Robust Portfolio Choice and Indifference Valuation

Similar documents
Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Control Improvement for Jump-Diffusion Processes with Applications to Finance

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Asymmetric information in trading against disorderly liquidation of a large position.

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Pricing and hedging in incomplete markets

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Exponential utility maximization under partial information and sufficiency of information

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Robustness, Model Uncertainty and Pricing

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Martingale invariance and utility maximization

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

Utility indifference valuation for non-smooth payoffs on a market with some non tradable assets

On worst-case investment with applications in finance and insurance mathematics

Optimal investments under dynamic performance critria. Lecture IV

Indifference fee rate 1

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Robust Portfolio Decisions for Financial Institutions

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Doubly reflected BSDEs with jumps and generalized Dynkin games

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Risk Neutral Valuation

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

UNCERTAINTY AND VALUATION

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

Anumericalalgorithm for general HJB equations : a jump-constrained BSDE approach

Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Optimal Execution: IV. Heterogeneous Beliefs and Market Making

On modelling of electricity spot price

Carnegie Mellon University Graduate School of Industrial Administration

Spot and forward dynamic utilities. and their associated pricing systems. Thaleia Zariphopoulou. UT, Austin

Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging

Mean-variance hedging when there are jumps

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Real Options and Free-Boundary Problem: A Variational View

Sample Path Large Deviations and Optimal Importance Sampling for Stochastic Volatility Models

Control. Econometric Day Mgr. Jakub Petrásek 1. Supervisor: RSJ Invest a.s.,

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Exact replication under portfolio constraints: a viability approach

Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Computing Bounds on Risk-Neutral Measures from the Observed Prices of Call Options

A Robust Option Pricing Problem

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

Optimal Acquisition of a Partially Hedgeable House

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

ABOUT THE PRICING EQUATION IN FINANCE

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

Enlargement of filtration

Hedging under Arbitrage

An example of indifference prices under exponential preferences

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

induced by the Solvency II project

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

ON MAXIMIZING DIVIDENDS WITH INVESTMENT AND REINSURANCE

Effectiveness of CPPI Strategies under Discrete Time Trading

Stochastic Partial Differential Equations and Portfolio Choice. Crete, May Thaleia Zariphopoulou

The minimal entropy martingale measure

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

The Uncertain Volatility Model

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Kim Weston (Carnegie Mellon University) Market Stability and Indifference Prices. 1st Eastern Conference on Mathematical Finance.

King s College London

A Model with Costly-State Verification

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Efficient Market Making via Convex Optimization, and a Connection to Online Learning

Mgr. Jakub Petrásek 1. May 4, 2009

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

European option pricing under parameter uncertainty

Hans-Fredo List Swiss Reinsurance Company Mythenquai 50/60, CH-8022 Zurich Telephone: Facsimile:

Time-delayed backward stochastic differential equations: the theory and applications

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Recovering portfolio default intensities implied by CDO quotes. Rama CONT & Andreea MINCA. March 1, Premia 14

Portability, salary and asset price risk: a continuous-time expected utility comparison of DB and DC pension plans

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

Transcription:

and Indifference Valuation Mitja Stadje Dep. of Econometrics & Operations Research Tilburg University joint work with Roger Laeven July, 2012 http://alexandria.tue.nl/repository/books/733411.pdf

Setting An agent starts with an initial wealth, say x, which he can invest into a riskless bond and several risky assets. At maturity time T the agent will additionally receive a payoff H. How can the agent determine his optimal portfolio strategy? To answer this question one first has to address the following issues: How to model the payoff and the risky asset? How to evaluate the quality of the agent s portfolio strategy? Which constraints to impose on the trading strategies allowed?

Setting For the dynamics of the assets we assume a continuous-time setting with jumps and ambiguity. Ambiguity: True probabilistic model is unknown. Jumps: Economic shocks like financial crashes, unexpected announcements of the ECB, environmental disasters causing sudden movements in prices.

Setting Consider a probability space (Ω, F, P) with two independent stochastic processes: A standard d-dimensional Brownian Motion W. A Poisson counting measure N(ds, dx) on [0, T ] R \ {0} with compensator ˆN(ds, ω, dx) = n(s, ω, dx)ds. We assume that the measure n(s, dx) is predictable and satisfies sup ( x 2 1)n(s, dx) <. s R\{0} Define Ñ(ds, dx) = N(ds, dx) n(s, dx)ds.

