Capital in the 21 st century

Similar documents
Inequality and growth Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics

Capital in the 21 st century

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Visby, June

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Cologne, December 5 th 2013

Econ 133 Global Inequality and Growth. Inequality between labor and capital. Gabriel Zucman

Capital is Back: Wealth-Income Ratios in Rich Countries Thomas Piketty & Gabriel Zucman Paris School of Economics October 2012

About Capital in the 21 st Century

Wealth, Inequality & Taxation T. Piketty, IMF Supplementary slides

Should the Rich Pay for Fiscal Adjustment? Income and Capital Tax Options

Rethinking Wealth Taxation

FIGURE I.1. Income inequality in the United States,

LECTURE 14: THE INEQUALITY OF CAPITAL OWNERSHIP IN EUROPE AND THE USA

Lecture 4: From capital/income ratios to capital shares

Global economic inequality: New evidence from the World Inequality Report

Thomas Piketty s Capital in the 21 st Century

long run inequality History and Inequality University of Oslo

Income Inequality in France, : Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA)

Wealth, inequality & assets: where is Europe heading?

LECTURE 9: THE RETURN OF CAPITAL IN THE 21 ST CENTURY

Inequality, Capitalism & Crisis in the Long Run. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Paris, AFEP Conference, July 6 th 2012

Inequality Dynamics in France, : Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA)

From Communism to Capitalism: Private vs. Public Property and Rising. Inequality in China and Russia

SKEMA BUSINESS SCHOOL Global risk and the mounting wealth gap Michel Henry Bouchet

From Communism to Capitalism: Private Versus Public Property and Inequality in China and Russia

Wealth, Inequality & Taxation. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Berlin FU, June 13 th 2013 Lecture 1: Roadmap & the return of wealth

Reflections on capital taxation

LECTURE 11: INCOME INEQUALITY IN EUROPE AND THE USA

Inequality and Social Mobility. Econ 101

The Elephant Curve of Global Inequality and Growth *

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL INEQUALITY DYNAMICS: NEW FINDINGS FROM WID.WORLD

Graduate Public Finance

Maurizio Franzini and Mario Planta

Lecture 3: Income & Wage Taxation Over Time & Across Countries (check on line for updated versions)

LECTURE 3: MEASURING THE WEALTH OF NATIONS. Dr. Aidan Regan Website:

The Distribution of US Wealth, Capital Income and Returns since Emmanuel Saez (UC Berkeley) Gabriel Zucman (LSE and UC Berkeley)

ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality

ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality

GLOBAL INEQUALITY AND AUSTRALIA S ROLE

Applying Generalized Pareto Curves to Inequality Analysis

Distributional National Accounts DINA

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

Two Cheers for Piketty

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Capitalism, Inequality & Globalization. Public University of Navarre Pamplona, Spain May 21 st 2018 J. E. Stiglitz

Capital Accumulation, Private Property, and Inequality in China,

Econ 133 Global Inequality and Growth. What is Income? Gabriel Zucman

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. Models of the wealth distribution. Gabriel Zucman

Study Questions. Lecture 15 International Macroeconomics

Study Questions. Lecture 1 Overview of the World Economy

Econ 133 Global Inequality and Growth. What is Income? Gabriel Zucman

Lecture 4: Income Taxes Over Time & Across Countries

Income Inequality in Korea,

Measuring inequality Issues to be addressed by the HLEG subgroup on income and wealth inequality

On the distribution of wealth and the share of inheritance

Globalization, Inequality, and Tax Justice

Study Questions (with Answers) Lecture 15 International Macroeconomics

CAPITAL IN THE 21 ST CENTURY*

The Crisis of the 2020s:

LECTURE 12: THE 1 PERCENT IN EUROPE AND THE USA

WORKING PAPERS INFORUM WORKING PAPER Investment and Exports: A Trade Share Perspective. Douglas Nyhus Qing Wang.

