Modeling Yields at the Zero Lower Bound: Are Shadow Rates the Solution?

Similar documents
Transmission of Quantitative Easing: The Role of Central Bank Reserves

A Probability-Based Stress Test of Federal Reserve Assets and Income

A Probability-Based Stress Test of Federal Reserve Assets and Income

A Probability-Based Stress Test of Federal Reserve Assets and Income

Market Price of Longevity Risk for A Multi-Cohort Mortality Model with Application to Longevity Bond Option Pricing

Term Structure Analysis with Big Data

Tomi Kortela. A Shadow rate model with timevarying lower bound of interest rates

Term Structure Models with Negative Interest Rates

Extrapolating Long-Maturity Bond Yields for Financial Risk Measurement

A Multifrequency Theory of the Interest Rate Term Structure

Linearity-Generating Processes, Unspanned Stochastic Volatility, and Interest-Rate Option Pricing

Predictability of Interest Rates and Interest-Rate Portfolios

Understanding and Influencing the Yield Curve at the Zero Lower Bound

Linear-Rational Term-Structure Models

State Space Estimation of Dynamic Term Structure Models with Forecasts

European spreads at the interest rate lower bound

Monetary Policy Expectations at the Zero Lower Bound

Time-Varying Lower Bound of Interest Rates in Europe

Valuing the Probability. of Generating Negative Interest Rates. under the Vasicek One-Factor Model

Estimation of dynamic term structure models

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Valuing the Probability of Generating Negative Interest Rates under the Vasicek One-Factor Model

The Effectiveness of Alternative Monetary Policy Tools in a Zero Lower Bound Environment

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Staff Working Paper No. 763 Estimating nominal interest rate expectations: overnight indexed swaps and the term structure

Predictability of Interest Rates and Interest-Rate Portfolios

Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations

European option pricing under parameter uncertainty

Market risk measurement in practice

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Numerical schemes for SDEs

Interest Rate Curves Calibration with Monte-Carlo Simulatio

School of Economics. Honours Thesis. The Role of No-Arbitrage Restrictions in Term Structure Models. Bachelor of Economics

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

A Macro-Finance Model of the Term Structure: the Case for a Quadratic Yield Model

Market interest-rate models

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Monte Carlo Methods for Uncertainty Quantification

Measuring the stance of monetary policy in zero lower bound environments. Leo Krippner. August JEL classi cation: E43, G12, G13

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model

On VIX Futures in the rough Bergomi model

Resolving the Spanning Puzzle in Macro-Finance Term Structure Models

The Black-Scholes Model

Exploring Volatility Derivatives: New Advances in Modelling. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY

Monetary Policy and Stock Market Boom-Bust Cycles by L. Christiano, C. Ilut, R. Motto, and M. Rostagno

The Black-Scholes Model

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Torben G. Andersen

The Information Content of the Yield Curve

Predictability of Interest Rates and Interest-Rate Portfolios

Financial Risk Management

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting MarketAFA, Disruptions 1/7/ / 14

Model Estimation. Liuren Wu. Fall, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu Model Estimation Option Pricing, Fall, / 16

Inflation risks and inflation risk premia

King s College London

Hedging of swaptions in a Lévy driven Heath-Jarrow-Morton framework

Smooth estimation of yield curves by Laguerre functions

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Lecture 3: Forecasting interest rates

Forecasting Interest Rates and Exchange Rates under Multi-Currency Quadratic Models

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

MLEMVD: A R Package for Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Multivariate Diffusion Models

Estimating Nominal Interest Rate Expectations: Overnight Indexed Swaps and the Term Structure

Real-time forecasting with macro-finance models in the presence of a zero lower bound. Leo Krippner and Michelle Lewis. March 2018

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/ / 24

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

Estimating Term Premia at the Zero

Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

Alternative VaR Models

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

A discretionary stopping problem with applications to the optimal timing of investment decisions.

