Economics Lecture Sebastiano Vitali

Similar documents
Economics Lecture Sebastiano Vitali

1. Suppose that instead of a lump sum tax the government introduced a proportional income tax such that:

E&G, Ch. 1: Theory of Choice; Utility Analysis - Certainty

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis October 16, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 1

Module 2 THEORETICAL TOOLS & APPLICATION. Lectures (3-7) Topics

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Uncertainty in Equilibrium

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

9 D/S of/for Labor. 9.1 Demand for Labor. Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, April 14, 2009

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

INDIVIDUAL CONSUMPTION and SAVINGS DECISIONS

ECO401 Quiz # 5 February 15, 2010 Total questions: 15

Problem Set 5: Individual and Market Demand. Comp BC

Marginal Utility, Utils Total Utility, Utils

A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

LECTURE 1 : THE INFINITE HORIZON REPRESENTATIVE AGENT. In the IS-LM model consumption is assumed to be a

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Dividend Policy Chapter 16

Introduction to economics for PhD Students of The Institute of Physical Chemistry, PAS Lecture 3 Consumer s choice

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

False_ The average revenue of a firm can be increasing in the firm s output.

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Solutions to Problem Set 1

UNIT 10 EXERCISE ANSWERS UNIT 10 ANSWERS TO EXERCISES EXERCISE 10.1 THE CONSEQUENCES OF PURE IMPATIENCE

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. The Budget Set for Consumers. Indifference Curves are Like a Topographical Map for Utility.

Microeconomics Pre-sessional September Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. Maximizing Utility. The Budget Set for Consumers. Slope =

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

Intro to Economic analysis

Chapter 3. Consumer Behavior

Chapter 19: Intertemporal Choice and Capital Decisions

Consumption and Saving

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function

Problems. 1. Given information: (a) To calculate wealth, we compute:

Problems. units of good b. Consumers consume a. The new budget line is depicted in the figure below. The economy continues to produce at point ( a1, b

MICROECONOMIC THEORY 1

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C

Midterm 1 - Solutions

Economics Lecture Sebastiano Vitali

Mathematical Economics

Midterm Exam No. 2 - Answers. July 30, 2003

Appendix 4.A. A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

ECONOMICS 2. Sponsored by a Grant TÁMOP /2/A/KMR Course Material Developed by Department of Economics,

The Static Model. Consumer Assumptions on the preferences: Consumer. A description of the Model Economy

A. Introduction to choice under uncertainty 2. B. Risk aversion 11. C. Favorable gambles 15. D. Measures of risk aversion 20. E.

ECON 314: MACROECONOMICS II CONSUMPTION

Final Exam Solutions

ECO 100Y INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

NAME: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMIC THEORY SPRING 2008 ECONOMICS 300/010 & 011 Midterm I March 14, 2008

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk

Topic 3: The Standard Theory of Trade. Increasing opportunity costs. Community indifference curves.

a. Write down your budget equation:. b. If you spend all of your income on commodity 1, how much of it could you buy?.

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty

7.3 The Household s Intertemporal Budget Constraint

Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities

Preferences. Rationality in Economics. Indifference Curves

Lecture 4: Consumer Choice

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

UNCERTAINTY AND INFORMATION

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Corporate Finance - Yossi Spiegel

Homework 3 Solutions

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Chapter 4. Consumption and Saving. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Review of Previous Lectures

Midterm 1 - Solutions

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Microeconomics. The Theory of Consumer Choice. N. Gregory Mankiw. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich update C H A P T E R

Economics and Finance,

Problems. the net marginal product of capital, MP'

Economics 101 Section 5

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

1. Compare the following two pairs of goods: (1) Coke and Pepsi, (2) Plane tickets and hotel bookings

NAME: ID # : Intermediate Macroeconomics ECON 302 Spring 2009 Midterm 1

Intermediate Macroeconomics, Sciences Po, Answer Key to Problem Set 9

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

ECON 311 Winter Quarter, 2010 NAME: KEY Prof. Hamilton

Optimal Portfolio Selection

Problem set 2. Filip Rozsypal November 23, 2011

The Economics of Public Policy 7. Market Failures due to Asymmetric Information

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES

A Theory of Leaning Against the Wind

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

Transcription:

