Risk Aggregation

Dynamic Risk Management in Electricity Portfolio Optimization via Polyhedral Risk Functionals

P2.T8. Risk Management & Investment Management. Jorion, Value at Risk: The New Benchmark for Managing Financial Risk, 3rd Edition.

Coherent allocation of risk capital

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Stochastic Interest Rates

A Preference Foundation for Fehr and Schmidt s Model. of Inequity Aversion 1

Backtesting Expected Shortfall: the design and implementation of different backtests. Lisa Wimmerstedt

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Chapter 2 Managing a Portfolio of Risks

Week 3 Lesson 3. TW3421x - An Introduction to Credit Risk Management The VaR and its derivations Coherent measures of risk and back-testing!

Risk and Management: Goals and Perspective

RISKMETRICS. Dr Philip Symes

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

Expected utility inequalities: theory and applications

VaR Estimation under Stochastic Volatility Models

Stress testing of credit portfolios in light- and heavy-tailed models

Conditional Value-at-Risk, Spectral Risk Measures and (Non-)Diversification in Portfolio Selection Problems A Comparison with Mean-Variance Analysis

MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management. John Dodson. September 6, 2017

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Appropriate risk measures, time horizon and valuation principles in economic capital models

The Use of the Tukey s g h family of distributions to Calculate Value at Risk and Conditional Value at Risk

Transcription:

SOLVENCY AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION HARRY PANJER University of Waterloo JIA JING Tianjin University of Economics and Finance Abstract This paper discusses a new criterion for allocation of required capital. This criterion is uniformly applicable to financial enterprises of all types. A completely natural rule for allocating capital to business units is described. This rule allocates capital in a way that is invariant over the method of decomposing the enterprise into business units. Analytic results are derived in the case of multivariate normal risks. Presented at the International Symposium on Insurance Regulatory Environment and Actuarial Practice in China held October -2, 200 at Renmin University, Beijing.

. Introduction The subject of the determination of risk capital has been of active interest to researchers, of interest to regulators of financial institutions, and of direct interest to commercial vendors of financial products and services. At the international level, the actuarial and accounting professions through the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) and the International Actuarial Association are co-operating in developing a framework for capital requirements for insurance companies. Similarly the Basel Committee (BIS) has been developing capital standards for the banking sector. The concept of Value at Risk (VaR) has become the standard risk measure used to evaluate exposure to risk. In general terms, the VaR is the amount of capital required to ensure, with a high degree of certainty, that the enterprise doesn t become technically insolvent. The degree of certainty chosen is arbitrary. In practice, it can be a high number such as 99.95% for the entire enterprise, or it can be much lower, such as 95%, for a single unit within the enterprise. This lower percentage may reflect the inter-unit diversification that exists. The promotion of concepts such as VaR has prompted the study of risk measures by numerous authors (e.g Wang (996, 997)). Specific desirable properties of risk measures were proposed as axioms in connection with risk pricing by Wang, Young and Panjer (997) and more generally in risk measurement by Artzner et al (999). We consider a random variable X j representing the negative of the possible outcomes of profits, that is the possible losses, arising from a block of business identified with subscript j. Then the total or aggregate losses for several blocks combined is simply the sum of the losses for all blocks combined X = X + X 2 + + X n where n is the number of blocks. The probability distribution of the aggregate losses depends not only on the distributions of the losses for the individual blocks but also on the inter-relationships between them. Correlation is one such measure interrelationship. Correlation is, however, a simple linear relationship that may not capture many aspects of the relationship between the variables. It does however, perform perfectly for describing inter-relationships in the case where the losses from the individual blocks form a multivariate normal distribution. Although the normal assumption is used extensively in connection with the modeling of changes in the logarithm of prices in the stock market, it may not be entirely appropriate for modeling many processes including claims processes. The normal model does however, provide a benchmark and provide insight. 2

