COLLECTIVE BARGAINING, WAGE RIGIDITIES AND EMPLOYMENT: AN ANALYSIS USING MICROECONOMIC DATA

Similar documents
ASYMMETRIES IN THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INFLATION AND ACTIVITY

Regional convergence in Spain:

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

Staggered Contracts and Unemployment during the Great Recession: Evidence from Spain

Portuguese Banking System: latest developments. 2 nd quarter 2018

Working Paper. Labour market adjustment in Europe during the crisis: microeconomic evidence from the wage dynamics network survey

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

2. International developments

Portuguese Banking System: latest developments. 4 th quarter 2017

Projections for the Portuguese Economy:

This presentation. Downward wage rigidity in EU countries. Based on recent papers on wage rigidity in European countries:

3 Lower interest rates and sectoral changes in interest income

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

BALANCE OF PAYMENTS: BALANCES TABLE 1.1. SOURCE: Banco de España.

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Developments in the economic situation Asociación Española de Directivos, Santa Cruz de Tenerife

The main assumptions underlying the scenario are as follows (see the table):

ARTICLES LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS TO THE RECESSION IN THE EURO AREA

Portuguese Banking System: latest developments. 1 st quarter 2018

Results of non-financial corporations to 2018 Q4: preliminary year-end data. Álvaro Menéndez and Maristela Mulino

Spanish deposit-taking institutions net interest income and low interest rates

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Working Paper No Accounting for the unemployment decrease in Australia. William Mitchell 1. April 2005

Portuguese Banking System: latest developments. 2 nd quarter 2017

Rebuilding of the European and US Economy and Japan. Richard C. Koo Chief Economist Nomura Research Institute Tokyo January 2012

Portugal: economic adjustment and challenges ahead

Firm level evidence on wage dynamics in Europe

Survey on the access to finance of enterprises in the euro area. October 2014 to March 2015

SURVEY OF FINANCIAL COMPETENCES (ECF) 2016: MAIN RESULTS

Eurosystem Wage Dynamics Network. How are firms wages and prices linked: survey evidence in Europe

Portuguese Banking System: latest developments. 1 st quarter 2017

Comparing wage bargaining arrangements: Is the French arrangement unique?

1. THE ECONOMY AND FINANCIAL MARKETS

Introduction. Development of the minimum wage in Spain and international comparison

Labour market dualities The impact on aggregate wage growth

2 Analysing euro area net portfolio investment outflows

II. Underlying domestic macroeconomic imbalances fuelled current account deficits

6/16/2008. Unemployment. In this chapter, you will learn. Assumptions: Natural rate of unemployment. A first model of the natural rate

THE EFFECT OF DEMOGRAPHIC AND SOCIOECONOMIC FACTORS ON HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS* Luísa Farinha** Percentage

Results of non-financial corporations in the first half of 2018

THE EUROSYSTEM S EXPERIENCE WITH FORECASTING AUTONOMOUS FACTORS AND EXCESS RESERVES

CHAPTER 2. Hidden unemployment in Australia. William F. Mitchell

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

Banco de Portugal. Economic Research. Economic bulletin. June Volume 9 Number 2. Economic policy and situation. Articles

Projections for the Portuguese economy in 2017

Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model

Chapter 7 Unemployment and the Labor Market

Seasonal Factors Affecting Bank Reserves

FINANCIAL MARKETS IN EARLY AUGUST 2011 AND THE ECB S MONETARY POLICY MEASURES

Structural Changes in the Maltese Economy

Estimating Okun s Law for Malta

Modern DSGE models: Theory and evidence DISCUSSION OF H. UHLIG S AND M. EICHENBAUM S PRESENTATIONS

SOVEREIGN CDS PREMIA DURING THE CRISIS AND THEIR INTERPRETATION AS A MEASURE OF RISK

Previsions Macroeconòmiques. Macroeconomic scenario for the Catalan economy 2017 and June 2017

24 ECB THE USE OF TRADE CREDIT BY EURO AREA NON-FINANCIAL CORPORATIONS

44 ECB HOW HAS MACROECONOMIC UNCERTAINTY IN THE EURO AREA EVOLVED RECENTLY?

MACROECONOMICS. N. Gregory Mankiw. Unemployment 8/15/2011. In this chapter, you will learn: Natural rate of unemployment.

