Julio Videras Department of Economics Hamilton College

Similar documents
The federal estate tax allows a deduction for every dollar

Green Giving and Demand for Environmental Quality: Evidence from the Giving and Volunteering Surveys. Debra K. Israel* Indiana State University

Equality and Fertility: Evidence from China

The Impact of Taxation on Charitable Giving

Charitable Bequest Giving in the USA 1. Patrick Rooney*, Amir D. Hayat**, Michal Kramarek***, Xiaoyun Wang****

THE DESIGN OF THE INDIVIDUAL ALTERNATIVE

Monetary Policy Implications of Electronic Currency: An Empirical Analysis. Christopher Fogelstrom. Ann L. Owen* Hamilton College.

THE EFFECT OF THE CAPITAL GAINS TAX ON DONATIONS OF CASH AND APPRECIATED ASSETS

Federal Tax Policy and Charitable Giving: Revisiting the 1985 Study by Charles T. Clotfelter

The impact of charitable subsidies on religious giving and attendance: Evidence from panel data

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

The Impact of State and Local Government Spending on Charitable Giving in the United States. Lynn Vandendriessche

Jamie Wagner Ph.D. Student University of Nebraska Lincoln

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAX EVASION AND CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION. James M. Poterba. Working Paper No. 2119

Financial Risk Tolerance and the influence of Socio-demographic Characteristics of Retail Investors

Macroeconomic Experiences and Risk-Taking of Euro Area Households

Happiness across the life span:

Lifetime Wealth Taxation of the Very Rich

Appendix A. Additional Results

Unemployment and Happiness

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE

The Relative Income Hypothesis: A comparison of methods.

Bequests and Retirement Wealth in the United States

Religion and Volunteerism

Wealth Distribution and Bequests

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Beliefs in Technology and Support for Environmental Taxes: An Empirical Investigation

CHARITABLE CONTRIBUTIONS TO INTERNATIONAL RELIEF AND DEVELOPMENT

Church Contributions and Church Attendance

An assessment of Canadian Tax Policy for Charitable Giving: Addressing Methodological Challenges

While real incomes in the lower and middle portions of the U.S. income distribution have

How responsive are charitable donors to requests to give?

INTRODUCTION: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF TAX EXPENDITURES

Capital Gains Realizations of the Rich and Sophisticated

Strictness of Tax Compliance Norms: A Factorial Survey on the Acceptance of Inheritance Tax Evasion in Germany

Investigating the U-Shaped Charitable Giving Profile Using Register-Based Data

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

The Influence of Reference Group Contributions on a Family s Charitable Giving. Keegan Skeate

Intervivos Transfers and Bequests in three OECD Countries 1.

Strategic Timing of Charitable Giving

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CHARITABLE BEQUESTS AND TAXES ON INHERITANCES AND ESTATES: AGGREGATE EVIDENCE FROM ACROSS STATES AND TIME

Precautionary Saving and Health Insurance: A Portfolio Choice Perspective

Does Capitalism Flow to Poor Countries?

An Analysis of Charitable Giving to the Eugene Water and Electric Board s Customer Care Program

Social Security and Saving: A Comment

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings

A STUDY OF INVESTMENT AWARENESS AND PREFERENCE OF WORKING WOMEN IN JAFFNA DISTRICT IN SRI LANKA

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

Wage Gap Estimation with Proxies and Nonresponse

INVESTORS PERCEPTION TOWARDS MUTUAL FUND: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY WITH REFERENCE TO COIMBATORE CITY

Changes in Economic Mobility

Public-private sector pay differential in UK: A recent update

TAX EXPENDITURES Fall 2012

The Theory of Taxation and Public Economics

The Relationship between Charitable Giving. and Inequality Aversion

Econ 2230: Public Economics. Lecture 21: Subsidizing giving

How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK

Intergenerational Conflict over Fiscal Consolidation: Theory and Evidence from Japan

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

Data Appendix. A.1. The 2007 survey

How Changes in Tax Rates Might Affect Itemized Charitable Deductions. The Center on Philanthropy at Indiana University March 2009

The Social Costs of Unemployment: Accounting for Unemployment Duration

1) The Effect of Recent Tax Changes on Taxable Income

DATA CHOICE IN CAPITAL GAINS REALISATION RESPONSE STUDIES - A REVIEW JOHN MINAS*

What Makes Family Members Live Apart or Together?: An Empirical Study with Japanese Panel Study of Consumers

Access to Retirement Savings and its Effects on Labor Supply Decisions

Effects of Estate Tax Reform on Charitable Giving

Summary The Administration s 2010 and 2011 budget outlines contain a proposal to cap the value of itemized deductions at 28%, for high-income taxpayer

Tax Reform and Charitable Giving

Incentives and political contributions*

The Economic Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

ASSESSING FINANCIAL RISK TOLERANCE: DO DEMOGRAPHIC, SOCIOECONOMIC AND ATTITUDINAL FACTORS WORK?

