Academic Research Publishing Group

Similar documents
Journal of Economic & Financial Studies. Recent monetary policy effects on Japanese macroeconomy

Stock Prices, Foreign Exchange Reserves, and Interest Rates in Emerging and Developing Economies in Asia

Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research

Corporate Investment and Portfolio Returns in Japan: A Markov Switching Approach

Estimating a Fiscal Reaction Function for Greece

What determines government spending multipliers?

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy.

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

On Abenomics and the Japanese Economy. Motoshige Itoh Member, Council on Economic and Fiscal Policy and Professor, University of Tokyo

The Effectiveness of Non-traditional Monetary Policy and the Inflation Target Policy : The Case of Japan in Comparison with the US

An Estimated Fiscal Taylor Rule for the Postwar United States. by Christopher Phillip Reicher

Quarterly Currency Outlook

Monetary Policy Options in a Low Policy Rate Environment

Asian Economic and Financial Review, 2016, 6(4): Asian Economic and Financial Review. ISSN(e): /ISSN(p):

INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA

THE CONVERGENCE OF THE BUSINESS CYCLES IN THE EURO AREA. Keywords: business cycles, European Monetary Union, Cobb-Douglas, Optimal Currency Areas

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

Simulations Illustrate Flaw in Inflation Models

Futures Contracts Rates as Monetary Policy Forecasts

Discussion of Did the Crisis Affect Inflation Expectations?

Performance of Statistical Arbitrage in Future Markets

Oesterreichische Nationalbank. Eurosystem. Workshops. Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. Macroeconomic Models and Forecasts for Austria

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

The Pricing of Exchange Rates in Japan: The Cases of the Japanese Automobile Industry Firms after the US Lehman Shock

Cross- Country Effects of Inflation on National Savings

International Journal of Advance Research in Computer Science and Management Studies

Discussion of The Role of Expectations in Inflation Dynamics

Iranian Economic Review, Vol.15, No.28, Winter Business Cycle Features in the Iranian Economy. Asghar Shahmoradi Ali Tayebnia Hossein Kavand

Pavel Ryska. PCPE, April 18, 2015

Taylor and Mishkin on Rule versus Discretion in Fed Monetary Policy

Bank Characteristics and Payout Policy

Article published in the Quarterly Review 2014:2, pp

Contrarian Trades and Disposition Effect: Evidence from Online Trade Data. Abstract

Economic policy. Monetary policy (part 2)

Márcio G. P. Garcia PUC-Rio Brazil Visiting Scholar, Sloan School, MIT and NBER. This paper aims at quantitatively evaluating two questions:

Recent Comovements of the Yen-US Dollar Exchange Rate and Stock Prices in Japan

A measure of supercore inflation for the eurozone

E-322 Muhammad Rahman CHAPTER-3

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU?

Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

Analysis on accrual-based models in detecting earnings management

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Correlation between BET Index Evolution and the Evolution of Transactions Number Analysis Model

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

Accounting disclosure, value relevance and firm life cycle: Evidence from Iran

Data Revisions and Macroecomics DR. ANA BEATRIZ GALVAO WARWICK BUSINESS SCHOOL UNIVERSITY OF WARWICK SEP, 2016

The Effect of Recessions on Fiscal and Monetary Policy

An Empirical Examination of Traditional Equity Valuation Models: The case of the Athens Stock Exchange

Exchange Rate and Economic Performance - A Comparative Study of Developed and Developing Countries

PERUVIAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION. Modelling and forecasting money demand: divide and conquer

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Monetary Policy Objectives During the Crisis: An Overview of Selected Southeast European Countries

MODELING VOLATILITY OF US CONSUMER CREDIT SERIES

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the Export Performance: Empirical Evidence for Western Balkan Countries

Macroeconomics II. Explaining AS - Sticky Wage Model, Lucas Model, Sticky Price Model, Phillips Curve

Monetary Policy Revised: January 9, 2008

International journal of advanced production and industrial engineering (A Blind Peer Reviewed Journal)

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

Explore the themes and thinking behind our decisions.

Composition of Foreign Capital Inflows and Growth in India: An Empirical Analysis.

