A Two Dimensional Risk Measure

Similar documents
A Two-Dimensional Risk Measure

CONVENTIONAL FINANCE, PROSPECT THEORY, AND MARKET EFFICIENCY

Interpretive Structural Modeling of Interactive Risks

Subject CS1 Actuarial Statistics 1 Core Principles. Syllabus. for the 2019 exams. 1 June 2018

NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Continuous Distributions

On the Use of Stock Index Returns from Economic Scenario Generators in ERM Modeling

Fatness of Tails in Risk Models

1 Supply and Demand. 1.1 Demand. Price. Quantity. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 2 of the text.

Module Tag PSY_P2_M 7. PAPER No.2: QUANTITATIVE METHODS MODULE No.7: NORMAL DISTRIBUTION

REINSURANCE RATE-MAKING WITH PARAMETRIC AND NON-PARAMETRIC MODELS

Gamma Distribution Fitting

Web Extension: Continuous Distributions and Estimating Beta with a Calculator

Statistical Modeling Techniques for Reserve Ranges: A Simulation Approach

Measuring the Rate Change of a Non-Static Book of Property and Casualty Insurance Business

2007 ASTIN Colloquium Call For Papers. Using Interpretive Structural Modeling to Identify and Quantify Interactive Risks

Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. Portfolio Selection CHAPTER 1. JWPR026-Fabozzi c01 June 22, :54

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

Basic Procedure for Histograms

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Learning Objectives = = where X i is the i t h outcome of a decision, p i is the probability of the i t h

Characterization of the Optimum

CABARRUS COUNTY 2008 APPRAISAL MANUAL

Dot Plot: A graph for displaying a set of data. Each numerical value is represented by a dot placed above a horizontal number line.

PAPER NO.1 : MICROECONOMICS ANALYSIS MODULE NO.6 : INDIFFERENCE CURVES

Making Hard Decision. ENCE 627 Decision Analysis for Engineering. Identify the decision situation and understand objectives. Identify alternatives

THE RATE OF INTEREST NATURE, DETERMINATION AND RELATION TO ECONOMIC PHENOMENA IRVING FISHER, PH.D. ITS PROFESSOR OF POLITICAL ECONOMY, YALE UNIVERSITY

Notes on a Basic Business Problem MATH 104 and MATH 184 Mark Mac Lean (with assistance from Patrick Chan) 2011W

GRAPHS IN ECONOMICS. Appendix. Key Concepts. Graphing Data

the display, exploration and transformation of the data are demonstrated and biases typically encountered are highlighted.

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region*

Optimizing DSM Program Portfolios

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright

Inflation Targeting and Revisions to Inflation Data: A Case Study with PCE Inflation * Calvin Price July 2011

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

Module 6 Portfolio risk and return

A Two-Dimensional Dual Presentation of Bond Market: A Geometric Analysis

CHAPTER II LITERATURE STUDY

This is Interest Rate Parity, chapter 5 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0).

A Top-Down Approach to Understanding Uncertainty in Loss Ratio Estimation

The Expenditure-Output

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

Financial Econometrics (FinMetrics04) Time-series Statistics Concepts Exploratory Data Analysis Testing for Normality Empirical VaR

Intermediate Microeconomics UTILITY BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

OMEGA. A New Tool for Financial Analysis

Continuous random variables

Volatility Lessons Eugene F. Fama a and Kenneth R. French b, Stock returns are volatile. For July 1963 to December 2016 (henceforth ) the

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

Implementing Risk Appetite for Variable Annuities

Optimal Layers for Catastrophe Reinsurance

Rawley Thomas 1. Enterprise Risk Management Symposium Society of Actuaries. Chicago, IL. March 28 30, 2007

Economics 602 Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Problem Set 3 Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2012

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

~ In 20X7, a loaf of bread costs $1.50 and a flask of wine costs $6.00. A consumer with $120 buys 40 loaves of bread and 10 flasks of wine.