There are two broad approaches to the application of risk measurement to complex organizations such as insurance companies and banks. One method is to model each of the risk exposures and assign a capital requirement to each based on the study of that risk exposure (the risk-based capital approach). The total capital requirement is the adjusted sum of the capital requirements for each risk exposure. Some offset may be possible due to a recognition that there may be a diversification or hedging effect of risks that are not perfectly correlated. The second approach uses a model of the entire block of business or of the entire organization (the internal model approach). In this approach a mathematical model is developed to describe the entire organization and incorporates all interactions between blocks of business. In either approach an allocation of the total capital requirement back to the lines is necessary for a variety of reasons, including the measurement of return on capital and the compensation of managers of different units. This paper focuses on that allocation. 2. Risk Measures A risk measure is a mapping from the random variables representing the risks to the real numbers. A risk measure quantifies the risk exposure in a way that is meaningful for the problem at hand. The most commonly used risk measure in finance and statistics is a quantile or Value-at-Risk. The risk measure is simply loss size for which there is a small ( e.g. % ) probability of exceeding. For some time, it has been recognized that this measure suffers from serious deficiencies if losses are not normally distributed. Following Artzner et al. (999), a coherent risk measure is defined as one that has the following properties for any two bounded loss random variables X and Y. Throughout this paper, the risk measure is denoted by the function ρ (.). For this paper, it is convenient to think of ρ(x) as the capital requirement for the risk X.. Subadditivity: ρ(x + Y) ρ(x) + ρ(y) This means that the capital requirement for two risks combined will not be greater than for the risks treated separately. This is necessary, since otherwise companies would have an advantage to disaggregate into smaller companies. 2. Monotonicity: If X Y for any outcome, then ρ(x) ρ(y) This means that if for all possible outcomes, if one risk has greater losses that another, the capital requirement should be greater. 3. Positive Homogeneity: For any positive constant λ, ρ(λx) = λρ(y). This means that the capital requirement is independent of the currency in which the risk is measured. 3

4. Translation invariance For any positive constant α, ρ(x + α) = ρ(x) + α. This means that there is no additional capital requirement for an additional risk for which there is no uncertainty. The q-quantile or VaR The q-quantile, x q, is the smallest value satisfying Pr { X > xq} = q It is the Value-at-Risk and is used extensively in financial risk management of trading risk over a fixed (usually relatively short) time period. It is not a coherent risk measure. The conditional tail expectation or TailVar The conditional tail expectation is given by [ X X xq] E > This is called conditional tail expectation by Wirch (997) and TailVaR by Artzner et al (999). It can be seen that this will be larger that the VaR measure for the same vale of q described above since it can be thought of as the quantile x plus the expected excess q loss. TailVaR is a coherent measure in the sense of Artzner et al (999). The papers by Artzner (999) and Wirch and Hardy (999) on coherent risk measures are potential sources of ideas for the application of this kind of risk measure. Overbeck (2000) also discusses Var and TailVar as risk measures. He argues that Var is an all or nothing risk measure, in that if the extreme event occurs, there is no capital to cushion losses. This is somewhat tautological since the extreme event is one that uses up all the capital. He also argues that TailVar provides a definition of bad times which are those where losses exceed some threshold, not using up all available capital. TailVar the provides the expected excess loss over that threshold, when the threshold has been exceeded. One can define the threshold x q as we have done above in the definition [ X X xq] K = E >. Aleternatively, one can define the threshold by first establishing the quantity K by any method, and then solve to determine the threshold x q which defines the bad times. of Overbeck (2000). 4

3. Allocation of Capital Consider now that the random variable X and the allocation of capital to the individual risks X, X 2,, X n when the capital requirement ρ(x) has been determined for the total risk X. Delbaen and Denault (200) address this question by defining a set of desirable properties for an allocation methodology. They define a coherent allocation method as one that possesses these properties. The notation used by them is as follows. Let K = ρ(x) represent the risk measure for the total risk X. Let K i denote the allocation of K to the i-th risk. The properties are:. Full allocation K + K 2 + + K n = K This means that all of the capital is allocated to the risks. 2. No undercut K a + K b + + K z ρ( X a + X b + + X z ) for any subset {a, b,,z} of {, 2,, n}. This means that any decompositions of the total risk will not increase the capital from that if the risks stood alone. 3. Symmetry Within any decomposition, substitution of one risk X with and otherwise identical risk X 2 will result in no change in the allocations. 4. Riskless allocation The capital allocation to a risk that has no uncertainty is zero. 4. TailVar Allocation Overbeck (2000) discusses a natural extension of TailVar, among other methods, as a basis of allocating capital to the blocks or lines of credit risk. Delbaen and Denault (2000) briefly mention TailVar as well, but focus on game-theoretic methods. Overbeck (2000) and the above authors agree on the basic allocation rule. It is based on the idea that the capital for each risk should be based the contribution to the total capital, that is j [ X X xq] K = E > j 5