Statistical Methods in Financial Risk Management

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Rue de la Banque No. 52 November 2017

Market Anticipation of Fed Policy Changes and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Economics 883: The Basic Diffusive Model, Jumps, Variance Measures. George Tauchen. Economics 883FS Spring 2015

Financial Risk Management

Polynomial Models in Finance

Risk Management and Time Series

Modelling Credit Spread Behaviour. FIRST Credit, Insurance and Risk. Angelo Arvanitis, Jon Gregory, Jean-Paul Laurent

Volatility Trading Strategies: Dynamic Hedging via A Simulation

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Optimal Search for Parameters in Monte Carlo Simulation for Derivative Pricing

Duration-Risk versus Local Supply Channel in Treasury Yields: Evidence from the Federal Reserve s Asset Purchase Announcements

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

Term Structure Models Workshop at AFIR-ERM Colloquium, Panama, 2017

A New Approach to Asset Integration: Methodology and Mystery. Robert P. Flood and Andrew K. Rose

Working paper. An approach to setting inflation and discount rates

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

We consider three zero-coupon bonds (strips) with the following features: Bond Maturity (years) Price Bond Bond Bond

The Self-financing Condition: Remembering the Limit Order Book

A New Class of Non-linear Term Structure Models. Discussion

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Interest rate modelling: How important is arbitrage free evolution?

TOHOKU ECONOMICS RESEARCH GROUP

Estimating Term Structure of U.S. Treasury Securities: An Interpolation Approach

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

Value at Risk Ch.12. PAK Study Manual

Transcription:

Modeling Yields at the Zero Lower Bound: Are Shadow Rates the Solution? Jens H. E. Christensen & Glenn D. Rudebusch Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Term Structure Modeling and the Lower Bound Problem Day 2: The Lower Bound Problem Lecture II.2 European University Institute Florence, September 8, 2015 The views expressed here are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 1 / 36

Overview of Paper 2 / 36 We compare the shadow-rate arbitrage-free Nelson-Siegel (AFNS) model derived in Christensen and Rudebusch (2015a) to a standard Gaussian AFNS model. We find that, near the zero lower bound, the shadow-rate model provides: Better fit; Better short rate forecasts; Compression of yield volatility. Thus, we recommend shadow-rate models as a useful modeling tool that provides improvements over Gaussian models in the current low-yield environment.

Black s Shadow-Rate Approach 3 / 36 To account for the zero lower bound, Black (1995) proposed using standard tools to model a shadow rate, s t, that may be negative, while the observed short rate is truncated: r t = max{s t, 0}. This nonlinearity is numerically straightforward but computation can be prohibitively burdensome. Krippner (2013) provides an option-based approximation to Black s shadow-rate concept. Christensen and Rudebusch (2015a) use that approach to generate shadow-rate arbitrage-free Nelson-Siegel models.

The Shadow-Rate AFNS Model Class (1) where ω(τ) is a deterministic function of model parameters. 4 / 36 In the shadow-rate AFNS class of models, the shadow rate is s t = L t + S t, and the Q-dynamics of the factors X t = (L t, S t, C t ) are dl t 0 0 0 θ Q 1 L t ds t = 0 λ λ θ2 Q S t dt +ΣdW Q dc t 0 0 λ θ3 Q C t where Σ is a constant matrix. The instantaneous shadow forward rate is f t (τ) = L t + e λτ S t +λτe λτ C t + A f (τ), where A f (τ) is an analytical function of model parameters. The nonnegative instantaneous forward rate is ( ft (τ) ) 1 ( f t (τ) = f t (τ)φ +ω(τ) exp 1 [ ft (τ) ] 2 ), ω(τ) 2π 2 ω(τ) t,

The Shadow-Rate AFNS Model Class (2) 5 / 36 The yield-to-maturity is defined the usual way as y t (τ) = 1 τ = 1 τ t+τ t t+τ t f t (s)ds [ f t (s)φ ( ft (s) ) 1 +ω(s) exp ω(s) 2π ( 1 2 [ ft (s) ] 2 )] ds. ω(s) This is the measurement equation in the Kalman filter. Since yields are nonlinear functions of the state variables, we use the standard extended Kalman filter. Later, I perform a simulation study to analyze the efficiency of the extended Kalman filter for estimating shadow-rate models.