ARCH Proceedings

A Numerical Experiment in Insured Homogeneity

Corporate Risk Appetite and Program Structuring White paper 3 of 3

Cash Flow and the Time Value of Money

Cost of Capital (represents risk)

Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

Chapter 3. Numerical Descriptive Measures. Copyright 2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. Chapter 3, Slide 1

Optimal Withdrawal Strategy for Retirement Income Portfolios

Traditional Optimization is Not Optimal for Leverage-Averse Investors

Maximum Likelihood Estimation

The Risk Considerations Unique to Hedge Funds

A Framework for Understanding Defensive Equity Investing

Kevin Dowd, Measuring Market Risk, 2nd Edition

KEIR EDUCATIONAL RESOURCES

Properties of Probability Models: Part Two. What they forgot to tell you about the Gammas

Target Date Glide Paths: BALANCING PLAN SPONSOR GOALS 1

CHAPTER 2 RISK AND RETURN: Part I

FIN 6160 Investment Theory. Lecture 7-10

Ocean Hedge Fund. James Leech Matt Murphy Robbie Silvis

The Value of Flexibility to Expand Production Capacity for Oil Projects: Is it Really Important in Practice?

Mean-Variance Model for Portfolio Selection

If Tom's utility function is given by U(F, S) = FS, graph the indifference curves that correspond to 1, 2, 3, and 4 utils, respectively.

Review of Production Theory: Chapter 2 1

Chapter DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS: PHASE SPACE, NUMERICAL SOLUTIONS

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises

Equation Chapter 1 Section 1 A Primer on Quantitative Risk Measures

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Optimizing the Omega Ratio using Linear Programming

First Welfare Theorem in Production Economies

CHAPTER 2 Describing Data: Numerical

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module I

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Neil Bodoff, FCAS, MAAA CAS Annual Meeting November 16, Stanhope by Hufton + Crow

STAT 113 Variability

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Chapter# The Level and Structure of Interest Rates

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 2

The Real World: Dealing With Parameter Risk. Alice Underwood Senior Vice President, Willis Re March 29, 2007

Optimal Stochastic Recovery for Base Correlation

Obsolescence Risk and the Systematic Destruction of Wealth

Chapter 14 : Statistical Inference 1. Note : Here the 4-th and 5-th editions of the text have different chapters, but the material is the same.

Lecture 2 Describing Data

Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application

Note on Cost of Capital

Transcription:

A Two Dimensional Risk Measure Rick Gorvett, FCAS, MAAA, FRM, ARM, Ph.D. 1 Jeff Kinsey 2 Presented at Enterprise Risk Management Symposium Society of Actuaries Chicago, IL April 23 26, 2006 Copyright 2006 by the Society of Actuaries. All rights reserved by the Society of Actuaries. Permission is granted to make brief excerpts for a published review. Permission is also granted to make limited numbers of copies of items in this monograph for personal, internal, classroom or other instructional use, on condition that the foregoing copyright notice is used so as to give reasonable notice of the Societyʹs copyright. This consent for free limited copying without prior consent of the Society does not extend to making copies for general distribution, for advertising or promotional purposes, for inclusion in new collective works or for resale. 1 Rick Gorvett is State Farm Companies Foundation Scholar in Actuarial Science, and Director of the Actuarial Science Program, at the University of Illinois at Urbana Champaign. 2 Jeff Kinsey is an actuarial analyst at the State Farm Research Center in Champaign, IL, and a master s degree student in actuarial science at the University of Illinois at Urbana Champaign. 1

Abstract The measurement of risk is a critical component of enterprise risk management, insurance pricing and reserving, and strategic and operational decisionmaking. Some commonly used measures attempt to quantify risk by considering volatility or downside potential. Other measures examine ratios of upside versus downside potential, or upside potential versus volatility. A general characteristic of such measures is that they describe risk in a single dimension placing risk along a number line and providing a single quantitative value. In this paper, we suggest that risk is too complex to quantify with a single number. We suggest a two dimensional risk measure and introduce the concept of iso risk curves. Risk is synonymous with uncertainty lack of knowledge. Irving Fisher, The Theory of Interest, 1930 But Uncertainty must be taken in a sense radically distinct from the familiar notion of Risk, from which it has never been properly separated. Frank Knight, Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, 1921 2