Stellenbosch Economic Working Papers: 24/13

Volume 29, Issue 4. A Nominal Theory of the Nominal Rate of Interest and the Price Level: Some Empirical Evidence

Exchange Rate and Economic Growth in Indonesia ( )

MONETARY POLICY EXPECTATIONS AND BOOM-BUST CYCLES IN THE HOUSING MARKET*

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Effect of Firm Age in Credit Scoring Model for Small Sized Firms

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN

How High A Hedge Is High Enough? An Empirical Test of NZSE10 Futures.

Acemoglu, et al (2008) cast doubt on the robustness of the cross-country empirical relationship between income and democracy. They demonstrate that

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Fiscal consolidation through fiscal rules?

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data

A Kind of Neither Keynesian Nor Neoclassical Model (8): Equilibrium Between Fictitious and Substantial Economy

Making Monetary Policy: Rules, Benchmarks, Guidelines, and Discretion

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Explaining procyclical male female wage gaps B

THE IMPACT OF GROWTH RATE OF GDP ON UNEMPLOYMENT RATE IN BALKAN COUNTRIES (ALBANIA, MONTENEGRO, SERBIA AND MACEDONIA) DURING

Stock market firm-level information and real economic activity

The impacts of cereal, soybean and rapeseed meal price shocks on pig and poultry feed prices

TESTING THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS ON CORPORATE BOND YIELDS. Samih Antoine Azar *

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

Fitting linkers into a portfolio

Growth Rate of Domestic Credit and Output: Evidence of the Asymmetric Relationship between Japan and the United States

Measuring the natural interest rate in Brazil

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Period 3 MBA Program January February MACROECONOMICS IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY Core Course. Professor Ilian Mihov

Transcription:

Academic Research Publishing Group International Journal of Economics and Financial Research ISSN(e): 2411-9407, ISSN(p): 2413-8533 Vol. 2, No. 8, pp: 155-160, 2016 URL: http://arpgweb.com/?ic=journal&journal=5&info=aims Can the Disparity between GDP and GDP Forecast Cause Economic Instability? The Recent Japanese Case Yutaka Kurihara Professor, Department of Economics, Aichi University, Japan Abstract: This paper investigates the link between forecast disparity and macroeconomic instability that results from the data revision of GDP and inflation in Japan. The recent Japanese case, which reflects the unconventional monetary policy conducted since 2013, is also examined. The empirical results show that such disparities do not cause economic instability; however, they have have done so after the unconventional and drastic monetary policy was conducted. On the other hand, exchange rates impacted economic stability for the total period. For the first part of the period under study (from 2000 to 2012), currency appreciation caused instability; however, for the more recent period, depreciation has caused such instability. Recently, macroeconomic instability has been linked with exchange rate movements. Keywords: Economic stability; Forecast; GDP; Price. 1. Introduction Before economic data releases, markets move according to participants (including computer program) expectations. Some data are released with the condition that there may be some change in the future, and the data actually change thereafter. The first released data tend to be unreliable compared to the final figures, especially during times of economic turmoil. Data disparities are common, and they may be large or small. When they become large, markets usually move again. Data revisions, which can be large in magnitude and are subject to an indefinite way are important to the extent that the initially released data cannot be taken at face value (Baetje and Friedrici, 2016). Even when disparities are small, market turmoil or instability sometimes occur. Just before the first initial data are released and again when confirmation data are released, economists and private economic institutions expect each report, and when they are published, market participants (sometimes computers) see them and conduct transactions, invest, and sometimes speculate using the published data. In some cases, huge transactions occur and wrong one direction transactions dampen sound markets and economic development. Markets sometimes fluctuate as a result of such participants transactions. Also, they sometimes make use of economic data disparities on purpose. However, sometimes a large variety of expectations and the transactions that are based on such expectations stabilize markets. Market participants know quite well that disparities exist. It is quite difficult and at time nearly impossible to forecast economic data correctly; sometimes such forecasts are accurate and sometimes not, which is quite natural. However, sometimes market dispersions cause instability or turmoil. No problems result when such disparities cause market stability; however, the opposite case may cause serious situations and sometimes dampen economic growth. Such mechanisms should be examined much more but few studies have examined the relationship between forecast disparities and macroeconomic uncertainty not only in the fields of theoretical studies but also in empirical fields, despite the importance of this problem. Recent developments in ICT may accelerate economic stability or turmoil. Mankiw and Shapiro (1986) and Faust et al. (2005) showed that data revisions cause uncertainty because of the reliability of economic data in real time. Zarnowitz and Lambros (1987) indicated that the relationship between survey-based dispersion and macroeconomic uncertainty depends on the assumption that forecasters have stronger effects during times of greater economic turmoil. Fair and Shiller (1990) found that the quality of economic forecasts strongly relies on the volatility of the economy. Ang et al. (2007) and Genre et al. (2013) showed that consensus forecasts outperform other forecast models closer to the initial released data. Belke and Klose (2011) found that the use of real-time instead of ex post data leads to higher estimated output gap and inflation gap. Croushore (2011) indicated that evaluation of the success of policy authority actions and forecasts is crucially linked with whether or not real-time or confirmed revised values are used. Kalckreuth and Wolff (2011) found that discretionary fiscal policy is influenced by measurements of data error. Nalewaik (2011) showed that GDI instead of GDP is useful in the analysis of the current economic situation. Neri and Ropele (2011) found that the estimated policy rule becomes more inertial and less aggressive for the case of inflation rates. Giannone et al. (2012) indicated that data revisions cause the economic instability that surrounds key macroeconomic ratios. Cusinato et al. (2013) showed that there is 155