Economics Lecture 7 2016-17 Sebastiano Vitali

Course Outline 1 Consumer theory and its applications 1.1 Preferences and utility 1.2 Utility maximization and uncompensated demand 1.3 Expenditure minimization and compensated demand 1.4 Price changes and welfare 1.5 Labour supply, taxes and benefits 1.6 Saving and borrowing

2 Firms, costs and profit maximization 2.1 Firms and costs 2.2 Profit maximization and costs for a price taking firm 3. Industrial organization 3.1 Perfect competition and monopoly 3.2 Oligopoly and games

1.6 Saving and borrowing 1. Choices between income streams 2. The intertemporal budget line and present discounted value 3. Perfect capital markets 4. The simplest model of asset pricing 5. Saving and borrowing decisions 6. Effects an interest rate cut 7. Different borrowing and lending rates

1. Choices between income streams

You can lend at 10%. Choose between A, B and C. 2016 2017 A 10,000 22,000 B 18,000 11,000 C 20,000 11,000

You can lend at 10%. Choose between A, B and C. 2016 2017 A 10,000 22,000 B 18,000 11,000 C 20,000 11,000 C is better than B. If you start with A, lend 10,000 in 2016, get back 11,000 in 2017 you get C. With lending at 10% A and C are

You can lend at 10%. Choose between A, B and C. 2016 2017 A 10,000 22,000 B 18,000 11,000 C 20,000 11,000 C is better than B. If you start with A, lend 10,000 in 2016, get back 11,000 in 2017 you get C. With lending at 10% A and C are indifferent, both are better than B.

2. The intertemporal budget line and present discounted value

Assume you know for sure c 1 2016 2017 (y 0, y 1 ) income y 0 y 1 You can borrow and lend at interest rate r. c 0 Note that 10% interest r = 0.10. c 0 2016 consumption, c 1 2017 consumption Saving at date 0: s 0 = y 0 c 0 (if s 0 < 0 you are borrowing s 0 ) Consumption at date 1 c 1 = y 1 + (1 + r)s 0 = y 1 + (1 +r) (y 0 c 0 ) Budget constraint c 1 = y 1 + (1 +r) (y 0 c 0 )

(1+r) c 1 gradient (1+r) (y 0, y 1 ) Budget constraint c 1 = y 1 + (1 +r) (y 0 c 0 ) is a straight line with gradient (1+r). It can be rearranged to get c 0 c 0 + c 1 = y 0 + y 1 (1+r) (1+r) This straight line meets the horizontal axis at y 0 + y 1

c 0 B (y 0, y 1 ) c 1 ) r ( y y c 1 1 0 0 ) r ( y y c * * 1 1 0 0 ) y (y *, * 1 0 A ) y y ( *, * 1 0 Which budget line would you choose, A or B? Which income stream would you choose (y 0, y 1 ) or?

B (y 0, y 1 ) c 1 ) r ( y y c 1 1 0 0 ) r ( y y c * * 1 1 0 0 ) y (y *, * 1 0 A Which budget line would you choose, A or B? Non satiation implies that B is better than A. Which income stream would you choose (y 0, y 1 ) or? ) y (y *, * 1 0 c 0

Which budget line would you choose, A or B? Non satiation implies that B is better than A. * * Which income stream would you choose (y 0, y 1 ) or (y y )? 0, 1 c 1 Highest value of (y * 0, A y * 1 ) gives highest utility. B (y 0, y 1 ) c 0 y * 0 y ( 1 * 1 r ) c 0 y 0 y ( 1 1 r ) c 0

Present discounted value

Equations of 2 budget lines ) r ( y y ) r ( c c * * 1 1 1 0 1 0 ) r ( y y ) r ( c c 1 1 1 0 1 0 The present discounted value of the income stream (y 0,y 1 ) is y 0 + y 1 (1+r) In this model non satiation implies that any consumer would choose the income stream with the highest present value.