Setting Consider a probability space (Ω, F, P) with two independent stochastic processes: A standard d-dimensional Brownian Motion W. A Poisson counting measure N(ds, dx) on [0, T ] R \ {0} with compensator ˆN(ds, ω, dx) = n(s, ω, dx)ds. We assume that the measure n(s, dx) is predictable and satisfies sup ( x 2 1)n(s, dx) <. s R\{0} Define Ñ(ds, dx) = N(ds, dx) n(s, dx)ds.

Setting Consider a probability space (Ω, F, P) with two independent stochastic processes: A standard d-dimensional Brownian Motion W. A Poisson counting measure N(ds, dx) on [0, T ] R \ {0} with compensator ˆN(ds, ω, dx) = n(s, ω, dx)ds. We assume that the measure n(s, dx) is predictable and satisfies sup ( x 2 1)n(s, dx) <. s R\{0} Define Ñ(ds, dx) = N(ds, dx) n(s, dx)ds.

We assume that the financial market consists of one bond with interest rate zero and n d stocks. The return of stock i under a reference measure P evolves according to dst i St i = btdt i + σtdw i i t + βt(x)ñ(dt, dx), i = 1,..., n, R\{0} where b i, σ i, β i are R, R d, R-valued, predictable, uniformly bounded, stochastic processes. Assume β i > 1 for i = 1,..., n. Set b = (b i ) i=1,...,n σ t = (σt) i i=1,...,n, and β = (β i ) i=1,...,n. Further suppose σ has full rank and is uniformly elliptic, and sup β s (x) 2 n(s, dx) <. Write β L,2. s R\{0}

Denote by πt i the amount of money invested in the i-th risky asset at time t. Denote by (X (π) t ) the wealth process of a trading strategy π with initial capital x. In other words X (π) t is the total value of the portfolio at time t. Definition Let U be a compact set in R 1 n. The set of admissible trading strategies A consists of all n-dimensional predictable processes π = (π t ) 0 t T which satisfy π t U dp ds a.s.

Denote by πt i the amount of money invested in the i-th risky asset at time t. Denote by (X (π) t ) the wealth process of a trading strategy π with initial capital x. In other words X (π) t is the total value of the portfolio at time t. Definition Let U be a compact set in R 1 n. The set of admissible trading strategies A consists of all n-dimensional predictable processes π = (π t ) 0 t T which satisfy π t U dp ds a.s.

Choice under uncertainty Specifying the measure P implies estimating σ t, b t, and β t (x)n(t, dx). However, since the trader does not know these quantities he faces ambiguity. Many approaches in the literature to make choices under uncertainty are based on axiomatic foundations of preferences: Decision criteria for a payoff H: Subjective expected utility: U(H) = E Q [u(h)], Savage (1954). Multiple priors: U(H) = min Q M E Q [u(h)], Gilboa and Schmeidler (1989). Variational preferences: U(H) = min Q {E Q [u(h)] + c(q)}, Maccheroni, Marinacci and Rustichini (2006).

The portfolio selection problem Let H be a bounded contingent claim. We start with a probabilistic reference model P. The class of all alternative models considered will be given by Q = {Q Q P}. The robust portfolio selection problem is given by (π) V (H) = max U(H + X π A T ), where X (π) is the wealth process arising from an portfolio strategy π. U is an evaluation based on variational preference.

The portfolio selection problem Let H be a bounded contingent claim. We start with a probabilistic reference model P. The class of all alternative models considered will be given by Q = {Q Q P}. The robust portfolio selection problem is given by (π) V (H) = max U(H + X π A T ), where X (π) is the wealth process arising from an portfolio strategy π. U is an evaluation based on variational preference.

Different probabilistic models What does a different model Q Q entail for the evolution of the asset return? Let P be the predictable σ-algebra. One can show that every model Q is uniquely characterized by a predictable drift (q t ), a P B(R \ {0})-measurable ψ s (x) such that under the model Q: W t t 0 q sds is a Brownian motion. N(ds, dx) has a compensator given by n Q (s, dx) = (1 + ψ s (x))n(s, dx).

Different probabilistic models What does a different model Q Q entail for the evolution of the asset return? Let P be the predictable σ-algebra. One can show that every model Q is uniquely characterized by a predictable drift (q t ), a P B(R \ {0})-measurable ψ s (x) such that under the model Q: W t t 0 q sds is a Brownian motion. N(ds, dx) has a compensator given by n Q (s, dx) = (1 + ψ s (x))n(s, dx).