1. Introduction The two quotes above, separated by less than a decade, are exemplary of the difficulty and disagreements which even famous economists have had in defining the concept of risk. It is even more sobering to examine the primary works of other authors e.g., Adam Smith, Alfred Marshall and observe that there is often no effort at all to define the term 3 ; rather, the word risk is frequently assumed as common knowledge, and invested with its popular meaning and connotations. Today, we often use risk and uncertainty, at least informally, somewhat interchangeably, while recognizing that there is a formal technical difference. In particular, as Knight (1921) acknowledges, in a continuation of the above quote: The term risk, as loosely used in everyday speech and in economic discussion, really covers two things which, functionally at least, in their causal relations to the phenomena of economic organization, are categorically different. The essential fact is that risk means in some cases a quantity susceptible of measurement, while at other times it is something distinctly not of this character. It will appear that a measurable uncertainty, or risk proper, as we shall use the term, is so far different from an unmeasurable one that it is not in effect an uncertainty at all. We shall accordingly restrict the term uncertainty to cases of the non quantit(at)ive type. The whole idea of measuring risk is a critical concept for finance, economics and actuarial science 4 and yet it can prove notoriously difficult. Over the years, a variety of different risk measures has been proposed, several of which have been implemented by various practitioners. Many other risk metrics have been proposed, considered and analyzed in the actuarial, risk management and/or financial literature, in both academic journals and institutional publications. Sometimes, it seems that the optimal risk measure may depend upon the characteristics and conditions of the particular situation e.g., line of business, size, nature of the decision being made and sources of risk. In this paper, we introduce and consider a new, two dimensional risk measure. Various other measures attempt to quantify risk in terms of variability or downside potential. More elaborate measures created in the last few years have looked at ratios 3 Even in Knight s book, a chapter entitled The Meaning of Risk and Uncertainty, has only three occurrences of the word risk in its text. 4 While these industries have spent substantial time and effort in trying to quantify risk, it may be that, given the nature and complexity of the world, we will also want to begin achieving breakthroughs in the consideration of uncertainty in the future. 3

of upside versus downside potential, or upside potential versus outcome variability. Generally, however, other measures have attempted to quantify risk in a single dimension: each measure places risk along a number line and represents risk via a single quantitative value. We believe that risk is too complex to be quantified with a single number. In this paper, we present a two dimensional risk measure and introduce the concept of iso risk curves. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the two dimensional risk measure, and describes its essential characteristics. Section 3 provides an illustration of the measure with respect to a hypothetical distribution. Section 4 considers the risk measure with respect to two pairs of illustrative distributions with different characteristics. Section 5 evaluates the relative ranking of three distributions among four risk measures the measure introduced here and three others commonly used. Section 6 concludes, and briefly mentions directions for future research. 2. A Two Dimensional Risk Measure One of the problems associated with a one dimensional risk measure, or any measure that does not have a firm economic and/or mathematical foundation, is that it might not accurately represent the true riskiness of outcomes. For an actuary and/or an insurance company, the potential consequences of such a misrepresentation include charging an inappropriate price for an insurance or financial product, not properly estimating required return on equity and even making sub optimal operational or strategic planning decisions. Often, risk measures do not fulfill their intended purpose because they fail to adequately reflect the characteristics of the potential distribution of outcomes. For example, it is fairly simple to hypothesize a reasonable situation in which traditional measures of risk suggest two distributions are equivalent (say, because they have the same standard deviation or value at risk), when in fact one should be considered more risky than the other due to its skewness or kurtosis. The two dimensional risk measure introduced here is based upon the relationship between both upside and downside conditional expected values. For a particular distribution, and with respect to a selected dollar threshold, the conditional expected downside and upside values are calculated, and the difference between the values is taken. This difference is calculated for all possible thresholds in the range of potential outcomes. The result is an array of upside and downside values for various thresholds, along with their differences. The focus of this risk measure is to find the threshold where the distance between upside and downside is minimized. This 4