a difference between the revisions of GDP and adding new observations and that the latter is preponderant. Lewis (2013) found that government budget balances have a stabilizing influence on economic activity. Pedersen (2013) found that there is no improvement in nowcasting performance when historical data are supplemented. Laurent and Andrey (2014) showed that forecast accuracy of the data improves when the probability forecasts of both the coincident indicators model and the yield curve model are combined. Liebermann (2014) indicated that the precision of nowcasts increases with economic data information releases. Beradi and Duffy (2015) showed that the method of real-time parameterized expectations learning gives a plausible alternative way to use the real-time adaptive learning dynamics model. Bernoth et al. (2015) found that the intended discretionary response of fiscal policy to the cycle is counter-cyclical. Capek (2015) indicated that data revisions are unbiased and not autocorrelated by using the DSGE model. Leopoldo and Guilermo (2015) found that there is no reason to accept the interpretation that forecast errors have unfortunate systematic effects on fiscal procyclically. Baetje and Friedrici (2016) showed that disagreement is significantly linked with to data uncertainty. Cimadomo (2012) found that forecast errors for the government structural balance and the output gap play an important role in explaining the differences between estimates based on ex ante and ex post data. Also, Cimadomo (2016) indicated that fiscal data revisions are large and initial releases are biased estimates of final ones. Some studies have examined data dispersions including GDP; however, there are not enough of these in spite of their importance. In particular, few studies have examined the Japanese case. Using macroeconomic data, this study focuses on predicted real output and inflation rates. Also, the current study focuses on the recent Japanese unconventional monetary policy. This paper is structured as follows. Following this section, theoretical aspects of data dispersions are explained. Section 3 provides data description and empirical methods for the conduct of the empirical analyses the follow. Section 4 shows the empirical analyses and analyzes the results. Finally, this paper ends with a brief summary. 2. Theoretical Analysis If initially released data are not accurate or biased, later revisions may reflect large data uncertainty. On the other hand, if the initial data are correct, revisions would tend to be small in general. The disparities between the initial and final figures may have negative effects on the economy or sometimes dampen economic growth. This study starts with this point of view. Several studies have examined the link between initial and final data releases to determine whether revisions can be characterized as news or noise. Under the news view, data revisions occur as additional information becomes available. Accordingly, initial data are efficient and rational forecasts for the final data. On the other hand, if the preliminary announcement equals the final data plus some measurement errors, revisions reduce noise, which implies that they tend to be predictable. The present study mainly considers the latter case. The equation used in this study examines the relationship between data disparities and economic stability as explained in the next section. Data revision errors are defined as DIFFERENCE l t = A F t A l t, where the announced data at real-time vintage l and y F t denotes the true or final, revised data. A in the equation means GDP and inflation in this study. This study s measurement of data uncertainty is defined by the standard deviation of revision errors over a preselected revision window with length of quarters or months. The length is shown in the next section. Whether or not forecast dispersions of GDP and inflation that reflect data uncertainty impact economic stability is examined. Detailed data and empirical methods are also explained in the section 3. The recent Japanese unconventional monetary policy also is considered. 3. Data and Empirical Methods This study uses the predicted real GDP rate and predicted inflation rate, both as measured by the GDP price index. The real GDP growth rate is defined as the annualized quarter-over-quarter percentage change using forecast horizons of four quarters (one year) and eight quarters (two years). Inflation rate is defined as the annualized monthover-month percentage change using forecast horizons of three (one quarter) or six months (a half year). The proxy for economic stability, such as macroeconomic uncertainty, is the standard deviation among individual forecast. The sample period for GDP is from 2000Q1 to 2016Q1 and the sample period for inflation is from 2013M1 to 2016M6. The data are from the Japanese Statistical Bureau and the Bank of Japan. Since April, 2013, a new, unconventional monetary policy has been conducted in Japan. To check the difference between the periods before and after implementation of this police would be interesting and necessary; however, not enough time has passined since this policy was first introduced, so the problem of the amount data would occur especially for quarterly data (i.e., GDP). So examination of the differences between the period before the unconventional monetary policy and the period of after its implementation is applied to the case of inflation, which can be determined from monthly data. GDP data are usually quarterly. Whether or not forecast disparities reflect instability of the Japanese economy is assessed using the following regression (1). log (σ t ) = α + β log (DIFFERENCE t-h ) + ε t (1) where DIFFERENCE t-h is defined as the forecast disparity for the target quarter or month at point t, observed h quarters or months ago, depending on the forecast horizon. 156