The choice of the penalty function A standard example for the penalty function is the relative entropy, i.e., ( dq ) c(q) = γh(q P) = γe Q [log ], γ > 0 dp see for instance Hansen and Sargent (1995, 2000, 2001). In our setting it may be seen that H(Q P) = E Q [ T with r 1 (q) = q 2 2, r 2 (y) = 0 { } ] r 1 (q s ) + r 2 (ψ s (x))n(s, dx) ds, R\{0} { (1 + y) log(1 + y) y, if y 1;, otherwise.

The choice of the penalty function A standard example for the penalty function is the relative entropy, i.e., ( dq ) c(q) = γh(q P) = γe Q [log ], γ > 0 dp see for instance Hansen and Sargent (1995, 2000, 2001). In our setting it may be seen that H(Q P) = E Q [ T with r 1 (q) = q 2 2, r 2 (y) = 0 { } ] r 1 (q s ) + r 2 (ψ s (x))n(s, dx) ds, R\{0} { (1 + y) log(1 + y) y, if y 1;, otherwise.

Assumptions The plausibility index c is of the form c(q) = E Q [ T 0 { } ] r 1 (s, q s ) + r 2 (s, x, ψ s (x))n(s, dx) ds, R\{0} for convex non-negative functions r 1 and r 2 which are continuous on their domain with r 1 (t, 0) = r 2 (t, x, 0) = 0.

Assumptions There exist K 1, K 2 > 0 such that c(q) K 1 + K 2 H(Q P)). There exist a ˆK 1, ˆK 2, q r 1 (t, q) ˆK 1 + ˆK 2 q. Furthermore, for every C > 0 there exist ˆK 3 > 0 and a process ˆK 4 (x) L,2 such that y r 2 (t, x, y) ˆK 4 (x) + ˆK 3 log(1 + y) for y [ 1, C]. u is linear, exponential, or logarithmic.

Assumptions There exist K 1, K 2 > 0 such that c(q) K 1 + K 2 H(Q P)). There exist a ˆK 1, ˆK 2, q r 1 (t, q) ˆK 1 + ˆK 2 q. Furthermore, for every C > 0 there exist ˆK 3 > 0 and a process ˆK 4 (x) L,2 such that y r 2 (t, x, y) ˆK 4 (x) + ˆK 3 log(1 + y) for y [ 1, C]. u is linear, exponential, or logarithmic.

Assumptions There exist K 1, K 2 > 0 such that c(q) K 1 + K 2 H(Q P)). There exist a ˆK 1, ˆK 2, q r 1 (t, q) ˆK 1 + ˆK 2 q. Furthermore, for every C > 0 there exist ˆK 3 > 0 and a process ˆK 4 (x) L,2 such that y r 2 (t, x, y) ˆK 4 (x) + ˆK 3 log(1 + y) for y [ 1, C]. u is linear, exponential, or logarithmic.

Relation to previous works Static Duality methods: Biagini and Frittelli (2004), Schachermayer (2004). BSDEs have been used in utility maximization problems in a Brownian framework by Skiadas (2003), Hu, Imkeller and Müller (2005), Cheridito and Hu (2010), or Horst et al. (2011). in a framework with continuous or non-continuous filtrations by Mania and Schweizer (2005), Becherer (2006), Bordigoni et al. (2007), or Morlais (2009a), in a framework with unpredictable jumps in the asset price by Jeanblanc et al. (2009), or Morlais (2009b), (2010). in a Brownian framework for evaluations given by BSDEs by Klöppel and Schweizer (2005) and Sturm and Sircar (2011) in utility maximization with ambiguity by Müller (2005), Delong (2011) and Øksendal and Sulem (2011).

Relation to previous works Static Duality methods: Biagini and Frittelli (2004), Schachermayer (2004). BSDEs have been used in utility maximization problems in a Brownian framework by Skiadas (2003), Hu, Imkeller and Müller (2005), Cheridito and Hu (2010), or Horst et al. (2011). in a framework with continuous or non-continuous filtrations by Mania and Schweizer (2005), Becherer (2006), Bordigoni et al. (2007), or Morlais (2009a), in a framework with unpredictable jumps in the asset price by Jeanblanc et al. (2009), or Morlais (2009b), (2010). in a Brownian framework for evaluations given by BSDEs by Klöppel and Schweizer (2005) and Sturm and Sircar (2011) in utility maximization with ambiguity by Müller (2005), Delong (2011) and Øksendal and Sulem (2011).

u linear The optimization problem is V (H) = max π U(H + X (π) T ). Assume first that u is linear. Define { } g 1 (t, z) : = sup zq r 1 (t, q) ; q R d { } g 2 (t, x, z) : = sup y R y z r 2 (t, x, y) Note that and g i 0 are convex functions with minimum g 1 (t, 0) = g 2 (t, x, 0) = 0.

u linear The optimization problem is V (H) = max π U(H + X (π) T ). Assume first that u is linear. Define { } g 1 (t, z) : = sup zq r 1 (t, q) ; q R d { } g 2 (t, x, z) : = sup y R y z r 2 (t, x, y) Note that and g i 0 are convex functions with minimum g 1 (t, 0) = g 2 (t, x, 0) = 0.