World Inequality. Executive Summary. Facundo Alvaredo. Emmanuel Saez Gabriel Zucman. English version. Coordinated by

INCOME AND WEALTH INEQUALITY: EVIDENCE AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS*

Table 4.1 Income Distribution in a Three-Person Society with A Constant Marginal Utility of Income

Fiscal Fact. Reversal of the Trend: Income Inequality Now Lower than It Was under Clinton. Introduction. By William McBride

Piketty s Capital in the Twenty-First Century: Criticisms and Debates

Dr Piketty on wealth and capital: Accumulation vs. finance

Finance, an Inequality Factor

Executive Summary. Trends in Inequality: Globally and Nationally. How inequality constraints growth

Income and Wealth Concentration in Switzerland over the 20 th Century

TOP INCOME SHARES IN THE LONG RUN: AN OVERVIEW

How fat is the top tail of the wealth distribution?

Working paper series. Simplified Distributional National Accounts. Thomas Piketty Emmanuel Saez Gabriel Zucman. January 2019

Introduction of World Wealth and Income Database

Lecture 4: Inequality in the long run: labor income vs capital ownership

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

The Material Well-Being of the Poor and the Middle Class since 1980

STRUCTURAL SHIFTS AND CHALLENGES IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY M I C H A E L S P E N C E N E W D E L H I J A N U A R Y

TOP INCOMES IN THE UNITED STATES AND CANADA OVER THE TWENTIETH CENTURY

2012 Canazei Winter Workshop on Inequality

Discussion: Accounting for Wealth Inequality Dynamics: Methods, Estimates and Simulations for France ( )

QUESTIONNAIRE A I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (2 points each)

Study Questions. Lecture 1 Overview of the World Economy

Deciphering the fall and rise in the net capital share by Matthew Rognlie, MIT BPEA Conference Draft (March, 2015)

Income and Wealth Inequality in Chile

Is there still room for interest rates to rise in the eurozone?

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality

1 Income Inequality in the US

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Income Inequality Matters, but Mobility Is Just as Important. Daniel R. Carroll and Anne Chen

ECON 1100 Global Economics (Fall 2013) The Distribution Function of Government portions for Exam 3

Long-term economic growth Growth and factors of production

Inequality. Ross Garnaut

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.ec] 1 Sep 2014

Living with austerity how is it affecting the better-off half of the 99%?

Lecture 4: Inequality in the long run: labor income vs capital ownership

Against the Consensus Reflections on the Great Recession. Justin Yifu Lin National School of Development Peking University

Secular stagnation, deflation & fiscal policy

TAX REFORM, DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND RISING INEQUALITY

Capitalism, Inequality & Globalization. J. E. Stiglitz Davidson College March 2018

Global Aging and Financial Markets

All Members, India ranks 62 nd among 74 emerging economies on an Inclusive Development Index 2018

Transcription:

Capital in the 21 st century Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Lisbon, April 27 2015

This presentation is based upon Capital in the 21 st century (Harvard University Press, March 2014) This book studies the global dynamics of income and wealth distribution since 18 c in 20+ countries; I use historical data collected over the past 15 years with Atkinson, Saez, Postel-Vinay, Rosenthal, Alvaredo, Zucman, and 30+ others; I try to shift attention from rising income inequality to rising wealth inequality The book includes four parts: Part 1. Income and capital Part 2. The dynamics of the capital/income ratio Part 3. The structure of inequalities Part 4. Regulating capital in the 21 st century In this presentation I will present some results from Parts 2 & 3, focusing upon the long-run evolution of capital/income ratios and wealth concentration (all graphs and series are available on line: see http://piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c )

This presentation: three points 1. The long-run dynamics of income inequality. The end of the Kuznets curve, the end of universal laws. Country-specific institutions and policies matter. 2. The return of a patrimonial (or wealth-based) society in the Old World (Europe, Japan). Wealth-income ratios seem to be returning to very high levels in low growth countries. The metamorphosis of capital. 3. The future of wealth concentration: with high r - g during 21 c (r = net-of-tax rate of return, g = growth rate), then wealth inequality might reach or surpass 19 c oligarchic levels. Need for for more transparency.