Capital Gains Tax Options: Behavioral Responses and Revenues

Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner

How Does the Incentive Effect of the Charitable Deduction Vary Across Charities?

Government Consumption Spending Inhibits Economic Growth in the OECD Countries

Retirement Plan Coverage of Baby Boomers: Analysis of 1998 SIPP Data. Satyendra K. Verma

Inequality and Redistribution

Spending Someone Else s Money: The Impact Of Inheritances On Charitable Giving

Online Appendix for The Importance of Being. Marginal: Gender Differences in Generosity

IN JULY OF 2009, THE HOUSE DEMOCRATS PROPOSED A

HOW DOES CHARITABLE GIVING RESPOND TO INCENTIVES AND INCOME? NEW ESTIMATES FROM PANEL DATA. Jon Bakija and Bradley T. Heim

Liquidity Constraints and Entrepreneurship. Household Wealth, Parental Wealth, and the Transition In and Out of Entrepreneurship 1

Giving and Volunteering in British Columbia

ESTIMATING THE RISK PREMIUM OF LAW ENFORCEMENT OFFICERS. Brandon Payne East Carolina University Department of Economics Thesis Paper November 27, 2002

Changes in Stock Ownership by Race/Hispanic Status,

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

TRICKLE-DOWN CONSUMPTION. Marianne Bertrand (Chicago Booth) Adair Morse (Berkeley)

Wealth Transfer Estimates: 2001 to 2055 St. Louis Metropolitan Area

What is Driving The Labour Force Participation Rates for Indigenous Australians? The Importance of Transportation.

Health Status and Portfolio Choice by Harvey S. Rosen, Princeton University Stephen Wu, Hamilton College. CEPS Working Paper No. 75.

The Truth on Spending: How the Federal and State Governments Measure Up Heather Winnor, Elon College

ECONOMETRIC ISSUES IN ESTIMATING THE BEHAVIORAL RESPONSE TO TAXATION: A NONTECHNICAL INTRODUCTION ROBERT K. TRIEST *

The impact of a longer working life on health: exploiting the increase in the UK state pension age for women

Are Americans Saving Optimally for Retirement?

Poverty and Income Distribution

The Impact of College Financial Aid Rules on Household Portfolio Choice

The Value of Social Security Disability Insurance

A STUDY ON FACTORS INFLUENCING OF WOMEN POLICYHOLDER S INVESTMENT DECISION TOWARDS LIFE INSURANCE CORPORATION OF INDIA POLICIES IN CHENNAI

Transcription:

LUCK AND GIVING Julio Videras Department of Economics Hamilton College Abstract: This paper finds that individuals who consider themselves lucky in finances donate more than individuals who do not consider themselves lucky even after controlling for income, wealth, and relevant socio-demographic variables.

1 Introduction Economic policies that foster individual decision-making regarding savings and retirement, policies such as 401(k) plans and partial privatization of Social Security, increase wealth differences among those who make goods decisions and those who make bad decisions as well as among those who had good luck and those who have bad luck (Surowiecki, 2004). In a society characterized by increasing risks, how does financial luck affect individuals willingness to redistribute wealth through donations? Recent work by Alesina, Di Tella, and MacCulloch (2004) shows that, in the US, the rich are more averse to inequality than the poor are. Alesina, Di Tella, and MacCulloch argue that perceptions about social mobility make the rich fear their status might be precarious and they might fall behind. Thus, people who have had luck in finances and believe their wealth can be partly attributed to good fortune might fear experiencing bad luck in the future and might be more likely to donate to charitable organizations to redistribute income. Similarly, individuals who have experienced financial luck may be more willing to redistribute wealth if they realize the status of less well-off people can be partly due to bad luck rather than to laziness only. This paper seeks evidence of the importance of financial luck in giving. Using micro-data from the 2001 U.S. Survey of Consumer Finances 1 (SCF), a Tobit model is estimated. The results suggest that financial luck increases charitable giving even after controlling for income, wealth, and relevant socio-demographic variables. Although the literature on charitable giving is extensive, the importance of financial luck has not yet been examined. Many papers have analyzed the influence of the tax code and disposable income, for example, Boskin and Feldstein (1977) and Clotfelter (1980, 1985). Auten and Joulfaian (1996) examine intergenerational effects and show that the parents of wealthier children contribute more to charities. Andreoni and Scholz (1998) find some evidence that interdependence of preferences matter within sociodemographic groups. Andreoni, Brown, and Rischall (2003) find that men and women have different preferences towards giving. Consistent with the warm-glow argument 1 The Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) is sponsored by the Federal Reserve Board and the U.S. Department of the Treasury samples. The survey samples a cross-section of U.S. residents to study the financial decisions of households and over-samples wealthy individuals. 2