Variational preferences with a linear u If u is linear the dynamic evaluation according to variational preferences is given by } [ ] U t (H) = min {E Q H F t c t (Q). Q Q We can show that there exist unique suitably integrable processes Z and Z such that T [ U t (H) = H g 1 (s, Z s ) + g 2 (s, x, Z ] s (x))n(s, dx) ds t T + Z s dw s + t T t R\{0} R\{0} Z s (x)ñ(ds, dx)

Variational preferences with a linear u If u is linear the dynamic evaluation according to variational preferences is given by } [ ] U t (H) = min {E Q H F t c t (Q). Q Q We can show that there exist unique suitably integrable processes Z and Z such that T [ U t (H) = H g 1 (s, Z s ) + g 2 (s, x, Z ] s (x))n(s, dx) ds t T + Z s dw s + t T t R\{0} R\{0} Z s (x)ñ(ds, dx)

Theorem Suppose that we start with functions g 1, g 2 0 with g 1 (t, 0) = g 2 (t, x, 0) = 0. Assume further: (a) There exists K > 0 such that g 1 (t, z) K (1 + z 2 ). For every C > 0 there exists K > 0 and K L 2, such that g 2 (t, x, z) K (x) + K z 2 for all z C. (b) z g 1 (t, z) K(1 + z ) for z 1, z 2 R d (c) For every C > 0 there exists ˆK > 0 and H L,2 such that y g 2 (t, x, y) H(x) + ˆK y for x R and y [ 1, C]. Then for every bounded terminal condition F the corresponding BSDE with driver g(t, z, z) = g 1 (t, z) + R\{0} g 2(t, z(x))n(t, dx) has a unique bounded solution.

Define f (t, z, z) : = min { πb t + g 1 (t, z πσ t ) π U + g 2 (t, x, z(x) πβ(x))n(t, dx)}. R\{0} Theorem Let (Y t, Z t, Z t ) be the unique solution of the BSDE with terminal condition H and driver function f. Then we have V (H) = Y 0 + x. Furthermore, the optimal strategy is given by the strategy π which attains the minimum in f (t, Z t, Z t ).

Define f (t, z, z) : = min { πb t + g 1 (t, z πσ t ) π U + g 2 (t, x, z(x) πβ(x))n(t, dx)}. R\{0} Theorem Let (Y t, Z t, Z t ) be the unique solution of the BSDE with terminal condition H and driver function f. Then we have V (H) = Y 0 + x. Furthermore, the optimal strategy is given by the strategy π which attains the minimum in f (t, Z t, Z t ).

Interpretation f (t, z, z) = min { πb t + g 1 (t, z πσ t ) π U + g 2 (t, x, z(x) πβ(x))n(t, dx)}. R\{0} When choosing π the trader faces a tradeoff between: (a) Getting the excess return π s b s. (b) Diminishing the fluctuation of the future payoff coming from the locally Gaussian part, this means choosing π such that Z s π s σ s is small. (c) Diminishing the fluctuation of the future payoff coming from the jumps, this means choosing π such that Z s π s β s is small.

Relationship of the optimal portfolio selection problem and the excess return The KKT conditions yields that there exists Lagrange multiplier µ, ζ R n with µ, ζ 0 such that b s = (µ s ζs ) σ s z g 1 (s, z πσ s ) z g 2 (s, x, z s (x) πβ s (x))β s (x)n(s, dx) R\{0} where: = A + B + C, A: Sensitivity of f with respect to the constraints. B : Sensitivity of f with respect to Z, the fluctuation of the evaluation due to the Brownian motion. C : Sensitivity of f with respect to Z, the fluctuation of the evaluation due to the jumps.

Multiple priors with a CARA utility function Start again with a reference model P. Let M be the set of all models which are close to P. Specifically choose λ 0 and P B(R \ {0})-measurable processes d (x), d + (x) L,2 Denote { } M := Q P q λ, and ds (x) ψ s (x) d s + (x). With a CARA utility function the problem becomes [ ] V (H) = max min exp{ α(h + X (π) π T )} Q M E Q for α > 0.