Upward Nominal Wage Rigidity

The ECB Survey of Professional Forecasters. Fourth quarter of 2016

HIGHER SCHOOL CERTIFICATE EXAMINATION ECONOMICS 2/3 UNIT (COMMON) Time allowed Three hours (Plus 5 minutes reading time)

Article. 1 The employment-gdp relationship since the crisis. The relationship between euro area employment and GDP

How does labour market structure affect the response of economies to shocks?

54 ECB RESULTS OF THE ECB SURVEY OF PROFESSIONAL FORECASTERS FOR THE FOURTH QUARTER OF 2009

Introduction and summary

Portuguese Banking System: latest developments. 3 rd quarter 2017

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF RISING THE RETIREMENT AGE: LESSONS FROM THE SEPTEMBER 1993 LAW*

Labour Cost Adjustment in Estonia During and After the Crisis

NATIONAL BANK OF SERBIA. Speech at the presentation of the Inflation Report May Dr Jorgovanka Tabaković, Governor

A Study on the Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity. in Korea

How the Portuguese firms adjusted to the economic and financial crisis: main shocks and channels of adjustment. Fernando Martins Banco de Portugal

QUARTERLY REPORT ON THE SPANISH ECONOMY OVERVIEW

HOUSEHOLD FINANCE AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY: A COMPARISON OF THE MAIN RESULTS FOR MALTA WITH THE EURO AREA AND OTHER PARTICIPATING COUNTRIES

Unemployment and the Labor Market

Economics 2005 HIGHER SCHOOL CERTIFICATE EXAMINATION. Total marks 100. Section I. Pages 2 8

QUARTERLY REPORT ON THE SPANISH ECONOMY 1 OVERVIEW

The Role of Unemployment in the Rise in Alternative Work Arrangements. Lawrence F. Katz and Alan B. Krueger* 1 December 31, 2016

LABOUR MARKET FLOWS IN MALTA

Introduction to SPAIN

Postponed recovery. The advanced economies posted a sluggish growth in CONJONCTURE IN FRANCE OCTOBER 2014 INSEE CONJONCTURE

Recent developments and challenges for the Portuguese economy

Projections for the Portuguese economy:

António Antunes** and Nuno Ribeiro**

Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. Consultative Document. Pillar 2 (Supervisory Review Process)

COMMENTS on Income and wealth of Euro Area Households in Times of Ultra- Loose Monetary Policy

An Improved Framework for Assessing the Risks Arising from Elevated Household Debt

SEGMENTING WAGES * Mário Centeno ** Alvaro A. Novo **

Ninth IFC Conference on Are post-crisis statistical initiatives completed?

Portugal: surprise increase in 3Q GDP growth to 0.8% QoQ

Private non-financial sector indebtedness: where do we stand?

Eurozone. Economic Watch FEBRUARY 2017

52 ECB. The 2015 Ageing Report: how costly will ageing in Europe be?

Recent developments in the euro money market. Money Market Contact Group Frankfurt, 18 September 2012

Labour. Overview Latin America and the Caribbean EXECUT I V E S U M M A R Y

Changes in output, employment and wages during recessions in the United Kingdom

NBS MoNthly BulletiN february 2017

Wage Costs and Alternative Margins of Adjustment: Survey Evidence from European Firms

OVERNIGHT INTEREST RATE VOLATILITY AND ITS TRANSMISSION ALONG THE EURO AREA MONEY MARKET YIELD CURVE

Annex I Data definitions and sources

Chapter 6: Unemployment*

The End of the Business Cycle?

