The New Keynesian Model

Similar documents
Monetary Economics Final Exam

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

The Basic New Keynesian Model

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

The new Kenesian model

Satya P. Das NIPFP) Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model 1 / 18

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

DSGE Models with Financial Frictions

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility

Advanced Topics in Monetary Economics II 1

Staggered Wages, Sticky Prices, and Labor Market Dynamics in Matching Models. by Janett Neugebauer and Dennis Wesselbaum

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

The Role of Firm-Level Productivity Growth for the Optimal Rate of Inflation

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

THE ZERO LOWER BOUND, THE DUAL MANDATE,

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

The Extensive Margin of Trade and Monetary Policy

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Dynamic AD and Dynamic AS

Money and monetary policy in Israel during the last decade

Advanced Topics in Monetary Economics II 1

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Money and monetary policy in the Eurozone: an empirical analysis during crises

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1.

PART 4 Theory of Economic Fluctuations

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Product Cycles and Prices: Search Foundation

A dynamic model with nominal rigidities.

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Optimality of Inflation and Nominal Output Targeting

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Introduction to DSGE Models

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Alternative theories of the business cycle

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Money in an RBC framework

Do Nominal Rigidities Matter for the Transmission of Technology Shocks?

Recently the study of optimal monetary policy has shifted from an

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

Phillips Curve Instability and Optimal Monetary Policy. Troy Davig July 2007; Revised November 2015 RWP 07-04

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

The science of monetary policy

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity

Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8

Nominal Rigidities, Asset Returns and Monetary Policy

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series. Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier.

Uninsured Unemployment Risk and Optimal Monetary Policy

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Inflation s Role in Optimal Monetary-Fiscal Policy

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve

GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy

On the Implications of Structural Transformation for Inflation and Monetary Policy (Work in Progress)

A Model with Costly-State Verification

Gali Chapter 6 Sticky wages and prices

Forward Guidance Under Uncertainty

Should Central Banks Target Investment Prices?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SIMPLE ANALYTICS OF THE GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIER. Michael Woodford

Endogenous Trade Participation with Incomplete Exchange Rate Pass-Through

Fiscal and Monetary Policy in a New Keynesian Model with Tobin s Q Investment Theory Features

Discussion Paper Series

1.3 Nominal rigidities

Macroeconomics and finance

Online appendix. A. General equilibrium model of heterogeneous bank shocks. April 30, 2013

TECHNOLOGY SHOCKS IN A TWO-SECTOR DSGE MODEL

Does a Currency Union Need a Capital Market Union?

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Empirical Properties of Inflation Expectations and the Zero Lower Bound

The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk

The Government Spending Multiplier in a Model with the Cost Channel

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

Transcription:

The New Keynesian Model Noah Williams University of Wisconsin-Madison Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 1 / 37

Research strategy policy as systematic and predictable...the central bank s stabilization goals can be most effectively achieved only to the extent that the central bank not only acts appropriately, but is also understood by the private sector to predictably act in a certain way. The ability to successfully steer private-sector expectations is favored by a decision procedure that is based on a rule, since in this case the systematic character of the central bank s actions can be most easily made apparent to the public. (Woodford 2003, p. 465) Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 2 / 37

Money, prices, and nominal rigidities Flexible-price models Flexible price models share a common property the inverse of the aggregate price level, 1/P t, behaves like a speculative asset price. Yet this seems at odds with the evidence. Many researchers accept that some degree of nominal rigidity in prices and/or wages is necessary if a dynamic general equilibrium model is going to have any chance of matching macro time series data and be useful for policy exercises. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 3 / 37

Price Stickiness Tendency of prices to adjust slowly in economy. Sources: Monopolistic competition and menu costs. Under perfect competition, market forces prices to adjust rapidly. But in many markets, sellers produce differentiated goods with some market power: monopolistic competition. Sellers set prices. Menu costs: costs of changing prices may lead to price stickiness. Even small costs like these may prevent sellers from changing prices often. Since competition isn t perfect, having the wrong price temporarily won t affect the seller s profits much. The firm will change prices when demand or costs of production change enough to warrant the price change. We ll actually study the simpler time-dependent pricing rules, rather than menu cost models which lead to state-dependent pricing. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 4 / 37

Empirical Evidence on Price Stickiness Carlton (1986): Industrial prices often fixed for several years, changed more often the more competitive the industry. Kashyap (1995): Catalog prices don t seem to change much from one issue to the next. Menu costs may not be cause of stickiness. Bils-Klenow (2004): Half of all goods prices last more that 5.5 months. Varies dramatically over types of goods, amount of competition in industry. Steinsson-Nakamura (2008): Excluding sales, frequency of price changes is 9-12 % per month. Median duration regular prices is 8-11 months. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 5 / 37