c 1 Which income stream is optimal at interest rate r? (y * 0, y * 1 ) gradient - (1 + r) Which income (y 0, y 1 ) stream is optimal at interest rate r? 0 c 0

c 1 Which income stream is optimal at interest rate r? (y * 0, y * 1 ) (y * 0, y * 1 ) gradient - (1 + r) Which income (y 0, y 1 ) stream is optimal at interest rate r? 0 c 0

c 1 gradient - (1 + r ) Which income stream is optimal at interest rate r? (y * 0, y * 1 ) (y * 0, y * 1 ) Which income (y 0, y 1 ) stream is optimal at interest rate r? 0 c 0

c 1 gradient - (1 + r ) Which income stream is optimal at interest rate r? (y * 0, y * 1 ) (y * 0, y * 1 ) gradient - (1 + r) Which income (y 0, y 1 ) stream is optimal at interest rate r? 0 c 0 (y 0, y 1 )

c 1 gradient - (1 + r ) Which income stream is optimal at interest rate r? (y * 0, y * 1 ) Which income stream is optimal at (y * 0, y * 1 ) gradient - (1 + r) (y 0, y 1 ) interest rate r? 0 c 0 (y 0, y 1 ) Which income stream is optimal depends on the interest rate.

Definition The present discounted value (pdv) at date 0 of an income stream y 0, y 1, y 2,...y t,...y T, paying y t at date t, discounted at an interest rate r is pdv of y 0, y 1,y 2...y t,...y T, is y 0 y ( 1 1 r ) ( 1 y 2 r ) 2...... ( 1 y t r ) t... ( 1 y T r ) T

The pdv of y 0, y 1, y 2,...y t,...y T is the maximum amount of debt at date 0 which you could repay using the entire income stream y 0, y 1, y 2,...y t,...y T. If you get the income stream y 0, y 1, y 2,...y t,...y T, at interest rate r, start with no savings and no debt at date 0, you can follow any consumption path and leave no debt or savings at date T whose pdv c 0 c ( 1 1 r ) ( 1 c 2 r ) 2...... ( 1 c t r ) t... ( 1 is equal to the pdv of the income stream. c T r ) T

3. Perfect capital markets

3. Perfect capital markets a strong assumption

3. Perfect capital markets a strong assumption 1. no uncertainty (can be relaxed)

3. Perfect capital markets a strong assumption 1. no uncertainty (can be relaxed) 2. You can borrow and lend at the same interest rate r.

3. Perfect capital markets a strong assumption 1. no uncertainty (can be relaxed) 2. You can borrow and lend at the same interest rate r. 3. The only constraint on borrowing is that you must have enough income to repay your debt.

3. Perfect capital markets a strong assumption 1. no uncertainty (can be relaxed) 2. You can borrow and lend at the same interest rate r. 3. The only constraint on borrowing is that you must have enough income to repay your debt. Credit crunch???

3. Perfect capital markets a strong assumption 1. no uncertainty (can be relaxed) 2. You can borrow and lend at the same interest rate r. 3. The only constraint on borrowing is that you must have enough income to repay your debt. Credit crunch??? 4. There is a perfect and costless mechanism which ensures that no one takes on loans that they cannot repay and that all debts are repaid.

Credit Crunch Questions Why did households, firms, banks and governments borrow money they are now not able to repay? Why were banks willing to lend to them?

The simplest model of asset pricing

Renowned French artist Bernard Maquin created the Royal Diamond Chess set Valued at over 5 million, it contains diamonds, emeralds, rubies, pearls and sapphires. The king piece alone weighs 165.2 grams of 18 carat yellow gold, 73 rubies and 146 diamonds. Source: http://www.charleshollandercollection.com/chess.html

The simplest model of asset pricing Suppose you own the chess set which you do not like so keep it in the bank, you are only interested in it as an asset. How do you decide whether to sell it now or in 10 years? Suppose everyone knows that the price now is 5 million and the price in 10 years will be 15 million. Selling the chess set now adds 5 million to of your monetary wealth. Selling the chess set in 10 years adds million of your monetary wealth.

The simplest model of asset pricing Suppose you own the chess set which you do not like so keep it in the bank, you are only interested in it as an asset. How do you decide whether to sell it now or in 10 years? Suppose everyone knows that the price now is 5 million and the price in 10 years will be 15 million. Selling the chess set now adds 5 million to the pdv of your monetary wealth. Selling the chess set in 10 years adds million of your monetary wealth.