threshold value, along with the corresponding value of the difference between expected upside and downside, represents the two dimensions of the risk measure. 5 At this point, it is helpful to define a few terms that will be used throughout the remainder of this paper. For a particular outcome distribution, we have the following parameters: Threshold: The dollar value at which downside and upside conditional expected values are calculated. Upside: The conditional expected value of all outcomes greater than the threshold. Downside: The conditional expected value of all outcomes less than the threshold. Spread: The difference between the upside and downside values at a particular threshold. Minimum Spread: The minimum of all spread values calculated. These parameters lead to the two dimensions of this risk measure, which can be identified as an ordered pair: or, notationally, (Minimum Spread, Threshold @ Minimum Spread) (s, t). This approach has certain similarities to the return volatility tradeoff in the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). In that context, an investor desires to maximize expected return for a given level of volatility (or variability or risk ), or equivalently, minimize volatility for a given level of expected return. An analogous approach applies to this risk measure. In comparing various distributions, it is preferred to have a higher optimal threshold value t for a given value of minimum spread s, and similarly, a smaller s for a given t. 5 Among existing risk metrics, this measure is most similar to the Omega Ratio presented by Keating and Shadwick (2002). In the Omega Ratio, the upside and downside expected value relationship involves the ratio of upside to downside, as opposed to the difference as used in the current measure. 5

The two dimensions shown above were selected for various reasons. First, the minimum spread value occurs at a threshold where the rate of change of the upside and downside values are equal. This can be seen more clearly in the illustrative example in the following section. The concept of equal rates of change is analogous to many marginal equality concepts found in economics. In addition, it is also very important to include where this minimum value occurs. The threshold value where the minimum occurs will change depending on the mean, variance and skewness of the underlying distribution. That being the case, the threshold value contains various characteristics of the first three central moments of the underlying distribution. Within s t space, 6 this single point does not lie in isolation. It lies on a curve of equally risky points. These curves, which we have named iso risk curves, are positive sloping, non overlapping curves that fill the entire s t space. 7 These iso risk curves will vary in slope and curvature depending on particular risk appetites. People (or organizations, if one wishes to informally endow them with risk preference traits) that are more willing to accept risk will have a flatter iso risk curve at a particular point than those that are more risk averse. Likewise, the slope of an iso risk curve will be greater for those that are risk averse as opposed to those more willing to accept risk. Analogously to preferring to be on a higher utility curve in economic theory, so too is it preferable to be on a higher (in the northwest direction of the s t plane) iso risk curve. In particular, points lying on higher iso risk curves are perceived to be less risky than those lying on lower iso risk curves. 3. An Illustrative Example The following example serves to illustrate this risk measure. Figure 1 shows a density plot of a random sample of 10,000 values drawn from a gamma (4.5; 1,000) distribution. Each sample was then transformed in order to achieve the desired skew and scaling according to the formula: [ ln( sample value) 5,000] 37, 000 6 With the exception of Figures 3, 8 and 11 (which are reversed for clarity and pedagogic purposes), we will adopt the convention that t is plotted along the vertical (or y ) axis, and s is plotted along the horizontal (or x ) axis. 7 The obvious analogy is to utility curves in either risk return or two consumer good space. 6

Figure 1 Upside and downside were both calculated starting at an initial threshold value of 8,100. The threshold was then incremented by +100 up to the value 11,600; at each increment, both the upside and downside expected values were calculated. The formulas for the upside and downside calculations are as follows: Nu = Number of values greater than the threshold Nd = Number of values less than the threshold Ui = full amount of a simulated value which is greater than the threshold Di = full amount of a simulated value which is less than the threshold Upside = 1 N u N u i= 1 U i Downside = 1 N d N d i= 1 D i 7

Figure 2 shows a plot of upside and downside values at each threshold point. 15000 Figure 2 10000 5000 0-8100 -6100 Ave Value -4100-2100 -100 1900 3900 5900 7900 9900-5000 -10000 Threshold Value This graph in and of itself has some appealing characteristics. First, the two lines are horizontally asymptotic to the mean of the distribution. Second, the vertical distance between the two lines (the spread) gives a relative measure of variability; this will be better illustrated in a later example. Finally, the relative position where the spread is minimized describes the skewness of the distribution. For a normal distribution, spread will be minimized at the 50 th percentile, whereas spread for a leftskewed distribution will be minimized at a point greater than the 50 th percentile, and for a right skewed distribution at a point less than the 50 th percentile. 8 8 A bit of reflection will suggest that the horizontal point (the threshold value) at which the vertical distance between the upward and downward expected value curves in Figure 2 is minimized, is also the point at which the two curves have the same slope (assuming certain regularity conditions i.e., assuming that the curves behave normally ). This is because, if at the minimum spread threshold the curves do not have identical slope, then either immediately to the left or right of that threshold the spread must be smaller (one curve will be gaining on the other). This possibility results in a contradiction. So minimum spread and equality of slope occur at the same point. This is analogous to several marginal equality concepts in economics e.g., a consumer will split her/his resources between two consumable goods according to the point at which the marginal benefit provided by each good is the same (otherwise, s/he would favor consuming more of the higher marginal benefit good). 8

