Economics 109 Practice Problems 1, Vincent Crawford, Spring 2002

Similar documents
6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Economics 171: Final Exam

Iterated Dominance and Nash Equilibrium

Name. Answers Discussion Final Exam, Econ 171, March, 2012

Name. FINAL EXAM, Econ 171, March, 2015

Week 8: Basic concepts in game theory

Using the Maximin Principle

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 5

MATH 4321 Game Theory Solution to Homework Two

HW Consider the following game:

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV. If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to

Introduction to Game Theory

Game Theory: Additional Exercises

Introduction to Multi-Agent Programming

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

Game Theory Notes: Examples of Games with Dominant Strategy Equilibrium or Nash Equilibrium

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

Rationalizable Strategies

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

1 Solutions to Homework 3

CMSC 474, Introduction to Game Theory 16. Behavioral vs. Mixed Strategies

Econ 711 Homework 1 Solutions

SI 563 Homework 3 Oct 5, Determine the set of rationalizable strategies for each of the following games. a) X Y X Y Z

University of Hong Kong

Week 8: Basic concepts in game theory

Introduction to Game Theory

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

CS 798: Homework Assignment 4 (Game Theory)

Answers to Problem Set 4

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions

CS711 Game Theory and Mechanism Design

Problem 3 Solutions. l 3 r, 1

Game Theory I. Author: Neil Bendle Marketing Metrics Reference: Chapter Neil Bendle and Management by the Numbers, Inc.

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1

Expectations & Randomization Normal Form Games Dominance Iterated Dominance. Normal Form Games & Dominance

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

Player 2 H T T -1,1 1, -1

Game Theory: Minimax, Maximin, and Iterated Removal Naima Hammoud

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

The Nash equilibrium of the stage game is (D, R), giving payoffs (0, 0). Consider the trigger strategies:

1 R. 2 l r 1 1 l2 r 2

ODD. Answers to Odd-Numbered Problems, 4th Edition of Games and Information, Rasmusen PROBLEMS FOR CHAPTER 1

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

University at Albany, State University of New York Department of Economics Ph.D. Preliminary Examination in Microeconomics, June 20, 2017

MIDTERM 1 SOLUTIONS 10/16/2008

Preliminary Notions in Game Theory

Agenda. Game Theory Matrix Form of a Game Dominant Strategy and Dominated Strategy Nash Equilibrium Game Trees Subgame Perfection

Game Theory. Analyzing Games: From Optimality to Equilibrium. Manar Mohaisen Department of EEC Engineering

m 11 m 12 Non-Zero Sum Games Matrix Form of Zero-Sum Games R&N Section 17.6

Solution to Tutorial 1

Economic Management Strategy: Hwrk 1. 1 Simultaneous-Move Game Theory Questions.

that internalizes the constraint by solving to remove the y variable. 1. Using the substitution method, determine the utility function U( x)

Solution to Tutorial /2013 Semester I MA4264 Game Theory

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1

Sequential-move games with Nature s moves.

Chapter 10: Mixed strategies Nash equilibria, reaction curves and the equality of payoffs theorem

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2

ECE 586GT: Problem Set 1: Problems and Solutions Analysis of static games

Bayesian Nash Equilibrium

Advanced Microeconomics

Econ 414 Midterm Exam

B w x y z a 4,4 3,3 5,1 2,2 b 3,6 2,5 6,-3 1,4 A c -2,0 2,-1 0,0 2,1 d 1,4 1,2 1,1 3,5

CMPSCI 240: Reasoning about Uncertainty

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Homework #2 Psychology 101 Spr 03 Prof Colin Camerer

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Simon Fraser University Spring 2014

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 601 Prof. James Peck Extra Practice Problems Answers (for final)

Now we return to simultaneous-move games. We resolve the issue of non-existence of Nash equilibrium. in pure strategies through intentional mixing.

Game Theory Problem Set 4 Solutions

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture X: Introduction to Game Theory

Microeconomics II. CIDE, Spring 2011 List of Problems

ECO 5341 (Section 2) Spring 2016 Midterm March 24th 2016 Total Points: 100

Notes for Section: Week 4

MIDTERM ANSWER KEY GAME THEORY, ECON 395

ECO303: Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Benjamin Balak, Spring 2008

Game Theory. VK Room: M1.30 Last updated: October 22, 2012.

