A new approach for valuing a portfolio of illiquid assets

Similar documents
Portfolio Theory and Risk Management in the presence of Illiquidity

A generalized coherent risk measure: The firm s perspective

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments

SOLVENCY AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION

Dynamic Risk Management in Electricity Portfolio Optimization via Polyhedral Risk Functionals

Allocation of Risk Capital via Intra-Firm Trading

Optimal Portfolio Liquidation with Dynamic Coherent Risk

Capital Allocation Principles

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

Pricing and risk of financial products

Mathematics in Finance

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

Risk, Coherency and Cooperative Game

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management

Measures of Contribution for Portfolio Risk

Value at Risk. january used when assessing capital and solvency requirements and pricing risk transfer opportunities.

References. H. Föllmer, A. Schied, Stochastic Finance (3rd Ed.) de Gruyter 2011 (chapters 4 and 11)

Liquidity-Adjusted Risk Measures

Maturity as a factor for credit risk capital

Risk measures: Yet another search of a holy grail

Efficient Portfolio Valuation Incorporating Liquidity Risk

The Statistical Mechanics of Financial Markets

RISKMETRICS. Dr Philip Symes

Financial Risk Management and Governance Beyond VaR. Prof. Hugues Pirotte

Markets with convex transaction costs

To split or not to split: Capital allocation with convex risk measures

Capital Conservation and Risk Management

Why Bankers Should Learn Convex Analysis

Conditional Value-at-Risk: Theory and Applications

Risk Measurement: History, Trends and Challenges

Order book resilience, price manipulations, and the positive portfolio problem

On Risk Measures, Market Making, and Exponential Families

Capital requirements, market, credit, and liquidity risk

Indices of Acceptability as Performance Measures. Dilip B. Madan Robert H. Smith School of Business

Performance Measurement with Nonnormal. the Generalized Sharpe Ratio and Other "Good-Deal" Measures

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note

Statistical Methods in Financial Risk Management

Strategies and Nash Equilibrium. A Whirlwind Tour of Game Theory

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

COHERENT VAR-TYPE MEASURES. 1. VaR cannot be used for calculating diversification

University of California Berkeley

Optimal Hedge Ratio under a Subjective Re-weighting of the Original Measure

Characterization of the Optimum

Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets

Conditional Value-at-Risk, Spectral Risk Measures and (Non-)Diversification in Portfolio Selection Problems A Comparison with Mean-Variance Analysis

Robustness issues on regulatory risk measures

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management: ineffectiveness of VaR and ES constraints

arxiv:math/ v1 [math.pr] 2 May 2006

Risk aversion in multi-stage stochastic programming: a modeling and algorithmic perspective

Risk measure pricing and hedging in incomplete markets

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Risk-Averse Decision Making and Control

Pricing & Risk Management of Synthetic CDOs

Financial Risk Management

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

Portfolio selection with multiple risk measures

Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING. Agenda. Agenda (Cont.) Traditional Measures of Market Risk

Master s in Financial Engineering Foundations of Buy-Side Finance: Quantitative Risk and Portfolio Management. > Teaching > Courses

Model Risk: A Conceptual Framework for Risk Measurement and Hedging

Calculating VaR. There are several approaches for calculating the Value at Risk figure. The most popular are the

Financial Risk Measurement/Management

THE TEMPORAL DIMENSION OF RISK

Risk Measurement in Credit Portfolio Models

ERM (Part 1) Measurement and Modeling of Depedencies in Economic Capital. PAK Study Manual

Risk Measures for Derivative Securities: From a Yin-Yang Approach to Aerospace Space

Sensible and Efficient Capital Allocation for Credit Portfolios

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

Model risk adjusted risk forecasting

MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management. John Dodson. September 6, 2017

Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Introduction to Financial Mathematics

A Robust Option Pricing Problem

ON A CONVEX MEASURE OF DRAWDOWN RISK

University of California Berkeley

Can a coherent risk measure be too subadditive?

2 Control variates. λe λti λe e λt i where R(t) = t Y 1 Y N(t) is the time from the last event to t. L t = e λr(t) e e λt(t) Exercises

Lecture 6: Risk and uncertainty

Short Course Theory and Practice of Risk Measurement

Problem 1: Random variables, common distributions and the monopoly price

Alternative Risk Measures for Alternative Investments

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 16 Feb 2001

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Value at Risk, Expected Shortfall, and Marginal Risk Contribution, in: Szego, G. (ed.): Risk Measures for the 21st Century, p , Wiley 2004.

Minimization of the Total Required Capital by Reinsurance

Illiquidity Spirals in Coupled Over-the-Counter Markets 1

Coherent allocation of risk capital

Liquidity-Sensitive Automated Market Makers via Homogeneous Risk Measures

Put Call Parity and Market Frictions

Risk based capital allocation

Chapter 2 Uncertainty Analysis and Sampling Techniques

Lecture 1 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia.