Figure 3 shows spread versus the threshold value. 14000 Figure 3 12000 10000 Spread (s) 8000 6000 4000 2000 5300, 3881 0-8100 -6100-4100 -2100-100 1900 3900 5900 7900 9900 Threshold Value (t) The minimum spread value and the corresponding threshold are the two values of concern for this risk measure. As shown in Figure 3, for this distribution spread is minimized at a threshold value of 5,300 with a minimum spread value of 3,881. Figure 4 plots this point with the minimum spread value s on the horizontal axis and the threshold at which the minimum spread occurs plotted on the vertical axis (the convention which will be used throughout the remainder of the paper). 10000 9000 8000 7000 Figure 4 Threshold (t) 6000 5000 4000 3000 2000 1000 3881, 5300 0 0 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 6000 7000 8000 9000 10000 Spread (s) 9

The theory underlying this risk measure is that this point is one of a series of points of equal risk that lie on an iso risk curve. For a particular distribution, the points on a given iso risk curve are considered to be of equal risk relative to each other (from the standpoint of a person or other entity with a given risk appetite), whereas points above the iso risk curve are considered less risky and points below the curve are more risky compared to that particular distribution. Figure 5 illustrates this concept. Figure 5 Conceptually, iso risk curves can be thought of in two ways. First, the slope of the iso risk curve can be thought of as how much an entity with a particular risk appetite is willing to sacrifice in the threshold value for a unit increase in certainty (here, a unit increase in certainty would be a unit decrease in spread). Secondly, the vertical axis intercept of the iso risk curve has an interesting interpretation: the intercept value on the threshold axis indicates the threshold value that would be accepted for absolute certainty (zero spread) of that particular result. Using a simplifying assumption that the iso risk curves are linear, Figure 6 shows how the slopes of iso risk curves will change according to varying risk appetites. 10

Figure 6 One can see that, in exchange for reducing spread (or risk), a risk averse entity will be willing to accept a smaller (possibly even negative) threshold value compared with a less risk averse (or more risk accepting) entity. 4. Comparing Distributions Often in practice, two or more distributions will be compared, evaluated and even ranked according to a particular measure of risk. In this section, we illustrate how the s t risk measure introduced here behaves when comparing two or more simple distributions. Example 1: Two Distributions with the Same Mean The purpose of this first comparison is to show how this risk measure performs with two distributions that have the same mean but different variances. For this comparison, a random sample of 10,000 values was drawn from each of the following distributions: Normal ( 0; 1,000 ) Normal ( 0; 10,000 ) Few would argue with the suggestion that the N(0; 10,000) is more risky. However, it is interesting to see how the graphical s t framework illustrates the differences in these two distributions. Figures 7 through 9 show this comparison. 11

Figure 7 40000 30000 20000 10000 Ave Value 0-10000 -39700-14700 10300 35300-20000 -30000-40000 Threshold Value Figure 8 Spread (s) 45000 40000 35000 30000 25000 20000 15000 10000 5000 0 0, 16042 0, 1593-39700 -14700 10300 35300 Threshold (t) 12

Figure 9 Maintaining the simplifying assumption that iso risk curves are linear, the N(0; 1,000) distribution is clearly shown to be less risky in Figure 9 it is on a higher, or more left, iso risk curve. In fact, only a horizontal iso risk curve, which would represent an infinite risk tolerance and fictitious in practice, would place these two distributions as equally preferable in terms of risk. It is also interesting to note the values of minimum spread for each of these distributions. For the N(0; 1,000) distribution, the minimum spread was achieved at a threshold of 0 with a spread value of 1,593. The N(0; 10,000) distribution had a minimum spread at a threshold of 0 with a spread value of 16,042 which is roughly ten times the size of the N(0; 1,000) minimum spread value. It is not coincidental that we began with two distributions in which one had a standard deviation 10 times the other. Example 2: Two Distributions with the Same Standard Deviation As a second comparison, a random sample of 10,000 values was drawn from each of the following two distributions: Normal ( 10,000; 1,000 ) Normal ( 10,000; 1,000 ) Again, few would argue that the N( 10000,1000) is more risky. For this example, charts analogous to the first example are displayed as Figures 10 through 12. 13