Q1 2010 Q2 2010 Q3 2010 Q4 2010 Q1 2011 Q2 2011 Q3 2011 Q4 2011 Q1 2012 Q2 2012 Q3 2012 Q4 2012 Q1 2013 Q2 2013 Q3 2013 Q4 2013 Q1 2014 Q2 2014 Q3 2014 Q4 2014 Q1 2015 Q2 2015 Q3 2015 Q4 2015 Q1 2016 Moreover, a new explanatory variable, exchange rate, is added to the equation. The reason that exchange rates should be included in the equation is that especially since 2013, the unconventional monetary policy began to be conducted and exchange rates moved greatly as a result. Significant depreciation of the Japanese yen has occurred and may cause economic fluctuations. In Japan, a drastic new policy, called Abenomics (for Abe, the prime minister), was adopted in April 2013 to combat deflation. Japan has been under severe economic conditions (i.e., deflation). Moreover, by strengthening coordination between the Japanese central bank (Bank of Japan; BOJ) and the government, since April 2013, the Japanese government has implemented measures to achieve a new fiscal structure to ensure the credibility of the fiscal condition. At that time, BOJ introduced an unprecedented and unconventional aggressive monetary policy that expands the volume of government bond purchases to pour money into markets for consumption, investment, and so on. As a result of this policy, exchange rates depreciated and stock prices rose. The movement of exchange rates (real effective exchange rate) are shown in Figure 1. 120.00 Figure-1. Exchange rate 100.00 80.00 60.00 40.00 20.00 0.00 For the analysis that includes exchange rates, this equation (2) instead of the equation (1) is regressed. log (σ t ) = α + β log (DIFFERENCE t-h ) +γ log (EXCHANGE t-h ) + ε t (2) Empirical methods are OLS (ordinary least squares) and robust estimation. Robust estimation is unlike maximum likelihood estimation. OLS estimates for regression are sensitive to the observations that do not follow the pattern of the other observations. This is not a problem if the outlier is simply an extreme observation from the tail of a normal distribution; however, if the outlier is from non-normal measurement error or some other violation of standard OLS, it compromises the validity of the regression results if a nonrobust regression method is employed. In this study, there are not enough sample numbers, so along with the usual OLS, robust estimation is used. 4. Empirical Results and Analyses First, GDP is regressed. The empirical results of equation (1) are reported in Table 1 and the results of the equation (2) are reported in Table 2. Table-1. Difference of GDP and Economic Stability. Horizon = 4 or 8 Horizon = 4 Horizon = 4 Horizon = 8 Horizon = 8 C 0.899*** (11.765) 0.702*** (14.469) 0.835*** (10.542) 0.664*** (13.368) DIFFERENCE 0.024 (0.131) 0.094 (0.790) 0.064 (0.329) 0.049 (0.402) Adj.R2-0.016-0.015 Adj.Rw-squared 0.013 0.003 F- 0.017 (0.895) 0.108 (0.743) 0.624 (0.429) 0.162 (0.687) Note. Figures in parentheses are t-s for OLS, z- robust estimation, and probability for F- and. ***, **, and * denote 1%. 5%, and 10% significance levels respectively. 157