Table 2 Monthly Frequency of Price Changes for Selected Categories % of Price Quotes with Price Changes % of Price Quotes with Price Changes, excluding observations with item substitutions All goods and services 26.1 (1.0) 23.6 (1.0) Durable Goods 29.8 (2.5) 23.6 (2.5) Nondurable Goods 29.9 (1.5) 27.5 (1.5) Services 20.7 (1.5) 19.3 (1.6) Food 25.3 (1.8) 24.1 (1.9) Home Furnishings 26.4 (1.8) 24.2 (1.8) Apparel 29.2 (3.0) 22.7 (3.1) Transportation 39.4 (1.8) 35.8 (1.9) Medical Care 9.4 (3.2) 8.3 (3.3) Entertainment 11.3 (3.5) 8.5 (3.6) Other 11.0 (3.3) 10.0 (3.3) Raw Goods 54.3 (1.9) 53.7 (1.7) Processed Goods 20.5 (0.8) 17.6 (0.7) Notes: Frequencies are weighted means of category components. Standard errors are in parentheses. Durables, Nondurables and Services coincide with U.S. National Income and Product Account classifications. Housing (reduced to home furnishings in our data), apparel, transportation, medical care, entertainment, and other are BLS Major Groups for the CPI. Raw goods include gasoline, motor oil and coolants, fuel oil and other fuels, electricity, natural gas, meats, fish, eggs, fresh fruits, fresh vegetables, and fresh milk and Noah Williams cream. (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 6 / 37

FIGURE 3: PRICE OF TRISCUIT 9.5 oz IN DOMINICK S FINER FOODS SUPERMARKET IN CHICAGO Figure 1 2.65 Triscuit 9.5 oz price 1.14 1 399 week Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 7 / 37

Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 8 / 37

Adding nominal rigidities Objectives 1 To examine how the introduction of nominal rigidity affects analysis of macro issues. 2 To see how models employed in policy analysis can be derived when some degree of nominal rigidity is introduced into the dynamic general equilibrium models examined so far. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 9 / 37

Basic new Keynesian model Three basic components 1 An expectational IS curve (Euler equation) 2 An inflation adjustment equation (Phillips curve/price setting) 3 A specification of policy behavior Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 10 / 37

An optimizing based model The model consists of households who supply labor, purchase goods for consumption, and hold money and bonds, and firms who hire labor and produce and sell differentiated products in monopolistically competitive goods markets. The basic model of monopolistic competition is drawn from Dixit and Stiglitz (1977). Each firm set the price of the good it produces, but not all firms reset their price each period. Households and firms behave optimally: households maximize the expected present value of utility and firms maximize profits. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 11 / 37

Households The preferences of a representative household defined over a composite consumption good C t, real money balances M t /P t, and leisure 1 N t, where N t is the time devoted to market employment. Households maximize E t i=0 [ C 1 σ β i t+i 1 σ + γ ( Mt+i 1 b P t+i ) ] 1 b χ N1+η t+i. (1) 1 + η The composite consumption good consists of differentiate products produced by monopolistically competitive final goods producers (firms). There are a continuum of such firms of measure 1, and firm j produces good c j. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 12 / 37

Households The composite consumption good that enters the household s utility function is defined as [ 1 C t = 0 ] θ c θ 1 θ 1 θ jt dj θ > 1. (2) The parameter θ governs the price elasticity of demand for the individual goods. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 13 / 37

Households The household s decision problem can be dealt with in two stages. 1 Regardless of the level of C t, it will always be optimal to purchase the combination of the individual goods that minimize the cost of achieving this level of the composite good. 2 Given the cost of achieving any given level of C t, the household chooses C t, N t, and M t optimally. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 14 / 37

Households Dealing first with the problem of minimizing the cost of buying C t, the household s decision problem is to subject to [ 1 0 1 min p jt c jt dj c jt 0 ] θ c θ 1 θ 1 θ jt dj Ct, (3) where p jt is the price of good j. Letting ψ t be the Lagrangian multiplier on the constraint, the first order condition for good j is p jt ψ t [ 1 0 ] 1 c θ 1 θ 1 θ jt dj c 1 θ jt = 0. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 15 / 37

Households Rearranging, c jt = (p jt /ψ t ) θ C t. From the definition of the composite level of consumption (2), this implies C t = [ (pjt 1 0 ψ t ) θ C t ] θ 1 θ dj θ θ 1 ( ) 1 θ [ 1 = ψ t 0 ] θ pjt 1 θ θ 1 dj Ct. Solving for ψ t, [ 1 ψ t = 0 ] 1 pjt 1 θ 1 θ dj Pt. (4) Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 16 / 37