Ambiguity with a CARA utility function Theorem We have V (F ) = exp{ α(x + Y 0 )} where Y is the unique solution of the backward stochastic equation with terminal payoff H and driver function { min π U πb t + α 2 Z t πσ t 2 + λ Z t πσ t + 1 ( ) exp{α( Z t (x) πβ t (x))} α( Z t (x) πβ t (x)) 1 α ( ) + d s + (x)i + d {πβt(x) Z t(x)} s (x)i {πβt(x) Z t(x)} ( ) exp α( Z t (x) πβ t (x) 1}, α Furthermore, the optimal portfolio strategy is given by π which minimizes the expression above.

Ambiguity with a CARA utility function Theorem We have V (F ) = exp{ α(x + Y 0 )} where Y is the unique solution of the backward stochastic equation with terminal payoff H and driver function { min π U πb t + α 2 Z t πσ t 2 + λ Z t πσ t + 1 ( ) exp{α( Z t (x) πβ t (x))} α( Z t (x) πβ t (x)) 1 α ( ) + d s + (x)i + d {πβt(x) Z t(x)} s (x)i {πβt(x) Z t(x)} ( ) exp α( Z t (x) πβ t (x) 1}, α Furthermore, the optimal portfolio strategy is given by π which minimizes the expression above.

Numerical Results Assume a degenerate one point jump distribution with intensity 1. We consider a European put option with strike price 2 and time-to-maturity of 0.5 years. We take b = 0.04, σ = 0.2, a = 1, β = 0.03, u upper = 10 and u lower = 0. The number of simulations is 10,000.

1.20 1.15 1.10 1.05 1.00 0.95 0.90 0 30 60 90 (i) no ambiguity, no hedge (long dashes with cross); (ii) no ambiguity, with hedge (long dashes); (iii) Brownian ambiguity only (λ = 0.25), with hedge (dashes); (iv) jump ambiguity only (d = 0.25 and d + = 0.5), with hedge (short dashes); (v) both Brownian ambiguity and jump ambiguity (λ = 0.25, d = 0.25 and d + = 0.5) with hedge. (dots)

The KKT conditions of the optimization problem yield b t = A + B + C + D + E A: Due to the hedging constraints. B : Due to the risk coming from the Brownian part. Vanishes if α 0, or if there is no Gaussian part. C : Due to the risk coming from the jumps. Vanishes if α 0, or if there are no jumps. D : Due to the ambiguity coming from the Brownian motion. Vanishes as λ 0. E : Due to the ambiguity coming from the jumps. Vanishes if d +, d 0, or if there are no jumps.

Variational preferences with a logarithmic utility We will consider trading strategies ρ which denote the part of wealth invested in stock i. The admissible trading strategies are supposed to take values in a compact set C and ρ s β s 1 + ɛ. We denote the wealth process corresponding to a trading strategy ρ with initial capital x by X (ρ).

Portfolio selection problem with a logarithmic utility We want to maximize [ inf Q Q E Q log ( X (ρ) ) T T + t over all admissible strategies ρ. Let f (s, z, z) : = inf ρ C { ρb s + R\{0} g 1 (t, z ρσ s ) + ρ 2 2 { } ] r 1 (s, q s ) + r 2 (s, x, ψ(x)n(s, dx) ds, R\{0} g 2 (s, x, z(x) log(1 + ρβ s (x)))n(s, dx) R\{0} } [log(1 + ρβ s (x)) + ρβ s (x)]n(s, dx).

Robust portfolio selection with a logarithmic utility Denote by Y the solution of the BSDE T T T Y t = 0+ f (s, Z s, Z s )ds Z s dw s Z t (x)ñ(ds, dx). t t t R\{0} Theorem The BSDE has a unique solution and the value of the portfolio selection problem under ambiguity with a logarithmic utility is given by V (x) = Y 0 + log(x). Furthermore, the optimal strategy is given by the trading strategy ρ which attains the minimum in the driver function f (t, Z t, Z t ).

Robust portfolio selection with a logarithmic utility Denote by Y the solution of the BSDE T T T Y t = 0+ f (s, Z s, Z s )ds Z s dw s Z t (x)ñ(ds, dx). t t t R\{0} Theorem The BSDE has a unique solution and the value of the portfolio selection problem under ambiguity with a logarithmic utility is given by V (x) = Y 0 + log(x). Furthermore, the optimal strategy is given by the trading strategy ρ which attains the minimum in the driver function f (t, Z t, Z t ).