The Real-World Dynamics Christensen and Rudebusch (2012) study the performance of various AFNS models on a long sample of weekly U.S. Treasury yields (1987-2010). They favor the following specification of the P-dynamics: dl t 10 7 0 0 0 ds t = κ P 21 κ P 22 κ P 23 L t S t dt+σ dc t 0 0 κ P 33 C t where Σ is a diagonal matrix. This is the transition equation in the Kalman filter. θ P 2 θ P 3 dw L,P t dw S,P t dw C,P t We study this model throughout the paper, denoted the CR model, and its shadow-rate equivalent referred to as the B-CR model following notation in Kim and Singleton (2012)., Note: Unit root imposed to address finite-sample bias. 6 / 36

Kalman Filter Estimation with a Unit Root (1) 7 / 36 Normally, we start the Kalman filter using the unconditional distribution of the state variables. However, when we impose a unit-root property on the Nelson-Siegel level factor, the joint dynamics of the state variables are no longer stationary. Thus, we cannot start the Kalman filter at the unconditional distribution. Instead, we follow Duffee (1999) and derive a distribution for the starting point of the Kalman filter based on the yields observed at the first data point in each sample.

Kalman Filter Estimation with a Unit Root (2) The model states that zero-coupon yields are given by y t = A+BX t +ε t, ε t N(0, H). For the first set of yield observations, this equation reads y 1 = A+BX 0 +ε 0 BX 0 = y 1 A ε 0. Now, multiply from the left on both sides with B to obtain B BX 0 = B (y 1 A) B ε 0. Then, we can isolate X 0 by using the inverse of B B: X 0 = (B B) 1 B (y 1 A) (B B) 1 B ε 0. Here, ε 0 is normally distributed with zero mean and covariance matrix H. Thus, X 0 follows a normal distribution: X 0 N[(B B) 1 B (y 1 A),(B B) 1 B HB(B B) 1 ]. Thus, this is the normal distribution used to start the Kalman filter when unit-root properties are imposed. 8 / 36

Data and Model Estimation 9 / 36 Both models are estimated on a weekly (Fridays) sample of H.15 (3-m, 6-m) and Gürkaynak, Sack, and Wright (2007) (1-, 2-, 3-, 5-, 7-, 10-yr) zero-coupon Treasury bond yields from January 4, 1985, to October 31, 2014. We do weekly re-estimations with endpoints starting in January 6, 1995, to the end of the sample to generate real-time yield decompositions. This should allow for a comprehensive study of model performance both in the normal period (Jan. 6, 1995 to Dec. 12, 2008) and in the zero lower bound (ZLB) period (Dec. 19, 2008 to Oct. 31, 2014). Here, I have updated most results through August 14, 2015.

U.S. Interest Rates Reach Effective Zero Lower Bound Rate in percent 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 10 year yield 5 year yield 1 year yield 3 month yield 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Since 2009 zero lower bound problems are apparent. Swanson and Williams (2014) find that medium- and long-term Treasury yields responded to economic news in 2009 and 2010 in a traditional way. Still, short maturities appeared constrained. However, problem is severe since August 2011. 10 / 36

Estimated Parameters from B-CR Model 11 / 36 K P K,1 P K,2 P K,3 P θ P Σ K1, P 10 7 0 0 0 σ 11 0.0069 (0.0001) K2, P 0.1953 0.3138-0.4271 0.0014 σ 22 0.0112 (0.1474) (0.1337) (0.0904) (0.0364) (0.0002) K3, P 0 0 0.4915-0.0252 σ 33 0.0257 (0.1200) (0.0087) (0.0004) The estimated parameters are very similar across the two models. Also, they are consistent with the results for AFNS models reported elsewhere, say, in Christensen et al. (2011).