Transcription:

COLLECTIVE BARGAINING, WAGE RIGIDITIES AND EMPLOYMENT: AN ANALYSIS USING MICROECONOMIC DATA The author of this article is Ernesto Villanueva of the Directorate General Economics, Statistics and Research. Introduction Reforms of the regulation of collective bargaining were introduced in Spain in 2010 and 2012. Among other objectives, the aim was to improve the response of wages to business cycle fluctuations. During the recessions that began in 1993 and in 2008, wage adjustment was limited, while employment fell significantly. The regulation of collective bargaining in Spain, which introduced minimum wages that had to be paid by all the firms in a particular sector, irrespective of their situation, was one of the sources of wage rigidities that led to most of the weight of adjustment falling on employment. 1 This article offers an estimate of the impact that wage rigidity had on employment losses at the start of the 2008 recession, before the two latest labour market reforms were introduced. This quantification helps to calibrate the extent to which the increase in wage flexibility associated with the collective bargaining reforms may mitigate the destruction of employment in the event of future falls in demand. A number of macroeconomic studies of the consequences for employment of the regulation of collective bargaining basically draw their conclusions from international comparisons. 2 This article, by contrast, uses disaggregated data on individual labour market histories linked to the information available on the collective agreements applicable in each case. The use of disaggregated data is important in the Spanish context, since the regulation of collective bargaining generated heterogeneous wage dynamics across provinces, industries, and workers at the start of the 1993 and 2008 recessions. Of all the workers covered by a collective agreement, 55% had their conditions of employment determined by sectoral agreements at the provincial level, which were not renegotiated frequently. At the same time, the extension of collective agreements to all workers and firms within the scope of the agreement was automatic when the negotiating parties were, in legal terms, sufficiently representative. 3 As a result of these two characteristics, a high proportion of firms ended up being subject to compulsory minimum wages that were infrequently reviewed and that varied from sector to sector and within the same sector from province to province. The response of wage settlements to a change in economic activity has therefore been heterogeneous across sectors and provinces. Even within the same province and sector, the wages of different workers have growth at different rates, depending on how close their wage was to that agreed in the relevant collective agreement. The disaggregated information allows, on one hand, this degree of heterogeneity in wage setting to be accommodated and, on the other, its effects on the evolution of employment at the start of a recession to be verified. 1 Various papers of the ECB s Wage Dynamics Network have explored in detail the determinants of the lack of wage adjustment, beyond collective bargaining. See, also, Messina et al. (2010) or Dickens et al. (2007). 2 Murtin et al. (2014) observe that in France and Spain, where collective agreements are automatically extended, the rates of outflow from employment are relatively higher and the rates of creation of employment lower than in other countries. 3 See Bentolila, Izquierdo and Jimeno (2010). BANCO DE ESPAÑA 1 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, APRIL 2015 COLLECTIVE BARGAINING, WAGE RIGIDITIES AND EMPLOYMENT: AN ANALYSIS USING MICROECONOMIC DATA