Three facts about inequality in the long-run: income inequality, wealth-inequality, wealth-income ratios (Piketty-Saez, «Inequality in the long run», Science 2014) Fact n 1: in 1900-1910, income inequality was higher in Europe than in the United States; in 2000-2010, it is a lot higher in the United States

50% Figure 1. Income inequality: Europe and the U.S., 1900-2010 Share of top income decile in total pretax income (decennial averages) 45% 40% 35% 30% Top 10% income share: Europe Top 10% income share: U.S. 25% 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 The share of total income accruing to top decile income holders was higher in Europe than in the U.S. around 1900-1910; it is a lot higher in the U.S. than in Europe around 2000-2010. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c (fig.9,8)

Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2012 50% Share of top decile in national income 45% 40% 35% 30% Share of top decile in total income (including capital gains) Excluding capital gains 25% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 The top decile share in U.S. national income dropped from 45-50% in the 1910s-1920s to less than 35% in the 1950s (this is the fall documented by Kuznets); it then rose from less than 35% in the 1970s to 45-50% in the 2000s-2010s. Sources and series: see

50% Figure 1. Income inequality: Europe and the U.S., 1900-2010 Share of top income decile in total pretax income (decennial averages) 45% 40% 35% 30% Top 10% income share: Europe Top 10% income share: U.S. 25% 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 The share of total income accruing to top decile income holders was higher in Europe than in the U.S. around 1900-1910; it is a lot higher in the U.S. than in Europe around 2000-2010. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c (fig.9,8)

50% Top 10% Income Share: Europe, U.S. and Japan, 1900-2010 U.S. Share of top decile in total income 45% 40% 35% 30% Europe Japan 25% 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 The top decile income share was higher in Europe than in the U.S. in 1900-1910; it is a lot higher in the U.S. in 2000-2010. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c.

The rise in US inequality in recent decades is mostly due to rising inequality of labor income It is due to a mixture of reasons: changing supply and demand for skills; race between education and technology; globalization; more unequal to access to skills in the US (rising tuitions, insufficient public investment); unprecedented rise of top managerial compensation in the US (changing incentives, cuts in top income tax rates); falling minimum wage in the US institutions and policies matter

This presentation: three points 1. The long-run dynamics of income inequality. The end of the Kuznets curve, the end of universal laws. 2. The return of a patrimonial (or wealth-based) society in the Old World (Europe, Japan). Wealth-income ratios seem to be returning to very high levels in low growth countries. Intuition: in a slow-growth society, wealth accumulated in the past can naturally become very important. In the very long run, this can be relevant for the entire world. Not bad in itself, but new challenges. The metamorphosis of capital call for new regulations of property relations. 3. The future of wealth concentration: with high r - g during 21 c, then wealth inequality might reach or surpass 19 c oligarchic levels.

Fact n 2: wealth inequality is always a lot higher than income inequality; it is now higher in the US than in Europe Fact n 3: wealth inequality is less extreme today than a century ago in Europe, although the total capitalization of private wealth relative to national income has now recovered from the 1914-1945 shocks

100% Figure 2. Wealth inequality: Europe and the U.S., 1870-2010 Share of top wealth decile in total net wealth (decennial averages) 90% 80% 70% 60% Top 10% wealth share: Europe Top 10% wealth share: U.S. 50% 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010 The share of total net wealth belonging to top decile wealth holders has become higher in the US than in Europe over the course of the 20 th century. But it is still smaller than what it was in Europe before World War 1. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c (fig.10,6)

700% Figure 3. Wealth-income ratios: Europe and the U.S., 1900-2010 Total market value of net private wealth (% national income) (decennial averages) 600% 500% 400% 300% Europe 200% 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 U.S. Total net private wealth was worth about 6-7 years of national income in Europe prior to World War 1, down to 2-3 years in 1950-1960, back up to 5-6 years in 2000-2010. In the US, the U-shapped pattern was much less marked. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c (fig.5,1)

The metamorphosis of capital There s nothing bad with high wealth-income ratios (postwar reconstruction, growth slowdown), but this creates new policy challenges: financial regulation, real estate bubbles, return of inheritance A multidimensional approach to the history of capital and property relations: from land to business assets, foreign assets, real estate, public debt, immaterial capital, etc.

Figure S5.2. Private capital in rich countries: from the Japanese to the Spanish bubble 800% U.S.A Japan 700% Germany France Value of private capital (% of national income) 600% 500% 400% 300% U.K. Canada Spain Italy Australia 200% 100% 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Private capital almost reached 8 years of national income in Spain at the end of the 2000s (ie. one more year than Japan in 1990). Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c.