Households The Lagrange multiplier is the appropriately aggregated price index for consumption. The demand for good j can then be written as c jt = ( pjt P t ) θ C t. (5) The price elasticity of demand for good j is equal to θ. As θ, the individual goods become closer and closer substitutes, and, as a consequence, individual firms will have less market power. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 17 / 37

Households Given the definition of the aggregate price index in (4), the budget constraint of the household is, in real terms, C t + M t + B ( ) t Wt = N t + M ( ) t 1 Bt 1 + R t 1 + Π t, (6) P t P t P t P t P t where M t (B t ) is the household s nominal holdings of money (one period bonds). Bonds pay a gross nominal rate of interest R t. Real profits received from firms are equal to Π t. In the second stage of the household s decision problem, consumption, labor supply, money, and bond holdings are chosen to maximize (1) subject to (6). Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 18 / 37

Households The following conditions must also hold in equilibrium 1 the Euler condition for the optimal intertemporal allocation of consumption ( ) Ct σ Pt = βr t E t C σ; t+1 (7) P t+1 2 the condition for optimal money holdings: γ ( Mt P t ) b C σ t 3 the condition for optimal labor supply: = R t 1 R t ; (8) χn η t C σ t = W t P t. (9) Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 19 / 37

Firms Firms maximize profits, subject to three constraints: 1 The first is the production function summarizing the technology available for production. For simplicity, we have ignored capital, so output is a function solely of labor input N jt and an aggregate productivity disturbance Z t : c jt = Z t N jt, E(Z t ) = 1. 2 The second constraint on the firm is the demand curve each faces. This is given by equation (5). 3 The third constraint is that each period some firms are not able to adjust their price. The specific model of price stickiness we will use is due to Calvo (1983). Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 20 / 37

Price adjustment Each period, the firms that adjust their price are randomly selected: a fraction 1 ω of all firms adjust while the remaining ω fraction do not adjust. The parameter ω is a measure of the degree of nominal rigidity; a larger ω implies fewer firms adjust each period and the expected time between price changes is longer. For those firms who do adjust their price at time t, they do so to maximize the expected discounted value of current and future profits. Profits at some future date t + s are affected by the choice of price at time t only if the firm has not received another opportunity to adjust between t and t + s. The probability of this is ω s. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 21 / 37

Price adjustment The firm s decision problem First consider the firm s cost minimization problem, which involves minimizing W t N jt subject to producing c jt = Z t N jt. This problem can be written as min N t W t N t + ϕ n t (c jt Z t N jt ). where ϕ n t is equal to the firm s nominal marginal cost. The first order condition implies W t = ϕ n t Z t, or ϕ n t = W t/z t. Dividing by P t yields real marginal cost as ϕ t = W t / (P t Z t ). Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 22 / 37

Price adjustment The firm s decision problem The firm s pricing decision problem then involves picking p jt to maximize ( ) E t ω i pjt i,t+i Π, ϕ i=0 P t+i, c t+i = t+i [ ( ) 1 θ ( ) ] θ E t ω i pjt pjt i,t+i ϕ i=0 P t+i C t+i, t+i P t+i where the discount factor i,t+i is given by β i (C t+i /C t ) σ and profits are [( ) ] pjt Π(p jt ) = c jt+i ϕ t+i c jt+i P t+i Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 23 / 37

Price adjustment All firms adjusting in period t face the same problem, so all adjusting firms will set the same price. Let pt be the optimal price chosen by all firms adjusting at time t. The first order condition for the optimal choice of pt is ( ) ( 1 p E t ω i ) 1 θ ( ) ( i,t+i [(1 θ) t 1 p ) ] θ + θϕ t i=0 p jt P t+i t+i pt P t+i Using the definition of i,t+i, ( p ) t = P t ( θ ) Et i=0 ω i β i C 1 σ θ 1 E t i=0 ω i β i C 1 σ t+i t+i ϕ t+i ( Pt+i P t ) θ C t+i =0 ( Pt+i ) θ 1. (10) P t Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 24 / 37

The case of flexible prices If all firms are able to adjust their prices every period (ω = 0): ( p ) ( ) t θ = ϕ θ 1 t = µϕ t. (11) P t Each firm sets its price p t equal to a markup µ > 1 over nominal marginal cost P t ϕ t. When prices are flexible, all firms charge the same price, and ϕ t = µ 1. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 25 / 37

The case of flexible prices Using the definition of real marginal cost, this means W t P t = Z t µ. However, the real wage must also equal the marginal rate of substitution between leisure and consumption to be consist with household optimization: χn η t C σ t = Z t µ. (12) Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 26 / 37