The simplest model of asset pricing Suppose you own the chess set which you do not like so keep it in the bank, you are only interested in it as an asset. How do you decide whether to sell it now or in 10 years? Suppose everyone knows that the price now is 5 million and the price in 10 years will be 15 million. Selling the chess set now adds 5 million to the pdv of your monetary wealth. Selling the chess set in 10 years adds 15 million to the pdv of your monetary wealth. (1+r) 10

If the alternatives are sell the chess set now or sell in 10 years sell now if 5 million > 15 million (1+r) 10 Sell the chess set in 10 years if 5 million < 15 million (1+r) 10 You are indifferent between selling the chess set now and selling it in 10 years if 5 million = 15 million (1+r) 10

The chess set is unique, there is no other identical chess sets. Now suppose that this is a financial asset that many people (or organisations) own. If 5 million > 15 million everyone wants to sell now. (1+r) 10 If 5 million < 15 million everyone wants to buy now. (1+r) 10 The market can only clear if the current price is 15 million this is a no arbitrage argument. (1+r) 10

More generally no arbitrage arguments in a model with certainty imply that if an asset pays dividends d 1, d 2, d T at dates 1,2 T and is sold at price p T at date T then the price p 0 of the asset at date 0 must be the present discounted value of the dividends + price at date T, that is p 0 d (1 1 r) d2 (1 r) 2 d3 (1 r) 3... d (1 T r) T pt (1 r) T

No arbitrage conditions are very important in standard finance theory. I have assumed no uncertainty and perfect knowledge of what dividends and asset prices will be in the future. No arbitrage arguments can be extended to allow for uncertainty and are the foundation of the Black Scholes model of options pricing. Some financial economists argue that there are considerable limits to arbitrage and that this has important consequences for asset pricing.

The simple asset pricing models assumes that people know what prices will be in the future. The model can be extended to allow for uncertainty under strong assumptions. If an increase in current asset prices leads people to expect that future asset prices will be even higher, an increase in asset prices can increase demand and further increase prices. If a fall in current asset prices leads to people to expect that future asset prices will be even lower, a decrease in asset prices can decrease demand and further decrease prices.

The simple asset pricing models assumes that people know what prices will be in the future. The model can be extended to allow for uncertainty under strong assumptions. If an increase in current asset prices leads people to expect that future asset prices will be even higher, an increase in asset prices can increase demand and further increase prices. If a fall in current asset prices leads to people to expect that future asset prices will be even lower, a decrease in asset prices can decrease demand and further decrease prices.

The simple asset pricing models assumes that people know what prices will be in the future. The model can be extended to allow for uncertainty under strong assumptions. If an increase in current asset prices leads people to expect that future asset prices will be even higher, an increase in asset prices can increase demand and further increase prices. bubbles If a fall in current asset prices leads to people to expect that future asset prices will be even lower, a decrease in asset prices can decrease demand and further decrease prices.

The simple asset pricing models assumes that people know what prices will be in the future. The model can be extended to allow for uncertainty under strong assumptions. If an increase in current asset prices leads people to expect that future asset prices will be even higher, an increase in asset prices can increase demand and further increase prices. bubbles If a fall in current asset prices leads to people to expect that future asset prices will be even lower, a decrease in asset prices can decrease demand and further decrease prices. crashes

5. Saving and borrowing decisions

Assume preferences satisfy the standard assumptions of completeness, transitivity, continuity, nonsatiation and convexity so can be represented by a utility function u(c 0,c 1 ). The consumer maximizes u(c 0,c 1 ) subject to the budget constraint c 0 c ( 1 1 r ) y 0 c 1 (y 0, y 1 ) y ( 1 1 r ) 5. Saving and borrowing decisions At a tangency solution MRS = 1 + r gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0

This household s current consumption at A > current income What should she do borrow or save? c 1 gradient - (1 + r ) A (y 0, y 1 ) 0 c 0

This household s current consumption at A > current income The household borrows and increases present consumption. c 1 gradient - (1 + r ) A (y 0, y 1 ) 0 c 0

This household s current consumption at A < current income What should she do borrow or save? c 1 gradient - (1 + r ) A (y 0, y 1 ) 0 c 0

This household s current consumption at A < current income The household saves. c 1 gradient - (1 + r ) A (y 0, y 1 ) 0 c 0

Interest rates are an important policy instrument Set by central banks Some central banks (e.g. UK, Fed (US), ECB (Eurozone)) have a considerable degree of independence. If tax rates are stable or hard to change interest rates are the main short term policy instrument. Bank of England interest rate October 2008 4.5% October 2009 July 2016 0.5% August 2016-0.25%