Capital & inequality in America Inequality in America = a different structure as in Europe: more egalitarian in some ways, more inegalitarian in others The New World in the 19 th century: the land of opportunity (capital accumulated in the past matters less than in Europe; perpetual pop. growth as a way to reduce the level of inherited wealth and wealth concentration) and also the land of slavery: extreme form of property relation Northern US were in many ways more egalitarian than Old Europe; but Southern US were more inegalitarian We still have the same ambiguous relationship of America with inequality today: in some ways more merit-based; in other ways more violent («meritocratic extremism»)

Capital & inequality in Germany Lower market values of capital assets in Germany: lower real estate prices, and lower stock market capitalization of corporations Stakeholder capitalism: shareholders have to share power with worker representatives, regional govt, etc., so that the market value is much less than book value of corporation Apparently this does not prevent German companies from producing good cars This clearly illustrates that market and social values of capital can differ; property relations are socially, legally and historically determined

This presentation: three points 1. The long-run dynamics of income inequality. The end of the Kuznets curve, the end of universal laws. Countryspecific institutions and policies matter. 2. The return of a patrimonial (or wealth-based) society in the Old World (Europe, Japan). Wealth-income ratios seem to be returning to very high levels in low growth countries. 3. The future of wealth concentration: with high r - g during 21 c (r = net-of-tax rate of return, g = growth rate), then wealth inequality might reach or surpass 19 c oligarchic levels. Conversely, suitable institutions can allow to democratize wealth. Strong need for more transparency about global wealth dynamics and cross-border financial assets, in rich countries as well as in emerging countries (China, Latin America, Africa).

100% Figure 2. Wealth inequality: Europe and the U.S., 1870-2010 Share of top wealth decile in total net wealth (decennial averages) 90% 80% 70% 60% Top 10% wealth share: Europe Top 10% wealth share: U.S. 50% 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010 The share of total net wealth belonging to top decile wealth holders has become higher in the US than in Europe over the course of the 20 th century. But it is still smaller than what it was in Europe before World War 1. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c (fig.10,6)

Conclusions The history of income and wealth inequality is deeply political, social and cultural; it involves beliefs systems, national identities and sharp reversals In a way, both Marx and Kuznets were wrong: there are powerful forces pushing in the direction of rising or reducing inequality; which one dominates depends on the institutions and policies that different societies choose to adopt High r-g can push toward high wealth concentration, but many other forces are also important The ideal solution: progressive taxation, social state, financial transparency, economic democracy Other solutions involve authoritarian political & capital controls (China, Russia), or perpetual population growth (US) US high-inequality trap: oligarchic capture, or lack of historical experience with oligarchy?

Supplementary slides (long lecture version)

The return of a wealth-based society Wealth = capital K = everything we own and that can be sold on a market (net of all debts) (excludes human K, except in slave societies) In textbooks, wealth-income & capital-ouput ratios are supposed to be constant. But the so-called «Kaldor facts» actually rely on little historical evidence. In fact, we observe in Europe & Japan a large recovery of β=k/y in recent decades: β=200-300% in 1950-60s β=500-600% in 2000-10s (i.e. average wealth K was about 2-3 years of average income Y around 1950-1960; it is about 5-6 years in 2000-2010) (with β 600%, if Y 30 000 per capita, then K 180 000 per capita) (currently, K half real estate, half financial assets) Are we heading back to the β=600-700% observed in the wealth-based societies of 18 c -19 c? Or even more?

The simplest way to think about this is the following: in the long-run, β=s/g with s = (net-of-depreciation) saving rate and g = economy s growth rate (population + productivity) With s=10%, g=3%, β 300%; but if s=10%, g=1,5%, β 600% = in slow-growth societies, the total stock of wealth accumulated in the past can naturally be very important capital is back because low growth is back (in particular because population growth 0) in the long run, this can be relevant for the entire planet Note: β=s/g = pure stock-flow accounting identity; it is true whatever the combination of saving motives