A brief overview of studies in countries similar to Spain that have adopted a disaggregated approach for estimating the effect of collective bargaining on employment is presented below. Subsequently, the case of Spain is analysed, first, describing how the wages set by collective agreement were adjusted from the start of the 2008 recession and, second, relating the wage changes and employment losses observed for a sample of workers whose wages were determined at the time by sector-level collective agreements. Collective bargaining, wages and employment: results based on microeconomic data Various studies have documented that, after adjusting for changes in the composition of employment over the cycle, the Spanish and Italian labour markets showed a higher degree of wage rigidity than other advanced economies. 4 One possible explanation for this behaviour is that wages in these countries were largely determined by collective agreements that were infrequently revised, so that, at the start of a recession, a significant number of workers had wage increases set by multi-year agreements signed during the expansion phase. As a result, one would observe in countries like Italy and Spain that, although wage settlements in newly signed collective agreements do respond to changes in local or aggregate unemployment, the prevalence of multi-year collective agreements with pre-set increases makes the wage response at the aggregate level much smaller. 5 At the same time, when there are workers receiving higher wages than those set in the relevant collective agreement, the change in wage growth set in the agreement is only part of the total wage response. For example, the wage increases set in agreements may be offset in the case of these workers by a reduction in other wage components. 6 The extent to which wage rigidities associated with collective bargaining affect individual earnings, and their potential impact on employment, can be directly examined using microeconomic data obtained from the linking of information on firms, workers and agreements. For example, it has been observed in Italy with this type of data that between 1991 and 1999 the wages of a significant portion of workers grew at rates close to those set in the relevant collective agreement, indicating the presence of nominal rigidities. Furthermore, the unemployment rate was higher in those provinces in which larger numbers of workers were subject to these rigidities. 7 Likewise, in Portugal, it has been observed that in the four months following the extension of a collective agreement, the firms affected reduce their employment by around 2 percentage points (pp) more than firms in similar sectors. This reduction was more pronounced during the last recession and relatively greater among smaller firms. 8 With Portuguese data it has also been possible to establish that the impact of the extension of a collective agreement on the labour costs of a firm is greater the higher the proportion of workers whose wages were already close to the wage rates established by such agreement. 9 Wage adjustment in collective agreements in Spain during the crisis During the recession that began in Spain in 2008, wage adjustment was initially slow, since aggregate wages continued to grow until 2011, while employment was falling notably. At the same time, given that the most common level of collective bargaining in Spain was the sectoral/provincial level, firms from a single sector of activity, but located in provinces with 4 For example, a first approximation to the measurement of wage rigidities is to calculate the fraction of workers whose nominal wages have not changed in a given year or, alternatively, have increased at the same rate as inflation [see Dickens et al. (2007)]. A second approach attempts to calculate the response of wage growth to fluctuations in the rate of unemployment, having adjusted for cyclical changes in the characteristics of employed persons [see Haefke et al. (2013) for the United States, Carneiro et al. (2012) for Portugal De la Roca (2014) for Spain]. 5 See Rosolia (2015) and Bentolila, Izquierdo and Jimeno (2010). 6 See Cardoso and Portugal (2005). 7 See DeVicienti et al. (2007). 8 See Martins (2014). 9 See Guimaraes et al. (2014). BANCO DE ESPAÑA 2 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, APRIL 2015 COLLECTIVE BARGAINING, WAGE RIGIDITIES AND EMPLOYMENT: AN ANALYSIS USING MICROECONOMIC DATA

WAGE ADJUSTMENT AT THE START OF THE 1993 AND 2009 RECESSIONS BY YEAR AGREEMENT SIGNED TABLE 1 1993 2009 % workers Wage growth (a) % workers Wage growth (a) 2.6 4.69 8.0 0.99 Signed during the year following the one indicated in the column 65.9 5.05 20.8 1.75 Signed during the year indicated in the column 27.5 6.31 31.5 2.45 Signed two years before the one indicated in the column 2.5 6.55 37.0 2.58 SOURCE: Banco de España, based on the Register of Collective Agreements 1990-2012. a The column "Wage growth" shows the wage growth agreed in percentage points for 1993 (second column) and 2009 (fourth column) for a provincial sectoral agreement, without an indexation clause. collective agreements signed at different times, were subject to different wage rates. This disparity accentuates the negative impact on employment of a fall in aggregate demand at the beginning of a recession. 10 By way of illustration, Table 1 compares the wage growth established in provincial level agreements at the start of the 1993 and 2008 recessions, distinguishing between agreements by when they were signed. During the first recession, the sectoral agreements signed in 1992 set nominal wage increases for 1993 of around 6.5%, while the agreements signed during the following two years set them at around 5%. During the 1993 recession, firms employing a third of workers were subject to wage increases set in expansion phases. At the start of the 2008 recession, firms employing almost 70% of workers were subject to agreements that increased their labour costs of more than 2%, while the firms employing the remaining 30% applied wage increases of around 1%. Identification of the precise moment when agents change their perceptions regarding the behaviour of the economy (and, therefore, when wage adjustment should occur) is a complex task. In the case of the last recession it has been documented that expectations changed rapidly following the failure of Lehman Brothers on 15 September 2008, 11 so that this date can be used to separate those collective agreements signed during the expansion phase (before 15 September 2008) from those signed during the recession (after that date). Analysing the evolution of the nominal wages agreed for 2009, it is observed that the sectoral collective agreements signed between October 2007 and August 2008 established very similar nominal wage increases to those recorded in the previous expansion period, while the agreements signed after 15 September 2008 established lower wage increases, the difference between these two magnitudes being statistically significant (see Chart 1). This observation suggests that wage adjustment in that recession, once it commenced, was particularly rapid, but limited to newly signed agreements. Frequency of collective bargaining and employment losses In summary, as seen in the previous section, the overlapping of numerous collective agreements meant that at the start of the recession similar firms had to pay very different wage increases. One would expect those firms that had to pay higher wage increases to have suffered larger employment losses than similar firms whose sectoral agreement, having been signed later, established lower wage increases. 10 See Olivei and Tenreyro (2007) and Card (1990). 11 For example, Hudomiet et al. (2011) collected data on subjective expectations regarding the evolution of the stock market, documenting an abrupt change in the fourth quarter of 2008, around the time of the Lehman Brothers failure. BANCO DE ESPAÑA 3 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, APRIL 2015 COLLECTIVE BARGAINING, WAGE RIGIDITIES AND EMPLOYMENT: AN ANALYSIS USING MICROECONOMIC DATA