Figure 10 20000 15000 10000 5000 Ave Value 0-5000 -13700-8700 -3700 1300 6300 11300-10000 -15000-20000 Threshold Figure 11 5000 4500 4000 3500 Spread (s) 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000-10000, 1595 10000, 1608 500 0-13700 -8700-3700 1300 6300 11300 Threshold (t) 14

Figure 12 Maintaining the simplifying assumption of linear iso risk curves, the N(10,000; 1,000) will be on a higher curve in all cases except that of a vertical iso risk curve. A vertical iso risk curve would indicate a focus solely on variability reduction. 5. Comparing Risk Measures The s t risk measure will now be compared to some of the more popular risk measures currently used in practice. In particular, comparisons will be made to value at risk (VaR), tail value at risk (TVaR) and standard deviation (SD). For this comparison, a random sample of 10,000 values was drawn from each of the following distributions: A. Lognormal(0; 0.5) * 3000 8000 (Blue) B. Lognormal(0; 0.3) * 3000 4500 (Green) C. Normal(0; 1,500) (Red) Figure 13 is a density plot of the three distributions. 15

Figure 13 Based on just visual inspection of the density plots, one could possibly make an assessment as to the relative riskiness of these three distributions. Few would argue with the judgment that distribution A (the left most mode) is the riskiest of the three. However, legitimate arguments could be made as to why either distribution B or C might be considered the least risky distribution. Although distribution C has a higher average value, it is more variable than distribution B and has a higher probability of outcomes less than (approximately) 3,500. However, it also has significantly higher potential for outcomes greater than zero. Distribution B has less variability, but also is likely to be negative a majority of the time. Depending on a particular risk appetite, either distribution could be viewed as the least risky. VaR, TVaR and SD rank these distributions in the following orders (1 = least risky, 3 = most risky): Risk Measure Distribution A Distribution B Distribution C VaR (.01) 3 1 2 TVaR (.01) 3 1 2 Std. Dev. 3 1 2 Each risk measure has ranked distribution A as the riskiest and distribution B as the least risky. Now let s examine the s t risk measure s indications. Figure 14 shows how each of these distributions appears when the minimum spread and the corresponding threshold are plotted. 16

Figure 14 0-1,000 2,000 3,000 4,000 5,000 6,000 7,000-1000 -2000 B C Threshold (t) -3000-4000 -5000-6000 A -7000 Spread (s) The iso risk curve through each point will vary depending on particular risk appetites. For example, a risk averse appetite would shy away from volatile distributions and therefore would have a steeper iso risk slope, and thus distribution B would be considered less risky than distribution C. In contrast, a risk appetite that has a higher tolerance for risk would be more accepting of a volatile distribution as long as higher outcomes are more probable and would have flatter iso risk curves, thus assessing distribution C as less risky than B. There also exists a unique iso risk curve where these two points are considered equally risky. Figure 15 shows these various isorisk curves plotted on a single graph. Again, the simplifying assumption of linear isorisk curves is used. Figure 15 17

6. Conclusion and Future Research In this paper, we have presented a two dimensional risk measure. It is suggested that this measure reflects several moments of the distribution of possible outcomes, and thus has the potential to be a useful and effective tool in considering the relative preferences of different distributions. This is a young idea, and there are numerous paths in which further research can and will be conducted. Much of that research will involve potential applications of this risk measure concept, including: Determination of appropriate reinsurance prices (via the spread threshold tradeoff inherent in iso risk curves). Capital allocation decisions (via relevant distances between iso risk curves). Strategic and operational decision making (based on hypothesized distributions of outcomes before and after various alternatives. Another avenue for future exploration is to consider various formulas for the isorisk curves, which would permit parametric expression and analysis of different risk appetites. It is hoped that this paper will inspire additional research and comments in these and related areas. 18

References Fisher, I. 1930. The Theory of Interest, New York: The Macmillan Company. Keating, C., and Shadwick, W. 2002. An introduction to Omega. The Financial Development Centre Limited Knight, F. 1921. Risk Uncertainty, and Profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Co. 19