Test 1. ECON3161, Game Theory. Tuesday, September 25 th

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

CHAPTER 9 Nash Equilibrium 1-1

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Problem Set 2 - SOLUTIONS

January 26,

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

Problem Set 2 Answers

MS&E 246: Lecture 2 The basics. Ramesh Johari January 16, 2007

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

An introduction on game theory for wireless networking [1]

Answers to Text Questions and Problems Chapter 9

Transcription:

Economics 109 Practice Problems 1, Vincent Crawford, Spring 2002 P1. Consider the following game. There are two piles of matches and two players. The game starts with Player 1 and thereafter the players take turns. When it is a player s turn, he can remove any number of matches from either pile. Each player is required to remove some number of matches if either pile has matches remaining, and he can only remove matches from a pile at a time. Whichever players removes the last match wins the game. Winning gives a player a payoff equal to 1, and losing gives a player a payoff equal to 0. Write down the strategic form of this game when the initial configuration of the piles has one match in one of the piles, and two in the other one. P2. Consider the game Matching Pennies described and analyzed in class, but when the Row player R must go first and the Column player C has a spy who tells him, before C chooses his own action, whether the R is going to choose Heads or Tails. Assume that the spy can always predict R's choice correctly, and never lies. Also assume that both players know everything about the game, including the existence of the spy and exactly what information about R's choice the spy will give to C. (a) Draw the game tree (or "extensive form") for this game. Indicate clearly each player's choices, the information he has when he makes them, and the payoffs that result from each combination of choices. (b) Bearing in mind that a strategy must be a complete contingent plan for playing the game, list R's pure strategies. Then list C's pure strategies. (c) Draw the payoff matrix of the game. (Please make R the Row player and C the Column player, and be sure to identify C's pure strategies clearly enough so that someone could tell from your description exactly what C is supposed to do in every possible situation.) (d) Which, if any, of C's pure strategies are strictly dominated? Weakly dominated? (e) Use your payoff matrix from (c) to identify which of Row's pure strategies become (weakly or strictly) dominated when C's dominated pure strategies are eliminated. (f) Identify R's optimal strategy or strategies (all of them!) and his associated expected payoff. (There is more than one right way to do this. Pick the one that's easiest for you, but explain your argument.) (g) Identify C's optimal strategy or strategies and his associated expected payoff, again explaining your argument. (h) Show that any combination of R's and C's optimal strategies is in Nash equilibrium. (i) How much is C's spy worth to him, in terms of expected payoff? (That is, compare his equilibrium expected payoffs with and without the spy)? P3. Modify the original Battle of the Sexes game so that the man chooses his strategy first and the woman gets to observe his choice before choosing her strategy (and both know this). Give the game tree and payoff matrix that represent this game, and then find its Nash equilibrium or equilibria. How does your answer change (if at all) if the man chooses first but the woman does not get to observe his choice before choosing her strategy (and both know this)? (Hint: Is it possible, in this case, for the woman to base her choice on the man's choice?) How does your answer change (if at all) if the man goes first, the woman gets to observe his choice before making her own, but the man then gets to revise his choice if he wishes, and his decision to revise or not ends the game (and both know this)? Does the man's initial choice have any effect on the outcome in this case? Explain. 1