Tests of Parameter Restrictions in AFNS Models Likelihood ratio test 0 20 40 60 80 Independent factor AFNS model CR model 95 percentile of chi^2 distribution, df = 4 95 percentile of chi^2 distribution, df = 6 FOMC 12/16 2008 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 In AFNS models, we can test the significance of parameter restrictions with standard likelihood ratio tests. The CR model appears to be sufficiently flexible to capture the variation in the data and greater parsimony does not seem warranted. 12 / 36

Tests of Parameter Restrictions in B-AFNS Models Quasi likelihood ratio test 0 20 40 60 80 Independent factor B AFNS model B CR model 95 percentile of chi^2 distribution, df = 4 95 percentile of chi^2 distribution, df = 6 FOMC 12/16 2008 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 In shadow-rate AFNS models, we test the significance of parameter restrictions with quasi likelihood ratio tests. The B-CR model appears to be sufficiently flexible to capture the variation in the data and again greater parsimony does not seem warranted. 13 / 36

How Good is the Option-Based Approximation? Average Absolute Simulation Error in Shadow Yields and Average Absolute Approximation Error in Observed Yields: Averaged over 7 dates last observation in each year (2006-2014). Maturity in months 12 36 60 84 120 Shadow yields 0.16 0.46 0.76 0.80 0.75 Yields 0.13 0.55 1.27 1.76 2.21 We assess the approximation provided by the option-based B-CR model via Monte Carlo simulations. We simulate 50,000 ten-year-long factor paths and calculate observed and shadow zero-coupon bond yields. Differences (in basis points) are small. Thus, we conclude that the option-based B-CR model provides a very close approximation to the Black model for our data. 14 / 36

Value of Option to Hold Currency Rate in basis points 0 20 40 60 80 100 Five year Treasury yield Ten year Treasury yield Bear Stearns rescue 3/24 2008 FOMC 12/16 2008 FOMC 8/9 2011 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 The spread between the yield that respects the ZLB and the unconstrained yield of the shadow bond can be interpreted as the value of the option to hold currency. Since 2009 the option has had sustained material value. Thus, accounting for the ZLB should matter. 15 / 36

Forecast of Negative Short Rates 16 / 36 Probability 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 50 percent line FOMC 12/16 2008 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Any affine Gaussian dynamic term structure model places positive probabilities on future negative interest rates. Here, we exemplify this with three-month forecasts of the short rate from rolling estimations of the CR model.

The Choice of Lower Bound 17 / 36 In general, the lower bound can be nonzero, i.e. r t = max{r min, s t }. In that case, the formula for the forward rate that respects the r min lower bound is: ( ft (τ) r ) min 1 f t (τ) = r min +(f t (τ) r min )Φ +ω(τ) exp ω(τ) 2π ( 1 2 where the shadow forward rate, f t (τ), and ω(τ) remain as before. [ ft (τ) r ] 2 ) min, ω(τ) We make a comprehensive comparison between fixing the lower bound, r min, at zero or leaving as a free parameter to be determined in the estimation of the B-CR model.

Sensitivity of Shadow Rate Rate in percent 4 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 CR model B CR model, r(min) = 0 B CR model, r(min) free Rate in percent 5 4 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 B AFNS(2) model B AFNS(3) model B AFGNS model 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Right chart shows the estimated shadow-rate paths from the B-CR model with and without the lower bound fixed at zero, and the estimated short-rate path from the CR model. Left chart shows the estimated shadow-rate paths from independent-factor B-AFNS(2), B-AFNS(3), and five-factor B-AFGNS models. Note that shadow rates are sensitive both to the choice of lower bound and to the number of state variables. 18 / 36

Importance of Choice of Lower Bound Parameter estimate 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.03 FOMC 12/16 2008 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012 2016 Quasi likelihood ratio test 0 100 200 300 400 500 FOMC 12/16 2008 99 percentile of chi^2 distribution, df = 1 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012 2016 Right chart shows estimated values of the lower bound. Left chart shows quasi likelihood ratio tests of its significance. While a positive value for the lower bound has statistical support, we find no practical value of the added flexibility. Thus, consistent with theory and Treasury yield data, we recommend fixing it at zero. 19 / 36