Table-2. Difference of GDP, Exchange Rate and Economic Stability Horizon = 4 or 8 Horizon = 4 Horizon = 4 Horizon = 8 Horizon = 8 C 2.864*** (5.826) 2.165*** (5.864) 2.472*** (4.625) 1.580*** (4.238) DIFFERENCE 0.028 (0.170) 0.045 (0.363) 0.067 (0.369) 0.066 (0.523) EXCHANGE -0.018*** (-4.035) -0.012*** (-3.758) -0.015*** (-3.091) -0.008** (-2.340) Adj.R2 0.192 0.113 Adj.Rw-squared 0.247 0.117 F- 8.153 (0.0007) 4.839 (0.011) 14.271 (0.0007) 5.766 (0.055) Note. Figures in parentheses are t-s for OLS, z-s for robust estimation, and probability for F- and. ***, **, and * denote 1%. 5%, and 10% significance levels respectively. The empirical results are clear. They show that disparities in GDP data do not cause instability. The coefficients are positive as expected; however, they are not significant even at the 10% level. On the other hand, exchange rates have caused economic instability. It is interesting to note that exchange rate movements instead of disparities in GDP cause economic instability. For inflation, the empirical results are reported in Tables 3 and 4. Table-3. After Abenomics Horizon = 3 or 6 Horizon = 3 Horizon = 3 Horizon = 6 Horizon = 6 C 26.342*** (6.310) 28.632*** (5.691) 0.716*** (11.654) 0.679*** (10.164) DIFFERENCE 3.636* (1.733) 4.113* (1.748) 0.127*** (4.143) 0.139*** (4.142) Adj.R2 0.046 0.282 Adj.Rw-squared 0.090 0.392 F- 3.003 (0.090) 17.166 (0.0001) 3.058 (0.080) 17.164 (0.000) Note. Figures in parentheses are t-s for OLS, z-s for robust estimation, and probability for F- and. ***, **, and * denote 1%. 5%, and 10% significance levels, respectively. Table-4. After Abenomics. Horizon = 3 or 6 Horizon = Horizon = 3 Horizon = 6 Horizon = 6 3 C 57.626 (1.596) 60.896 (1.495) -1.312*** (-3.085) -1.342*** (-2.758) DIFFERENCE 3.803* (1.799) 4.277* (1.794) 0.138*** (5.573) 0.140*** (4.939) EXCHANGE 0.285 (0.872) 0.314 (0.850) 0.018*** (4.800) 0.018*** (4.291) Adj.R2 0.040 0.537 Adj.Rw-squared 0.113 0.604 F- 1.873 (0.167) 24.838 (0.000) 3.698 (0.157) 39.296 (0.000) Note. Figures in parentheses are t-s for OLS, z-s for robust estimation, and probability for F- and. ***, **, and * denote 1%. 5%, and 10% significance levels, respectively. The empirical results reveal some interesting points: Disparities do cause instability since implementation of the drastic, unconventional monetary policy. On the other hand, depreciation has caused economic instability. It is difficult to judge; however, recent depreciation of the yen has been significant (see Figure 1) and has caused large fluctuations in economic conditions. Of course this condition entails both pros and cons for the economy. 158