P4. Consider an ultimatum bargaining game with two players, R and C, and three possible contracts, A, B, and Z. The rules of bargaining allow R to propose one of these contracts, which C must then either accept or reject. If C accepts R's proposal, it determines the outcome; if he rejects it, the outcome is N (for "No Deal"). R's payoffs for the outcomes A, B, Z, and N are 1, 2, 3, and 0 respectively, and C's payoffs are 2, 1, -1, and 0 respectively. Clearly identifying each player's feasible pure strategies and making R the Row player, write the game tree and payoff matrix and identify the pure-strategy Nash equilibrium or equilibria, and the rollback or subgame-perfect equilibrium or equilibria, when: (a) C can observe, before deciding whether to accept, which contract R has proposed (b) C can observe, before deciding whether to accept, whether R has proposed Z or {either A or B}; but if R has proposed A or B, then C cannot tell which one. (For the game tree here, you don't have to re-draw the tree; just say how it must be changed from your tree for (a).) (c) C cannot observe anything (except that R has proposed one of the three possible contracts) before deciding whether to accept. (Hint: Are there any rollback/subgame-perfect equilibria in which C accepts R's proposal with positive probability?) (d) In which, if any, of the environments described in parts (a), (b), [and (c)] would both players benefit if contracts like Z were made legally unenforceable (so that if Z were proposed and accepted, the outcome would be N, not Z)? Explain. P5. Two people, Rhoda ("R" for short) and Colin ("C") must decide independently whether to try to meet at the fights ("F") or the ballet ("B"). Before R and C decide where to try to meet, R (but not C) must announce her intentions, f or b, about where she plans to go. Then R and C choose, simultaneously and independently, between F and B. R is free to choose either F or B independent of her announcement f or b, but if she announces f but chooses B, or announces b but chooses F, she incurs a cost c 0. If R and C both choose F, R's payoff is 2 less whatever cost she incurs, and C's payoff is 1. If R and C both choose B, R's payoff is 1 less whatever cost she incurs, and C's payoff is 2. If R chooses F but C chooses B, or vice versa, R's payoff is 0 less whatever cost she incurs, and C's payoff is 0. For example, if R announces f, chooses B, and C chooses B, R's payoff is 1-c. The structure of the game, including the announcement stage, is common knowledge. (a) Clearly identifying players' decisions and information sets, draw the extensive form (game tree) for this game. (It's easier to draw the information sets if you put both of R's decisions first.) (b) Identify the pure-strategy subgame-perfect equilibrium outcome(s) and payoffs when c > 2. (c) Identify the pure-strategy subgame-perfect equilibrium outcome(s) and payoffs when 0 c < 1. P6. (F'89 final) I have noticed that when two bicyclists meet going in opposite directions, they sometimes go into oscillations trying to avoid running into each other. (For example, one sometimes swerves to his right at the same time that the other swerves to his left, then they both swerve back in the opposite directions, and so on.) I have found that most of the time I can avoid these oscillations (and the ensuing crashes) by looking off in one direction and not meeting the other cyclist's eyes, so that he is not completely certain that I have seen him. (I usually look toward the side on which I hope to pass him, but it seems to work even when I look to the other side.) Explain this phenomenon as best you can, using whatever model or models you find helpful. 2

P7. (much too long for an exam question, but good practice) The government wishes to motivate two people, Algernon ("A" for short) and Bob ("B"), to register for the draft, but it has enough resources to prosecute only one person who fails to register. Assume that either person's payoff is 3 if he registers, and is therefore not prosecuted; 4 if he does not register, and is not prosecuted; and 0 if he does not register, and is prosecuted. Also assume that the structure of the game, including the rules described below, is common knowledge. Suppose first that A and B must decide whether to register simultaneously, and the government announces that once A and B have had a chance to register, it will check up on them in alphabetical order (A first, then B), prosecuting only the first one (if any) who is found not to have registered. (a) Treating only A and B (not the government) as players, write the extensive form (game tree) and normal form (payoff matrix, making A the Row player), clearly identifying players' strategies. (b) Find A's and B's subgame-perfect equilibrium strategy profiles. (c) Find A's and B's Nash equilibrium strategy profiles (all of them). (d) Find A's and B's rationalizable strategies (all of them). Now suppose that A and B must decide whether to register simultaneously, but the government instead checks up on A and B in random order (with each order equally likely), again prosecuting only the first one (if any) who is found not to have registered; everything else is the same as above. (e) Answer part (a) again, for the new game. (f) Answer part (b) again, for the new game. (g) Answer part (c) again, for the new game. (h) Answer part (d) again, for the new game. Now suppose that A and B must decide whether to register sequentially, with A going first and B observing A's decision before making his own decision, and the government announces that once A and B have had a chance to register, it will check up on them in alphabetical order (A first, then B), prosecuting only the first one (if any) who is found not to have registered. (i) Answer part (a) again, for the new game. (j) Answer part (b) again, for the new game. (k) Answer part (c) again, for the new game. (l) Answer part (d) again, for the new game. Finally, suppose that A and B must again decide whether to register sequentially, with A going first and B observing A's decision before making his own decision, but the government instead checks up on A and B in random order (with each order equally likely), prosecuting only the first one (if any) who is found not to have registered; everything else is the same as above. (m) Answer part (a) again, for the new game. (n) Answer part (b) again, for the new game. (o) Answer part (c) again, for the new game. (p) Answer part (d) again, for the new game. 3