Building Consistent Risk Measures into Stochastic Optimization Models

Expected utility theory; Expected Utility Theory; risk aversion and utility functions

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

This version: December 3, 2009

Coherent liquidity risk measures

Lecture 10: Performance measures

Transcription:

PRIN Conference Stochastic Methods in Finance Torino - July, 2008 A new approach for valuing a portfolio of illiquid assets Giacomo Scandolo - Università di Firenze Carlo Acerbi - AbaxBank Milano

Liquidity risk 1/23 What is liquidity risk? Treasurer s answer: the risk of running short of cash Trader s answer: the risk of trading in illiquid markets, i.e. markets where exchanging assets for cash may be difficult or uncertain Central Bank s answer: the risk of concentration of cash among few economic agents Setting a precise mathematical framework is not easy

Outline 2/23 The theoretical framework Portfolios and Marginal Supply-Demand Curves Liquidation value vs. usual mark-to-market value Liquidity policies and general mark-to-market values Coherent/convex risk measures and liquidity risk Some numerical examples

Portfolios 3/23 It is possible to trade in N 1 illiquid assets cash, which is by definition the only liquidity risk-free asset We define A portfolio is a vector p R N+1 p0 is the amount of cash p = (p1,..., p N ) is the assets position pn is the number of assets of type n

Liquid/Illiquid markets 4/23 Perfectly liquid market (S0(t) 1) Sn(t) is the unique price, at time t, for selling/buying a unit of asset n; this price does not depend on the size of the trade V (p, t) = p0 + N n=1 pnsn(t) is linear Illiquid markets (S0(t) 1) Sn(t) = Sn(t, x) will depend on the size x R (x > 0 is a sale) of the trade V (p, t) need not be linear anymore. A first idea is: V (p, t) = p0 + N n=1 pnsn(t, pn) But this is not the only sensible notion of value

Marginal Supply-Demand Curves - 1 5/23 Some basic definitions A Marginal Supply-Demand Curve (msdc) is a decreasing function m : R (0, + ) m + = m(0+) and m = m(0 ) are the best bid (sell) and ask (buy) prices. Of course m + m. Let x be the size of the transaction (x > 0 sale, x < 0 purchase). The unit price is and the proceeds are S(x) = 1 x x 0 P (x) = xs(x) = m(y) dy > 0 x 0 m(y) dy 0 Same setting as in Cetin-Jarrow-Protter 2005, but our focus is on m.

a typical MSDC 108 106 Bids 104 102 100 98 Asks 96-20 -15-10 -5 0 5 10 15 20

Marginal Supply-Demand Curves - 2 6/23 We can also allow for (care is needed with the details): Assets which are not securities (e.g. swaps) and can display negative (marginal) prices: m : R R Securities with finite depth market: m(x) = + for x << 0 and/or m(x) = 0 for x >> 0 Swaps with finite depth market: m(x) = + for x << 0 and/or m(x) = for x >> 0

Two simple notions of value - 1 7/23 Given m = (m1,..., m N ) a vector of msdc. Let p R N+1 be a portfolio. The Liquidation Value of p is L(p) = p0 + N n=1 pnsn(pn) = p0 + N n=1 p n 0 m n(x) dx The Usual Mark-to-Market Value of p is U(p) = p0 + pnm + n + as if only the best bid and ask would matter. pn>0 pn<0 pnm n Note that U(p) L(p) for any p.

Two simple notions of value - 2 8/23 Some properties of L and U: concavity. both L and U are concave (but not linear) additivity. L is subadditive (L(p + q) L(p) + L(q)) whenever p and q are concordant (pnqn 0 for n 1); it is superadditive for discordant portfolios U is always superadditive, and it is additive for concordant portfolios scaling if λ 1 L(λp) λl(p) U(λp) = λu(p)

Two simple notions of value - 3 9/23 Liquidation Mark-to-Market Value (L): measure of the portfolio value as if we are forced to entirely liquidate it (so, liquidity risk is a big concern) Usual MtM Value (U): measure of the portfolio value as if we don t have to liquidate even a small part of it (so, liquidity risk is not a concern) Our aim is to introduce notions of value between the two extreme cases. Whether and what to liquidate is a need that may vary.

Acceptable portfolios - 1 10/23 First we give a notion of acceptability for a portfolio: A liquidity policy is a convex and closed subset L R N+1 such that 1. p L implies p + a L for any a 0 (adding cash cannot worsen the liquidity properties of a portfolio) 2. (p0, p ) L implies (p0, 0 ) L (if a portfolio is acceptable, its cash component is acceptable as well) L collects the portfolios whose liquidity risk is not a concern and thus may be valued through U

Acceptable portfolios - 2 11/23 Examples of liquidity policies: 1. L = R N+1 Every portfolio is acceptable: no need to liquidate (this will lead to U) 2. L = {p : p = 0 } Only pure-cash portfolios are acceptable: need to entirely liquidate p (this will lead to L) 3. L = {p : p0 a} (a 0 fixed) This is a typical requirement imposed by the ALM of an institution 4. other examples may be based on bounds on concentration...