Will the rise of capital income-ratio β also lead to a rise of the capital share α in national income? If the capital stock equals β=6 years of income and the average return to capital is equal r=5% per year, then the share of capital income (rent, dividends, interest, profits, etc.) in national income equals α = r x β = 30% Technically, whether a rise in β also leads to a rise in capital share α = r β depends on the elasticity of substitution σ between capital K and labor L in the production function Y=F(K,L) Intuition: σ measures the extent to which workers can be replaced by machines (e.g. Amazon s drones) Standard assumption: Cobb-Douglas production function (σ=1) = as the stock β, the return r exactly in the same proportions, so that α = r x β remains unchanged, like by magic = a stable world where the capital-labor split is entirely set by technology But if σ>1, then the return to capital r falls less than the volume of capital β, so that the product α = r x β Exactly what happened since the 1970s-80s: both the ratio β and the capital share α have increased

With a large rise in β, one can get large rise in α with a production function F(K,L) that is just a little bit more substituable than in the standard Cobb-Douglas model (say if σ=1,5 instead of 1) Maybe it is natural to expect σ over the course of history: more and more diversified uses for capital; extreme case: pure robot-economy (σ=infinity) Less extreme case: there are many possible uses for capital (machines can replace cashiers, drones can replace Amazon s delivery workers, etc.), so that the capital share α continuously; there s no natural corrective mechanism for this The rise of β and α can be a good thing (we could all devote more time to culture, education, health, rather than to our own subsistance), assuming one can answer the following question: who owns the robots?

The future of wealth concentration In all European countries (UK, France, Sweden ), wealth concentration was extremely high in 18 c -19 c & until WW1: about 90% of aggregate wealth for top 10% wealth holders about 60% of aggregate wealth for top 1% wealth-holders = the classic patrimonial (wealth-based) society: a minority lives off its wealth, while the rest of the populaton works (Austen, Balzac) Today wealth concentration is still very high, but less extreme: about 60-70% for top 10%; about 20-30% for top 1% the bottom 50% still owns almost nothing (<5%) but the middle 40% now owns 20-30% of aggregate wealth = the rise of a patrimonial middle class How did it happen, and will it last? Will the patrimonial middle class expend, or will it shrink?

Key finding: there was no decline in wealth concentration prior to World War shocks; was it just due to shocks? Q.: Apart from shocks, what forces determine the long-run level of wealth concentration? A.: In any dynamic, multiplicative wealth accumulation model with random individual shocks (tastes, demographic,returns, wages,..), the steady-state level of wealth concentration is an increasing function of r - g (with r = net-of-tax rate of return and g = growth rate) With growth slowdown and rising tax competition to attract capital, r - g might well rise in the 21 c back to 19 c levels Future values of r also depend on technology (σ>1?) Under plausible assumptions, wealth concentration might reach or surpass 19 c record levels: see global wealth rankings

Capital & inequality in America Inequality in America = a different structure as in Europe: more egalitarian in some ways, more inegalitarian in some other dimensions The New World in the 19 th century: the land of opportunity (capital accumulated in the past mattered much less than in Europe; perpetual demographic growth as a way to reduce the level of inherited wealth and wealth concentration) and also the land of slavery Northern US were in many ways more egalitarian than Old Europe; but Southern US were more inegalitarian We still have the same ambiguous relationship of America with inequality today: in some ways more merit-based; in other ways more violent («meritocratic extremism»)

The US distribution of income has become more unequal than in Europe over the course of the 20 th century; it is now as unequal as pre-ww1 Europe But the structure of inequality is different: US 2013 has less wealth inequality than Europe 1913, but higher inequality of labor income

Higher inequality of labor income in the US could reflect higher inequality in education investment; but it also reflects a huge rise of top executive compensation that it very hard to explain with education and productivity reasonning alone In the US, this is sometime described as more merit-based: the rise of top labor incomes makes it possible to become rich with no inheritance ( Napoleonic prefets) Pb = this can be the worst of all worlds for those who are neither top income earners nor top successors: they are poor, and they are depicted as dump & undeserving (at least, nobody was trying to depict Ancien Regime inequality as fair) It is unclear whether rise of top incomes has a lot to do with merit or productivity: sharp decline in top tax rates & rise of CEO bargaining power are more convincing explanations; chaotic US history of social norms regarding inequality