Policy authorities should take these findings into account in some cases. Surely, data disparities should be avoided, especially for the case of noise. Forecasts should be performed as accurately as possible and at least should be able to account for the reasons for the disparities as market participants could understand and agree. In such cases, markets would rely on the authorities, and market turmoil would be avoided. However, along with improvements in the accuracy of forecasts, authorities should consider the movements of exchange rates. In some cases, markets (e.g., foreign exchange markets and stock markets, etc.), go out of control. Such situations should be avoided as much as possible. 5. Conclusions This paper empirically examined the relationship between forecast disparities and macroeconomic instability that resul from data revisions of GDP and inflation figures in Japan. The recent Japanese case, for which unconventional monetary policy has been conducted since 2013, was also examined. The empirical results showed that disparities in GDP forecasting do not cause instability; however, inflation figure disparities, after the unconventional and drastic monetary policy was conducted, have caused instability. On the other hand, exchange rates impacted economic instability for the total period. For the first part of the sample period (from 2000 to 2012), appreciation caused instability; also, for the more recent period, depreciation has caused economic instability. Recently, disparities in GDP and inflation data have been linked with macroeconomic instability. Exchange rates should be taken into account along with the some kinds of data dispersions. Finally, data accumulation seems necessary. Further study is necessary. Acknowledgments I was supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Number 15H03366 for this work. References Ang, A., Bekaert, G. and Wei, M. (2007). Do macro variables, asset markets, or surveys forecast inflation better? Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(4): 163-1212. Baetje, F. and Friedrici, K. (2016). Does cross-sectional forecast dispersion proxy for macroeconomic uncertainty? New empirical evidence. Economic Letters, 143(June): 38-43. Belke, A. and Klose, J. (2011). Does the ECB rely on a Taylor rule during the financial crisis? Comparing ex-post and real time data with real time forecasts. Economic Analysis and Policy, 41(2): 147-71. Beradi, M. and Duffy, J. (2015). Real-time, adaptive learning via parameterized expectations. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 19(2): 245-69. Bernoth, K., Hughes, H. and Lewis, J. (2015). The cyclicality of automatic and discretionary fiscal policy: What can real-time data tell us? Macroeconomic Dynamics, 19(1): 221-43. Capek, J. (2015). Estimating DSGE model parameters in a small open economy: Do real-time data matter? Review of Economic Perspective, 15(1): 89-114. Cimadomo, J. (2012). Fiscal policy in real time. Journal of Economics, 114(2): 440-65. Cimadomo, J. (2016). Real-time data and fiscal policy analysis: A survey of the literature. Journal of Economic Surveys, 30(2): 302-26. Croushore, D. (2011). Frontiers of real-time data analysis. Journal of Economics Literature, 49(1): 72-100. Cusinato, R. T., Minella, A. and da Pôrto, S. (2013). Output gap in Brazil: A real-time data analysis. Empirical Economics, 44(11): 113-27. Fair, R. C. and Shiller, R. J. (1990). Comparing information in forecasts from econometric models. American Economic Review, 80(3): 375-89. Faust, J., Rogers, J. H. and Wright, J. H. (2005). News and noise in G-7 GDP announcements. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 37(3): 403-19. Genre, V., Kenny, G., Meyler, A. and Timmermann, A. (2013). Combining expert forecasts: Can anything beat the simple average? International Journal of Forecast, 29(1): 108-21. Giannone, D., Henry, J., Lalik, M. and Modugno, M. (2012). An area-wide real-time database for the Euro area. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(4): 1000-13. Kalckreuth, U. and Wolff, G. B. (2011). Identifying discretionary fiscal policy reactions with real-time data. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 43(6): 1271-85. Laurent, P. and Andrey, V. (2014). Forecasting combination for U.S. recessions with real-time data. North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 28(April): 138-48. Leopoldo, A. and Guilermo, V. (2015). Fiscal procyclically and output forecast errors. Journal of International Money and Finance, 55(July): 193-204. Lewis, J. (2013). Fiscal policy in Central and Eastern Europe with real time data: Cyclicality, inertia and the role of EU accession. Applied Economics, 45(23): 3347-49. Liebermann, J. (2014). Real-time nowcasting of GDP: A factor model vs. professional forecasters. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 76(6): 205-349. Mankiw, N. G. and Shapiro, M. D. (1986). News and noise: An analysis of GDP revision. Survey of Current Business, 66(May): 20-25. 159

Nalewaik, J. J. (2011). Estimating probabilities of recession in real time using GDP and GDI. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44(1): 235-53. Neri, S. and Ropele, T. (2011). Imperfect information, real-time data and monetary policy in the Euro area. Economic Journal, 122(561): 651-74. Pedersen, M. (2013). Extracting GDP signals from the monthly indicator of economic activity: Evidence from Chilean real-time data. Journal of Business Cycle Measurement and Analysis, 2013(1): 5-20. Zarnowitz, V. and Lambros, L. A. (1987). Consensus and uncertainty in economic prediction. Journal of Political Economy, 95(3): 591-620. 160