18 Jan-75 Jan-77 Jan-79 Jan-81 Jan-83 Jan-85 Jan-87 Jan-89 Jan-91 Jan-93 Jan-95 Jan-97 Jan-99 Jan-01 Jan-03 Jan-05 Jan-07 Jan-09 Jan-11 Jan-13 Jan-15 16 14 12 10 Bank of England base rate 1973-2016 8 6 4 2 0 http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/boeapps/iadb/index.asp?travel=nixrpx &From=Repo&C=13T&G0Xtop.x=1&G0Xtop.y=1

Effects of an interest rate cut

If the interest rate you get on savings falls what do you do? 1. Increase current consumption 2. Decrease current consumption 3. No change in current consumption

If the interest rate you get on savings falls what do you do? 1. Increase current consumption 2. Decrease current consumption 3. No change in current consumption Usually, not generally true

6. Effects an interest rate cut In a simple macro model, cutting the interest rate increases growth increases inflation by increasing investment by firms increasing current consumption by households. The question here is: does the simple consumer theory model imply interest rate cuts increase current consumption?

General Principle If the household can continue to do after the rate change what it did before the rate change the rate change can t make it worse off and usually makes it better off.

An interest rate cut Never makes a borrower worse off Usually makes a borrower better off.

This household borrows gradient - (1 + r ) before the rate cut. c 1 (y 0, y 1 ) A 0 c 0

This household borrows before the rate cut. The substitution effect A to B of the cut increases consumption at date 0. The rate cut never decreases a borrower s utility. Here the rate cut increases utility. c 1 A gradient - (1 + r ) (y 0, y 1 ) B Interest rate cut from r to r. gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0

This household borrows before the rate cut. The substitution effect A to B of the cut increases consumption at date 0. The rate cut never decreases a borrower s utility. Here the rate cut increases utility. c 1 A gradient - (1 + r ) (y 0, y 1 ) B Interest rate cut from r to r. gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0

This household borrows before the rate cut. The substitution effect A to B of the cut increases consumption at date 0. The rate cut never decreases a borrower s utility. Here the rate cut increases utility. c 1 A gradient - (1 + r ) (y 0, y 1 ) B Interest rate cut from r to r. gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0

This household borrows before the rate cut. The substitution effect A to B of the cut increases consumption at date 0. The rate cut never decreases a borrower s utility. Here the rate cut increases utility. c 1 A gradient - (1 + r ) (y 0, y 1 ) B Interest rate cut from r to r. gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0

This household borrows before the rate cut. The substitution effect A to B of the cut increases consumption at date 0. The rate cut never decreases a borrower s utility. Here the rate cut increases utility. If c 0 is normal the income effect B to C increases c 0. c 1 A gradient - (1 + r ) (y 0, y 1 ) B C Interest rate cut from r to r. gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0 Income and substitution effects on c 0 work in the same direction.

Intuition for the effects of an interest cut on a borrower A rate cut makes current consumption relatively cheaper. The substitution effect increases current and decreases future consumption. A borrower is made better off by the rate cut. If current consumption is a normal good the rate cut increases current consumption. Income and substitution effects work in the same direction.

This household saves both before and after the interest rate cut. c 1 gradient - (1 + r ) A B (y 0, y 1 ) 0 c 0

This household saves both before and after the interest rate cut. The substitution effect A to B of the cut increases consumption at date 0. c 1 A (y 0, y 1 ) gradient - (1 + r ) B gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0

This household saves both before and after the interest rate cut. The substitution effect A to B of the cut increases consumption at date 0. c 1 A (y 0, y 1 ) gradient - (1 + r ) B gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0

This household saves both before and after the interest rate cut. The substitution effect A to B of the cut increases consumption at date 0. c 1 A (y 0, y 1 ) gradient - (1 + r ) B gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0

This household saves both before and after the interest rate cut. The substitution effect A to B of the cut increases consumption at date 0. c 1 A (y 0, y 1 ) gradient - (1 + r ) B gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0

This household saves both before and after the interest rate cut. The substitution effect A to B of the cut increases consumption at date 0. The household has lower utility c 1 gradient - (1 + r ) A B C gradient (y 0, y 1 ) - (1 + r) after the rate cut the income effect B to C 0 c 0 decreases c 0 consumption at date 0. Income and substitution effects on c 0 work in the opposite direction.