NOMINAL WAGE GROWTH AGREED FOR 2009, ACCORDING TO THE QUARTER IN WHICH AGREEMENT SIGNED (a) CHART 1 100 50 0-50 -100-150 -200-250 -4-3 -2-1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 WAGE GROWTH UPPER 95% BAND LOWER 95% BAND SOURCE: Banco de España, using the Register of Collective Agreements. a Predicted value, in basis points, of a regression of wage growth on the quarter in which agreement signed, adjusted by industry, province, multi-year agreement and indexation clause indicators. The values are the deviation with respect to 2.5%, the average growth agreed for 2009 in agreements signed between October and December 2007. To verify this hypothesis the probability of being unemployed between 2009 and 2010 is compared for workers employed in industries whose agreement for 2009 was signed during the upturn with that of workers whose collective agreement was signed during the recession (again using the failure of Lehman Brothers on 15 September 2008 to mark the cyclical turning point) (see left-hand panel of Chart 2). 12,13 Between January 2009 and December 2010 the probability of being unemployed was 1 pp higher for workers whose collective agreement for 2009 and 2010 was signed during the expansion than for other workers, the difference being even more marked in the case of workers with temporary contracts. Since collective agreements set minimum wages by sector of activity, province of residence and professional group, one would also expect wage increases and employment losses to have been especially large for workers whose wages were close to the wage rate set in an agreement. In this respect, workers whose wage in 2007 was up to 10% higher than the agreement minimum and whose collective agreement was signed before the failure of Lehman Brothers received a 1 pp higher wage increase than other workers (see Table 2). By contrast, the date of the collective agreement does not affect the wage growth of workers with a wage that exceeded the rate set in the collective agreement by at least 20%. As the right-hand panel of Chart 2 shows, the employment losses were especially large among workers whose wage was close to that set in the relevant collective agreement. Thus, among workers subject to a collective agreement signed during the expansion, those whose wage was closest to the minimum level set in the agreement spent 3% more days unemployed than other workers. To estimate the magnitude of these effects, a comparison may be made with the loss of employment that would have been observed if the agreements signed before the collapse of Lehman Brothers had been renegotiated with the same wage increases as were established in agreements signed after that date. The result of this exercise suggests that, had the agreements been renegotiated, the unemployment rate of workers whose wage before the recession was no more than 20 pp higher than the agreement minimum wage would have been 50% lower between 2009 and 2010. By contrast, given that the sectoral bargaining only sets minimum earnings, the renegotiation would not have had any effect on the levels of employment of workers whose wage was more than 1.4 times the provincial agreement rate. 12 The wage change set may reflect changes in agents perceptions of inflation or expe cted unemployment. 13 For further details, see Díez-Catalán and Villanueva (2014). BANCO DE ESPAÑA 4 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, APRIL 2015 COLLECTIVE BARGAINING, WAGE RIGIDITIES AND EMPLOYMENT: AN ANALYSIS USING MICROECONOMIC DATA

RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE PROBABILITY OF BEING UNEMPLOYED IN 2009 AND 2010 AND THE DATE ON WHICH THE COLLECTIVE AGREEMENT FOR 2009 IS SIGNED CHART 2 PROBABILITY OF BEING UNEMPLOYED, IF COLLECTIVE AGREEMENT SIGNED BEFORE 15 SEPTEMBER 2008 (a) MONTHLY PROBABILITY OF BEING UNEMPLOYED, FOR WAGES CLOSE TO AGREEMENT (b) 0.025 0.020 0.015 0.010 0.005 0.000-0.005 Apr-09 Jul-09 Oct-09 Jan-10 Apr-10 Jul-10 Oct-10 0.08 0.07 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.00-0.01-0.02 Jan-09 Apr-09 Jul-09 Oct-09 Jan-10 Apr-10 Jul-10 Oct-10 TEMPORARY PERMANENT UNEMPLOYMENT UPPER 95% BANKD LOWER 95% BAND SOURCE: Banco de España, using the Register of Collective Agreements and the Continuous Sample of Working Histories. a This panel presents the increase in the monthly probability of being unemployed associated with a collective agreement signed before 15 September 2008 estimated by means of linear regressions of the probability of being unemployed on the date on which the agreement is signed, industry and province indicators. b This panel presents the increase in the monthly probability of being unemployed associated with a collective agreement signed before 15 September 2008 for the sample of workers who in December 2007 received a wage that exceeded the agreement minimum for the sector by no more than 20%. The model includes collective agreement indicators. In short, the fact that employment losses and labour cost increases are concentrated among workers with wages close to an agreement rate established during the expansion suggests that at the start of the recession the wage rigidity associated with collective agreements acted as an aggregate shock transmission mechanism. Final comments The low degree of wage adjustment in Spain during the initial years of the recession has been singled out as a factor that may have contributed to the heavy job destruction that took place between 2009 and 2010. The evidence presented in this article, based on disaggregated information combining data on agreements, wages and the employment situation of workers, shows that there were particularly heavy employment losses among workers subject to collective agreements signed in the expansion phase, which set relatively high wage increases. Specifically, at the start of the 1993 and 2008 recessions wage conditions varied considerably owing to the existence of multi-year collective agreements signed during the upturn, which established large wage increases for a significant proportion of workers. By contrast, other groups of workers, subject to collective agreements signed in the recession, received wage increases more in line with the change in macroeconomic conditions. Also a higher probability of loss of employment is detected among workers subject to agreements signed during upturns, an effect that is exclusively due to those whose wages were closest to the minimum set in the agreement. The estimates presented suggest that for this group of workers a renegotiation of the provincial agreement would have reduced the probability of being unemployed by up to 50%. Since 2010, various labour reforms have been implemented to make the regulation of collective bargaining in Spain more flexible. Among other measures, mechanisms have been introduced that make it easier for firms to cease to apply higher-level collective agreements. Until more data (preferably microeconomic data like those used here) are available on collective bargaining developments since the application of these reforms, a comprehensive and rigorous evaluation of their effects is impossible. That said, the evidence presented in this article suggests that, given the orientation of the reforms, BANCO DE ESPAÑA 5 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, APRIL 2015 COLLECTIVE BARGAINING, WAGE RIGIDITIES AND EMPLOYMENT: AN ANALYSIS USING MICROECONOMIC DATA