This formula is not only simple, but intuitive. The capital required for each risk is precisely the expected contribution to the shortfall. Overbeck (2000) calls this the contribution to shortfall. It is obvious that this allocation method satisfies the four desired properties. Although Overbeck (2000) and Delbaen and Denault (2000) consider other plausible methods, this one seems to have the greatest natural appeal. 5. Application to Multivariate Normal Risks Consider the aggregate risk X = X + X 2 + + X n Where the X j s form a multivariate normal distribution. Note that X itself follows a normal distribution. Denoting its mean and variance by µ and σ, it is straightforward to show that the TailVar can be written as where 2 [ X X > x ] = µ aσ K = E q + ( xq ) a = φ Φ( x and φ(.) and Φ(.) are the probability density function and the cumulative distribution functions of the normal distribution with mean µ and standard deviation σ. To consider the individual allocations, it is sufficient to consider only the case with n = 2 by combining all the risks, except the first one, into the random variable X 2. This will simplify the notation considerably. q ) So consider the aggregate risk X = X + X 2 In this case, with a bit of calculation, one finds the allocation to risk : 2 σ 2 [ X X > x ] = µ + σ ( + ρ ) K = E q a,2. σ Table illustrates how the allocation works for different combinations of parameters. The column headings are as follows: Mean Mean of X StdDev Standard deviation of X Mean 2 Mean of X 2 StdDev 2 Standard deviation of X 2 6

Corr Correlation coefficient Prob Cumulative probability value TailVar Value of TailVar Pr(TailVar) Cumulative probability value at TailVar Alloc Allocation to risk Pr(Alloc ) Cumulative probability at this allocation for risk Alloc 2 Allocation to risk Pr(Alloc 2 ) Cumulative probability at this allocation for risk 2 If the two risks are identical, the proportion allocated to each risk is always 50% independent of the correlation. The size of the TailVar is, of course, dependent on the correlation coefficient. It is interesting to note that the the total capital allocated to risk can be less than the mean. This can only occur in the situation where the correlation coefficient is negative and σ ρ,2. σ This means that in the usual situation where the standard deviation of the risk is small relative to the standard deviation of the rest of the risks represented collectively by risk 2, any hedging provided by a risk will result in credit being given to that risk for hedging. When the above inequality is replaced by equality, as in the last line in Table, the allocation to the risk is exactly zero. 2 TABLE Mean StdDev Mean 2 StdDev 2 Corr Prob TailVar Pr(TailVar) Alloc Pr(Alloc ) Alloc 2 Pr(Alloc 2) 0 0 0 0.99 3.77 0.996 50% 0.97 50% 0.97 0 0 0.5 0.99 4.62 0.996 50% 0.99 50% 0.99 0 0 0.99 5.33 0.996 50% 0.996 50% 0.996 0 0-0.5 0.99 2.67 0.996 50% 0.909 50% 0.909 0 0-0.99 0 0.5 50% 0.5 50% 0.5 0 0 2 0.5 0.99 7.05 0.996 29% 0.978 7% 0.994 0 0 4 0.5 0.99 2.2 0.996 4% 0.959 86% 0.995 0 2 0 4 0.5 0.99 4. 0.996 29% 0.978 7% 0.994 0 0 2-0.5 0.99 4.62 0.996 0% 0.5 00% 0.99 0 0 4-0.5 0.99 9.6 0.996-8% 0.959 08% 0.995 0 2 0 4-0.5 0.99 9.23 0.996 0% 0.978 00% 0.99 References Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J.-M., and Heath, D. (999), Coherent Measures of Risk, Mathematical Finance, 9, 203-228. 7

Artzner, P. (999), Application of Coherent Risk Measures to Capital Requirements in Insurance, North American Actuarial Journal, 3, -25. Delbaen, F. and Denault M.(2000) Coherent Allocation of Risk Capital, Working Paper, ETH RiskLab, Zurich. Overbeck, L. (2000) Allocation of Economic Capital in Loan Portfolios, Measuring Risk in Complex Systems, Franke J., Haerdle W. and Stahl G. (eds), Springer. Wang, S. (996) Premium calculation by transforming the layer premium density, ASTIN Buletin 26, 7-92. Wang, S. (997) Implementation of PH transforms in Ratemaking, Proc. Casualty Actuarial Society. Wang S., Young V. and Panjer H. (997) Axiomatic characterization of insurance prices, Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 2, 73-83. Wirch, J., and Hardy, M. (999) A Synthesis of Risk Measures for Capital Adequacy, Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 25, 337-348. 8