Attainable portfolios 12/23 1. Start with a portfolio p, which need not be acceptable 2. Make it acceptable by liquidating the assets (sub)position q R N r = p q + L(0, q ) = (p0 + L(0, q ), p q ) L 3. Find the best way to do this, maximizing the Usual MtM value U(r) 4. Note that L is used in 2. and U in 3.: in 2. we care about liquidity risk, in 3. we don t as r L

A general definition of value 13/23 Having fixed a liquidity policy L we can define the associated MtM Value (sup = ) V L (p) = sup{u(r) : r = p q + L(0, q ) L, q R N } r R N+1 is optimal if V L (p) = U(r ). It is immediate to see that V L (r ) = U(r ) = V L (p) (there is no change in value passing from p to r ) The set over which U (concave) is maximized is convex. Thus The optimization program defining V L is always convex.

Some examples 14/23 1. If L = R N+1, then V L (p) = U(p) 2. If L = {p : p = 0 }, then V L (p) = L(p) 3. If L = {p : p0 a}, then V L (p) = sup{u(p q ) + L(0, q ) : L(0, q ) a p0, q R N+1 } which is not trivial (and non-linear)

Some properties 15/23 If L L, then V L V L. Thus, V L (p) U(p) L For any L, V L is concave and translational supervariant V L (p + a) V L (p) + a a 0

Computation of the value 16/23 As the problem defining V L is convex, many fast algorithms are available An analytical solution is sometime easy. Assume: {p : p0 a} mi continuous and strictly decreasing i Then if p0 a (p L) then r = p and V L (p) = U(p) if p0 < 0 then r i = m 1 i where λ is determined by L(r ) = p0 a. ( m i(0) 1 + λ )

Coherent risk measures - 1 17/23 Coherent risk measures (CRM) ρ : L R (L space of r.v.) are characterized by (Artzner-Delbaen-Eber-Heath-98) 1. Translation invariance: ρ(x + c) = ρ(x) c c R; 2. Monotonicity: ρ(x) ρ(y ) whenever X Y 3. Positive homogeneity: ρ(λx) = λρ(x) λ 0 4. Subadditivity: ρ(x + Y ) ρ(x) + ρ(y ). Axioms 3 and 4 do not seem to take into account liquidity risk: if I double my portfolio, its risk should more than double in many cases. They were replaced (Follmer-Schied02, Frittelli-Rosazza02) by the weaker axiom of convexity.

Coherent risk measures - 2 18/23 In our opinion, CRM are appropriate to deal with liquidity risk. The key point is that: If I double my portfolio... means p 2p, not X 2X The relation between p and its value X is not linear. We define risk measures defined directly on portfolios R = R(p) that are not necessarily positively homogeneous or subadditive.

Risk measures for portfolios 19/23 Given a liquidity policy L a probability space (Ω, F, P ) describing randomness up to T > 0 a coherent risk measure defined on some L L 0 (Ω, F, P ) the random future msdc: (mi(x, T )) for any i, where for any x, mi(x, T ) is a r.v. for any ω, x mi(x, T )(ω) is decreasing We compute V L (p) = V L (p, T )(ω) for any ω (it is a r.v.) and set R L (p) = ρ(v L (p))

Properties 20/23 Some properties (for general L and ρ) 1. R L is convex 2. R L is translational subvariant: R L (p + c) R L (p) c 3. R L is in general not homogeneous, nor subadditive 4. specific properties for R L may be derived from properties of V L (and coherency of ρ) 5. no monotonicity property can be introduced for R

A numerical example - 1 21/23 Consider (T is fixed) mi(x) = αi exp{ βix}, where, Ai > 0 and βi 0 are r.v. There can be Market risk only: αi jointly lognormal, βi = 0 Market and non-random liquidity risk: αi jointly lognormal, βi > 0 non-random Market and independent random liquidity risk: (αi, βi)i jointly lognormal, with αi βi Market and correlated random liquidity risk: (αi, βi)i jointly lognormal, with αi and βi negatively correlated Market and correlated random liquidity risk with shocks: (αi, βi)i jointly lognormal, with αi and βi negatively correlated, βi = βi + εi

A numerical example - 2 22/23 For a given portfolio p and L = {q : q0 a}, in any of the 5 previous situations we: set I = 10, αi and βi id. distr. for different i we perform 100k simulations of (mi(x))i for any outcome of the simulation we compute V L (p) we repeat for different inputs (p, a, mean, variances and correlations of αi and βi) A typical outcome is:

Conclusion 23/23 Messages: Liquidity risk arises when msdc are ignored Liquidity risk can be captured by a redefinition of the concept of value, which depends on a liquidity policy Coherent risk measures are perfectly adequate to deal with liquidity risk To do: study possible realistic (yet analytically tractable) stochastic models for a msdc (many studies of the bid-ask spread in the literature) portfolio optimization with liquidity risk