Model Fit near the ZLB Model fit is almost identical in the normal period as one could expect. Some notable differences in favor of the shadow-rate models in the recent ZLB period. 20 / 36 Normal period (Jan. 6, 1995-Dec. 12, 2008) RMSE Maturity in months All 3 6 12 24 36 60 84 120 yields CR 32.8 15.7 0.0 2.5 0.0 3.0 2.5 10.5 13.5 B-CR, r min = 0 32.7 15.5 0.7 2.4 0.1 2.8 2.1 10.5 13.4 B-CR, r min free 32.7 15.5 0.6 2.4 0.1 2.8 2.2 10.5 13.4 ZLB period (Dec. 19, 2008-Oct. 31, 2014) RMSE Maturity in months All 3 6 12 24 36 60 84 120 yields CR 21.1 12.1 0.0 2.4 0.0 3.2 3.4 11.6 10.1 B-CR, r min = 0 13.4 7.6 1.4 1.6 0.6 2.1 2.9 7.6 7.0 B-CR, r min free 12.1 7.0 1.5 1.3 0.8 1.9 3.0 6.6 6.3

Parameter Stability Parameter estimate 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 CR model B CR model, r(min) = 0 B CR model, r(min) free FOMC 12/16 2008 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012 2016 Parameter estimate 0.0050 0.0060 0.0070 0.0080 CR model B CR model, r(min) = 0 B CR model, r(min) free FOMC 12/16 2008 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012 2016 In addition to model fit, the estimated parameters are also hard to distinguish in the normal period κ P 33 and σ 11 are examples. However, we do see some wedges in the ZLB period. More importantly, some of the estimated parameters do change quite notably in the ZLB period within both models Fixing parameters at pre-crisis levels may not be appropriate. 21 / 36

Parameter Sensitivity of Short-Rate Projections Rate in percent 0 1 2 3 4 B CR parameter, 12/28 2007 CR parameter, 12/28 2007 CR parameter, 10/31 2014 B CR parameter, 10/31 2014 B CR state (12/28 2007) = (0.0382, 0.0520, 0.0137) CR state (12/28 2007) = (0.0382, 0.0519, 0.0137) CR state (10/31 2014) = (0.0382, 0.0536, 0.0110) B CR state (10/31 2014) = (0.0370, 0.0556, 0.0082) 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022 2024 Using pre-crisis versus current parameter estimates, we document both statistically and economically significant differences. Thus, real-time updating with rolling estimations is important. 22 / 36

Compression of Yield Volatility near the ZLB Rate in basis points 0 20 40 60 80 100 CR model B CR model, r(min) = 0 B CR model, r(min) free Three month realized volatility of three month yield Rate in basis points 0 20 40 60 80 100 CR model B CR model, r(min) = 0 B CR model, r(min) free Three month realized volatility of two year yield 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 Shown are the predicted three-month conditional volatility of the three-month (right) and two-year (left) Treasury yield with a comparison to a measure of realized yield volatility based on daily yield changes. The B-CR model can replicate the compression in volatility of short- and medium-term yields since 2009. A nonzero lower bound can produce extremely low short-term yield volatilities. 23 / 36

Yield Forecasts in Shadow-Rate Models n=1 y(x n T,τ). 24 / 36 Input: Estimated K P, Σ, θ P, λ, and filtered X t. The continuous-time P-dynamics are given by dx t = K P ( θ P X t )dt + ΣdW P t. The conditional mean of X T under the P-measure: E P t [X T ] = (I exp( K P (T t)))θ P + exp( K P (T t)) X t. The conditional covariance matrix of X T under the P-measure: V P t [X T ] = T t 0 e K P s Σ Σ e ( K P ) s ds. We simulate N = 1,000 draws directly at the desired horizon: ( ) XT n N Et P [X T ], Vt P [X T ], n = 1,..., 1000. The resulting conditional zero-coupon bond yield forecast is: Et P [y T (τ)] = 1 N N

Yield Forecasts in the Normal Period Three-month yield Six-month One-year Mean RMSE Mean RMSE RW -20.19 90.14-39.28 157.11 CR model -29.27 89.51-46.30 154.19 B-CR model, r min = 0-32.53 88.39-53.73 151.32 B-CR model, r min free -37.60 87.83-59.48 150.69 Two-year yield Six-month One-year Mean RMSE Mean RMSE RW -20.14 86.68-36.74 132.02 CR model -19.69 86.87-39.00 130.61 B-CR model, r min = 0-21.32 86.54-42.01 130.03 B-CR model, r min free -21.78 86.61-42.41 130.04 Ten-year yield Six-month One-year Mean RMSE Mean RMSE RW -12.76 59.13-20.87 72.80 CR model -7.21 56.33-18.34 69.85 B-CR model, r min = 0-7.81 56.52-19.27 70.32 B-CR model, r min free -7.68 56.52-19.17 70.33 25 / 36