WAGE GROWTH AND JOB DESTRUCTION IN 2009, BY DATE COLLECTIVE AGREEMENT SIGNED TABLE 2 1 Agreement signed before 15..2008 and age 0-10% above agreement minimum Wage gro th observed (a) Proportion of da s unemplo ed (b) (1) (2) 0.0102 (0.0042) 0.034 (0.010) 2 Agreement signed before 15..2008 and age 10-20% above minimum 3 Agreement signed before 15..2008 and age 20-40% above minimum 0.005 (0.0041) 0.002 (0.003) 0.024 (0.010) 0.010 ( ) SOURCE: Banco de España, based on the Register of Collective Agreements 2008-2010 and the Continuous Sample of Working Histories. a and Villanueva (2014)]. b adjustment to unexpected reductions in the demand for labour can be expected to take place in future more through wage changes than through heavy employment losses. 14.4.2015. REFERENCES BENTOLILA, S., M. IZQUIERDO and J. F. JIMENO (2010). Negociación colectiva: La gran reforma pendiente, Papeles de Economía Española, 124. CARD, D. (1990). Unexpected inflation, real wages and employment determination in union contracts, American Economic Review, 80:4, pp. 669-688. CARDOSO, A. R., and P. PORTUGAL (2005). Contractual wages and the wage cushion under different bargaining settings, Journal of Labor Economics, 23:4, pp. 875-902. CARNEIRO, A., P. GUIMARAES and P. PORTUGAL (2012). Real wages and the business cycle: accounting for worker, firm and job title heterogeneity, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, vol. 4, No. 2, pp. 133-152. DE LA ROCA, J. (2014). Real wages and business cycles: Evidence from Spain using Social Security data, SERIES, Special Issue on the Crisis in Spain. DEVICIENTI, F., A. MAIDA and P. SESTITO (2007). Downward wage rigidity in Italy: Micro-based measures and implications, The Economic Journal, vol. 117 (524), pp. 530-552. DICKENS, W., E. GROSHEN, J. MESSINA, J. TURUNEN, L. GOETTE, S. HOLDEN, M. SCHWEITZER and M. WARD (2007). How wages change: evidence from the International Wage Flexibility Project, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21 (2), pp. 195-214. DÍEZ-CATALÁN, L., and E. VILLANUEVA (2014). Contract staggering and unemployment during the Great Recession: Evidence from Spain, Working Papers, No. 1431, Banco de España. GUIMARAES, P., F. MARTINS and P. PORTUGAL (2014). Upward nominal wage rigidity, manuscript, Banco de Portugal. HAEFKE, CH., M. SONNTAG and T. VAN RENS (2013). Wage Rigidity and Job Creation, Journal of Monetary Economics, 60, pp. 887-899. HUDOMIET, P., G. KÉZDI and R. WILLIS (2011). Stock market crash and the expectations of American Households, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 26 (3), pp. 393-415. MARTINS, P. (2014). 30,000 Minimum Wages: The Economic Impact of the Extensions of Collective Agreements, Working Paper No. 51, University of London, School of Business and Management, Centre for Globalisation Research. MESSINA, J., P. DU CAJU, C. DUARTE, N. HANSEN and M. IZQUIERDO (2010). The Incidence of real and nominal wage rigidity: an individual based sectoral approach, Journal of the European Economic Association, vol. 8 (2-3), April/May. MURTIN, F., A. DE SERRES and A. HIJZEN (2014). Unemployment and the coverage extension of collective wage agreements, European Economic Review, 71:C, pp. 52-66. OLIVEI, G., and S. TENREYRO (2007). The timing of monetary policy shocks, American Economic Review, June, vol. 97 (3), pp. 636-663. ROSOLIA, A. (2015). On the response of Italian wages to the unemployment rate, manuscript, Banca d Italia. BANCO DE ESPAÑA 6 ECONOMIC BULLETIN, APRIL 2015 COLLECTIVE BARGAINING, WAGE RIGIDITIES AND EMPLOYMENT: AN ANALYSIS USING MICROECONOMIC DATA