The case of flexible prices Flexible-price output Let a ˆx t denote the percent deviation of a variable X t around its steady-state. Then, the steady-state yields η ˆn t + σĉ t = ẑ t. Now using the fact that ŷ t = ˆn t + ẑ t and ŷ t = ĉ t, flexible-price equilibrium output ŷt f can be expressed as [ ] 1 + η ŷt f = ẑ t. (13) η + σ Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 27 / 37

The case of sticky prices When prices are sticky (ω > 0), the firm must take into account expected future marginal cost as well as current marginal cost when setting p t. The aggregate price index is an average of the price charged by the fraction 1 ω of firms setting their price in period t and the average of the remaining fraction ω of all firms who set prices in earlier periods. Because the adjusting firms were selected randomly from among all firms, the average price of the non-adjusters is just the average price of all firms that was prevailing in period t 1. Thus, the average price in period t satisfies P 1 θ t = (1 ω)(p t ) 1 θ + ωp 1 θ t 1. (14) Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 28 / 37

Inflation adjustment Using the first order condition for p t and approximating around a zero average inflation, flexible-price equilibrium, π t = βe t π t+1 + κ ˆϕ t (15) where (1 ω) [1 βω] κ = ω Equation (15) is often referred to as the New Keynesian Phillips curve. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 29 / 37

Forward-looking inflation adjustment The New Keynesian Phillips curve is forward-looking; when a firm sets its price, it must be concerned with inflation in the future because it may be unable to adjust its price for several periods. Solving forward, π t = κ i=0 β i E t ˆϕ t+i, Inflation is a function of the present discounted value of current and future real marginal cost. Inflation depends on real marginal cost and not directly on a measure of the gap between actual output and some measure of potential output or on a measure of unemployment relative to the natural rate, as is typical in traditional Phillips curves. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 30 / 37

Real marginal cost and the output gap The firm s real marginal cost is equal to the real wage it faces divided by the marginal product of labor: ϕ t = W t /P t Z t. Because nominal wages have been assumed to be completely flexible, the real wage must equal the marginal rate of substitution between leisure and consumption. In a flexible price equilibrium, all firms set the same price, so (11) implies that ϕ = µ 1. From equation (9), ŵ t ˆp t = η ˆn t + σŷ t Recalling that ĉ t = ŷ t, ŷ t = ˆn t + ẑ t, the percentage deviation of real marginal cost around the flexible price equilibrium is ˆϕ t = [η ˆn t + σŷ t ] ẑ t = (η + σ) [ ŷ t ( 1 + η η + σ ) ẑ t ]. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 31 / 37

Real marginal cost and the output gap But from (13), this can be written as ˆϕ t = (η + σ) ( ŷ t ŷ f t ). (16) Using these results, the inflation adjustment equation (15) becomes π t = βe t π t+1 + κx t (17) where κ = (η + σ) κ = (η + σ) (1 ω) [1 βω] /ω and x t ŷ t ŷt f is the gap between actual output and the flexible-price equilibrium output. This inflation adjustment or forward-looking Phillips curve relates output, in the form of the deviation around the level of output that would occur in the absence of nominal price rigidity, to inflation. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 32 / 37

The demand side of the model Start with Euler condition for optimal consumption choice C σ t Linearize around steady-state: or ( ) Pt = βr t E t Ct+1 σ P t+1 σĉ t = (î t E t p t+1 + p t ) σe t ĉ t+1 ĉ t = E t ĉ t+1 Goods market equilibrium (no capital) ( ) 1 (î t E t p t+1 + p t ). σ Y t = C t. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 33 / 37

The demand side of the model Linearization Euler condition becomes ŷ t = E t ŷ t+1 ( ) 1 (î t E t p t+1 + p t ). σ This is often called an expectational IS curve, to make the comparisons with old-style Keynesian models clear. Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 34 / 37

Demand and the output gap Express in terms of the output gap x t = ŷ t ŷt f : ) ( ) 1 ( ) ŷ t ŷt f = E t (ŷ t+1 ŷt+1 f (î t E t p t+1 + p t ) + E t ŷt+1 f ŷt f σ or x t = E t x t+1 where r t = î t E t p t+1 + p t and r n t σ ( ) 1 (r t rt n ), σ ( E t ŷ f t+1 ŷ f t Notice that the nominal interest rate affects output through the interest rate gap r t r n t. ). Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 35 / 37

The general equilibrium model Two equation system π t = βe t π t+1 + κx t ( ) 1 x t = E t x t+1 (î t E t π t+1 rt n ) σ Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 36 / 37

The general equilibrium model Consistent with optimizing behavior by households and firms budget constraints market equilibrium Two equations but three unknowns: x t, π t, and i t need to specify monetary policy Noah Williams (UW Madison) New Keynesian model 37 / 37