Yield Forecasts in the ZLB Period Three-month yield Six-month One-year Mean RMSE Mean RMSE RW -1.34 6.45-2.15 7.17 CR model -6.87 26.29-19.02 42.16 B-CR model, r min = 0-16.98 19.68-33.42 35.80 B-CR model, r min free -21.04 23.78-38.69 41.38 Two-year yield Six-month One-year Mean RMSE Mean RMSE RW -3.45 23.04-9.84 26.13 CR model -18.08 31.03-47.88 54.65 B-CR model, r min = 0-22.12 35.08-49.83 60.62 B-CR model, r min free -25.01 37.33-56.35 66.12 Ten-year yield Six-month One-year Mean RMSE Mean RMSE RW -8.36 67.36-19.44 88.00 CR model -21.59 74.46-48.09 103.45 B-CR model, r min = 0-25.63 74.87-52.74 106.28 B-CR model, r min free -25.97 73.41-55.67 105.40 26 / 36

Short-Rate Projections in Shadow-Rate Models (1) 27 / 36 In affine models, the conditional expectation of X t is E P t [X t+τ ] = (I exp( K P τ))θ P + exp( K P τ)x t. In shadow-rate AFNS models, the instantaneous shadow rate is s t = L t + S t. Thus, the conditional expectation of the shadow-rate process is E P t [s t+τ ] = E P t [L t+τ + S t+τ ] = ( 1 1 0 ) E P t [X t+τ ]. However, we are interested in the conditional expectation of the short rate: E P t [r t+τ ] = E P t [max(r min, s t )].

Short-Rate Projections in Shadow-Rate Models (2) We are interested in the conditional expectation of the short rate: E P t [r t+τ ] = E P t [max(r min, s t )]. The conditional covariance matrix of the state variables is: V P t [X t+τ ] = τ 0 e K Ps ΣΣ e (K P ) s ds. Hence, the conditional covariance of the shadow-rate process is Vt P [s t+τ] = ( 1 1 0 ) 1 Vt P [X t+τ] 1. 0 Now, the conditional expectation of the short rate is given by Et P [r t+τ] = r t+τ f(r t+τ X t)dr t+τ = r min + (s t+τ r min )f(s t+τ X t)ds t+τ r ( min ) = r min +(Et P (Et P [s t+τ] r min ) [s t+τ] r min )N V P t [s t+τ] ( ) + 1 Vt P [s t+τ] exp 1 (Et P [s t+τ] r min ) 2. 2π 2 Vt P [s t+τ] 28 / 36

Forecast of Future Target Rates Normal period Six-month One-year Mean RMSE Mean RMSE RW 20.71 94.19 40.73 165.87 KW model -3.40 69.68 35.62 132.67 CR model -0.33 72.08 16.41 141.20 B-CR model, r min = 0 2.57 69.97 24.00 136.56 B-CR model, r min free 9.45 67.07 31.45 134.89 ZLB period Six-month One-year Mean RMSE Mean RMSE RW 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 KW model 35.53 38.70 96.53 97.28 CR model -0.97 30.17 7.08 43.93 B-CR model, r min = 0 5.95 12.35 15.51 19.91 B-CR model, r min free 11.98 15.79 22.87 26.47 Here, we study the models ability to forecast future policy target rates and include the Kim & Wright (2005, KW) model maintained at the Federal Reserve Board in the comparison. The B-CR model is competitive at forecasting future target rates in real time, both in the normal and the ZLB period. 29 / 36

Short-Rate Forecasts Also, the KW model is not reliable either since 2009. 30 / 36 Rate in percent 2 0 2 4 6 8 KW model CR model B CR model, r(min) = 0 B CR model, r(min) free Realized target rate FOMC 12/16 2008 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 This figure illustrates the real-time forecasts one year ahead of the short rate from the CR and B-CR models with a comparison to the KW model. The CR and B-CR models are indistinguishable prior to crisis and differences are minor until August 2011. However, since then the CR model has been a little erratic.