P8. Modify the payoff matrix of Battle of the Sexes to reflect the assumption that, other things equal, the man prefers to be with the woman, but the woman prefers to avoid the man more than she prefers the ballet to the fights. (Choose whatever payoff numbers you like, as long as the order is correct.) Then find the Nash equilibrium or equilibria of the modified game. P9. (fairly hard) Consider a two-person normal-form (payoff-matrix) game in which each player has a finite number of pure strategies. (a) Prove that if the game can be reduced to a single strategy combination by iterated deletion of weakly or strictly dominated strategies (or a mixture of both), then that strategy combination is a Nash equilibrium in the original game. (b) Prove that if the game can be reduced to a single strategy combination by iterated deletion of only strictly dominated strategies, then that strategy combination is the unique Nash equilibrium in the original game. (c) Prove that if the game has no strictly dominated strategies (even if dominated only by mixed strategies), then all of each player's pure strategies are rationalizable. P10. (a) What strategy would you play, against one randomly selected member of this class, in the Stag Hunt game presented in class. Explain. (b) What strategy would you play if the game were modified to include (simultaneously) everyone in the class, with the cooperation of everyone required for success in hunting a stag, but each guaranteed success (still with lower payoff) if he chooses to hunt rabbits alone. Explain. P11. Consider a Cournot duopoly game in which two firms, 1 and 2, simultaneously choose the quantities they will sell, q 1 and q 2, with the goal of maximizing their profits. Each firm's cost is c per unit sold, and the price each firm receives per unit sold, given q 1 and q 2, is P(q 1, q 2 ) = a b (q 1 + q 2 ), where a > 0 and b > 0. The structure of the game is common knowledge. (a) Write firm i's profit-maximization problem and use the first- and second-order conditions to derive its best-response function, expressing its optimal output q i as a function of firm j's output q j. (b) Identify the Nash equilibrium strategy profile(s) in this game. (c) Which values of q i are rational for firm i, for some feasible value of q j? (d) Which values of q j are rational for firm j, for some value of q i that is consistent with firm i being rational? (e) Identify each firm's rationalizable strategies in this game. (Hint: This can be done using algebra, but I think it's easier to use your answer to (a) and a graphical argument.) (f) Answer parts (a), (b), and (e) (yes, (e)) again for the analogous game with three firms, 1, 2, and 3, with unit cost c, outputs q 1, q 2, and q 3, and price per unit sold P(q 1, q 2, q 3 ) = a b (q 1 + q 2 + q 3 ). 4

P12. Find all pure strategy Nash equilibria in each of the following simultaneous-move games. In each case, comment on whether the prediction of the theory is reasonable. Where there are multiple equilibria, comment on how one might get selected. (i) Orange Crimson (ii) Left Right Orange 1, 1 0, 0 Up 100, 0.1 99, -0.1 Ann Crimson 0, 0 1, 1 Ann Down 101, 0.1 0, -0.1 (iii) C1 Charles C2 B1 B2 B1 B2 A1 2,2,2 2,3,2 A1 2,2,3 0,1,1 Ann A2 3,2,2 1,1,0 Ann A2 1,0,1 1,1,1 In games (i) and (ii), the payoffs in each cell are in the order (Ann, ). In game (iii) the payoffs are in the order (Ann,, Charles), and Charles's decision is to choose matrix C1 or matrix C2. P13. Determine the Row and Column players' optimal strategies in the following zero-sum twoperson games: (a) L C R FR (b) T 2-3 -1 1 M -1 1-2 2 B -1 2-1 3 L C R FR T 3-3 -2-4 M -4-2 -1 1 B 1-1 2 0 5