Intuition for the effects of an interest cut on a saver The substitution effect is the same as for a borrower; it increases current consumption. If the household continues to save after the rate cut it is worse off; the income effect gives a decrease in income in which case If current consumption is a normal good the rate cut decreases current consumption. Income and substitution effects work in opposite directions.

Someone who saves before the rate cut and borrows after the rate cut may have higher or lower utility after the rate cut. Here she has higher utility after the rate cut. c 1 A (y 0, y 1 ) gradient - (1 + r ) gradient B - (1 + r) 0 c 0 Income and substitution effects on c 0 work in the same direction.

Someone who saves before the rate cut and c 1 gradient - (1 + r ) borrows after the rate cut may have higher or lower utility after the rate cut. A Here she has higher utility after the rate cut. (y 0, y 1 ) C gradient B - (1 + r) 0 c 0 Income and substitution effects on c 0 work in the same direction.

Someone who saves before the rate cut and borrows after the rate cut c 1 A gradient - (1 + r ) may have higher or lower utility after the rate cut. Here she has lower utility at the low rate. (y 0, y 1 ) B gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0 Income and substitution effects on c 0 work in the opposite direction.

Someone who saves before the rate cut and borrows after the rate cut c 1 A gradient - (1 + r ) may have higher or lower utility after the rate cut. Here she has lower utility at the low rate. (y 0, y 1 ) C B gradient - (1 + r) 0 c 0 Income and substitution effects on c 0 work in the opposite direction.

Intuition for the effects of an interest cut on a saver The substitution effect is the same as for a borrower; it increases current consumption. If the household saves before the rate cut and borrows after it may be better off or worse off after the rate cut. If the household is better off the income effect increases current consumption, income and substitution effects work in the same direction. If the household is worse off the income effect decreases current consumption, income and substitution effects work in opposite directions.

7. Different borrowing and lending rates

7. Different borrowing and lending rates Banks make a profit on the difference between the rate at which they borrow and the rate at which they lend or invest their money. In the standard simple model competition in banking leads to 0 bank profits so borrowing and lending rates are the same. Where borrowers from banks may default the interest rate at which banks lend has to be higher than the rate at which they borrow if banks are not to make losses. In 2008 banks were unwilling to lend to each other, due to worries about default due to bank failure.

Sometimes it is possible to borrow at a low rate and invest at a higher rate If this can be done on an unlimited scale it can make unlimited profits. Carry trade. Borrow in Japanese yen, sell yen, buy another currency to invest at a higher rate. Buy yen, repay loan. But How risky is your investment? What about exchange rate risk?

at date 1 (y 0,y 1 ) borrowing or saving? different borrowing and lending rates at date 0

at date 1 save (y 0,y 1 ) different borrowing and lending rates at date 0

borrowing or saving? at date 1 (y 0,y 1 ) different borrowing and lending rates at date 0

at date 1 (y 0,y 1 ) borrow different borrowing and lending rates at date 0

different borrowing and lending rates at date 1 borrowing or saving? (y 0,y 1 ) at date 0

different borrowing and lending rates at date 1 (y 0,y 1 ) neither borrow nor save at date 0

at date 1 save at date 1 (y 0,y 1 ) (y 0,y 1 ) borrow different borrowing and lending rates at date 1 (y 0,y 1 ) at date 0 neither borrow nor save at date 0 borrow at rate r, steeper budget line gradient 1 + r save at rate r < r at date 0 flatter budget line gradient 1 + r

at date 1 (y 0,y 1 ) at date 0 Budget constraint with different borrowing and saving rates and a credit limit.

In the simple model borrowing and saving interest rates are the same and there is no credit limit. It is optimal to choose the income stream with the highest pdv regardless of preferences. at date 1 If there are different interest rates for borrowing and lending or credit limits the choice between income streams depends on preferences. (y 0,y 1 ) (y 0,y 1 ) at date 0

Have you got both debt and savings? In this model if the rate at which you borrow is higher than the rate you get on saving it is optimal to use your savings to pay off your debt.

Have you got both debt and savings? In this model if the rate at which you borrow is higher than the rate you get on saving it is optimal to use your savings to pay off your debt. Possible exception you can continue to borrow now but might not be able to borrow in the future.

What have we achieved? A very simple model of borrowing and saving. Shows ambiguous effects of interest changes on spending and saving. Explained why present discounted value can be used to value income streams. No uncertainty but see more sophisticated models of finance.