Short-Rate Expectations and Futures Rates (1) Rate in percent 2 0 2 4 6 FOMC 12/16 2008 KW model CR model B CR model, r(min) = 0 B CR model, r(min) free Federal funds futures rate Rate in percent 2 0 2 4 6 FOMC 12/16 2008 KW model CR model B CR model, r(min) = 0 B CR model, r(min) free Federal funds futures rate 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 Illustration of the one-year (left) and two-year (right) short rate projections from the standard CR and shadow-rate B-CR models since 2007 with a comparison to the KW model. Also shown are 12- and 24-month federal funds futures rates that are used as a rough benchmark to assess the appropriateness of the variation in each model. 31 / 36

Short-Rate Expectations and Futures Rates (2) 32 / 36 One-year contract Two-year contract Mean RMSE Mean RMSE KW model 51.34 66.68 86.19 107.74 CR model -21.82 77.44-39.99 119.88 B-CR model, r min = 0-17.11 39.31-44.01 73.28 B-CR, r min free -12.49 40.15-35.40 72.81 Reported are the mean and root mean squared differences relative to the one- and two-year federal funds futures rates for the period from January 5, 2007, to August 14, 2015. The short-rate expectations from the B-CR model are clearly competitive relative to the other models.

Average Short-Rate Expectations and Term Premiums For a start, the term premium is defined as TP t (τ) = y t (τ) 1 τ In the CR model, it holds that 1 τ t+τ t ( Et P [r s]ds = θ2 P + TP t(τ) = A(τ) τ 1 κp 21 κ P 22 t+τ t ) L t + κp 21 κ P 22 κp 23 ( 1 e κ P 33 τ κ P 22 κp 33 κ P 33 τ E P t [r s ]ds. 1 e κp 22 τ κ P 22 τ P L t + 1 e κ 22 τ κ P 22 τ (S t θ2) P P 1 e κ 22 τ ) κ P 22 τ (C t θ3), P + κp 21 (1 1 e κp 22 τ ) ( 1 e λτ κ P 22 κ P 22 τ L t + λτ [ 1 e κ P 33 τ ( 1 e λτ + e λτ + λτ κ P 23 P 1 e κ 22 τ ) κ P 22 τ S t P 1 e κ 22 τ ]) κ P 22 τ C t κ P 22 κp 33 κ P 33 τ (1 1 e κp 22 τ ) κ P 22 τ θ2 P κ P ( 23 1 e κ P 33 τ P κ P 22 κp 33 κ P 33 τ 1 e κ 22 τ ) κ P 22 τ θ3. P In the B-CR model, 1 t+τ τ t Et P [r s ]ds has to be approximated by numerically integrating the formula for Et P [r s ]. 33 / 36

Average Expected Short Rates the Next Ten Years Rate in percent 2 0 2 4 6 8 10 KW model CR model B CR model, r(min) = 0 B CR model, r(min) free SPF ten year forecast FOMC 12/16 2008 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Shown is the average expected short rate the next ten years. Also shown is the expected annual average return over the next ten years from holding 3-m T-Bills according to the SPF. The KW model tracks survey expectations closely by construction Its policy expectations are relatively high. 34 / 36

Ten-Year Term Premiums Rate in percent 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 KW model CR model B CR model, r(min) = 0 B CR model, r(min) free FOMC 12/16 2008 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Due to the high policy expectations in the KW model, its term premiums remain low by historical standards. The B-CR model delivers more plausible estimates relative to where we are in the monetary policy cycle. 35 / 36

Conclusion 36 / 36 We compare the shadow-rate AFNS model derived in Christensen and Rudebusch (2015a) with a matching standard AFNS model. We find that, while providing equal performance in normal times, the shadow-rate model stands out near the ZLB: Better fit; More accurate forecasts of future short rates; Compression of yield volatility. Questions remain about the extent to which other models that account for the unique yield dynamics near the ZLB can improve performance even further. However, for now, we recommend shadow-rate models as a useful modeling tool that provides improvements over Gaussian models in the current low-yield environment.