discussed by Becker (1974) and Andreoni (1990), MacGranahan (2000) shows that religious beliefs and social esteem also influence giving. The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 discusses the data and empirical model. Section 3 presents results and Section 4 concludes. 2 Data and the empirical model This study uses micro-data from the 2001 U.S. Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF). It is common practice in empirical analyses of giving to limit the sample to households with income above some lower limit (Clotfelter 1985, Andreoni and Scholz, 1998). This study excludes observations with income under $10,000, leaving a sample of 3,669 households. 2 The dependent variable is the log of donations (excluding political organizations). The independent variables include the logs of price of donations (PRICE), income (INCOME), debt (DEBT), and assets or wealth (WEALTH). The price of contributions is calculated as 1 minus the relevant tax rate for households that itemize and 1 minus half the tax rate for non-itemizers (Andreoni and Scholz, 1998). The 2000 rate schedules are used to impute tax rates for couples and singles based on total income. Although tax rates should be based on taxable income, the SCF does not include enough information on deduction and exemptions to calculate taxable income. As a result the control for price is likely to be a poor measure of the true price of donations. To control for socio-demographic characteristics of the respondents, a dummy variable equals one if the respondent is married (MARRIED) and a dummy is equal to one if the respondent is employed in the manufacturing sector (MANUFACTURING). The age of the respondent and quadratic and cubic terms for age are also included (AGE). Although the SCF does not ask respondents whether they believe they deserve their good luck in finances or not, saving habits and level of education can control for individuals skills and conscious efforts to accumulate assets. Thus, the variable COLLEGE equals one if the respondent has college education and the variable SAVE equals one if the respondent says the household saves every month. Regarding the respondents perception of financial luck, the SCF asks respondents whether they consider themselves lucky in finances relative to other people 2 The results are robust to using other reasonable lower limits. 3

of their generation in a 1-5 scale. Comparisons of mean net worth by level of luck reveal that net worth of households that strongly agree to the statement that they are lucky is on average almost $12,000,000 more than the net worth of other households. Mean comparisons also show that difference in net worth among individuals who Somewhat agree, Neither agree nor disagree, Somewhat disagree, or Strongly disagree are statistically insignificant. Thus, rather than using the scale variable, LUCK takes on the value of 1 for households who strongly agree and 0 otherwise. Table 1 presents summary statistics for the dependent and independent variables. SCF respondents are on average wealthy although there is considerable variability in wealth. Average donations are $57,141.8 with almost 58 percent of the respondents donating to charities. Forty-two percent of the respondents strongly agree they have been lucky in finances. Although the proportion of lucky individuals increases in the top percentiles of the total income distribution, the proportion is never above 84 percent and actually falls to 78 percent for those in the 99-percentile (those whose total income is $12,300,000 or more). Almost 90 percent of the individuals in the sample save regularly and more than half have college education. Average sample age is 48 years. The dependent variable is censored. SCF asks how much a household contributed during 2000 if contributions of money or property were equal to or above $500. Therefore, contributions of less than $500 are coded as zeros. Since Ordinary Least Square (OLS) regression is in general inconsistent when the dependent variable is censored, a standard Tobit models is estimated. 3 Results Table 2 presents results for the Tobit model. 3 Financial luck has an economically and statistically significant positive effect on giving. The coefficient indicates that financial luck increases mean log donations by almost.44, an increase of about 9 percent in the mean of log donations. The coefficient is statistically significant with a p-value equal to.017. The finding is consistent with the hypothesis that, after controlling for income and 3 The results are robust to dropping the very wealthy in the sample, those in the 90-percentile of the total income distribution. The only noteworthy difference when the very wealthy are excluded from the sample is the coefficient of logprice is statistically insignificant. 4

wealth, people who have been lucky in financial matters may feel compelled to give to charities more than individuals who have not been particularly lucky. Regarding the effect of saving regularly, the results indicate that saving increases mean log donations by.7, an increase of 14 percent in the mean of log donations. This positive effect on donations after controlling for income and wealth may be due to the fact that individuals for whom saving is a virtue may also think of contributing to charities as a virtue. Everything else equal, college-educated and married individuals donate more while respondents who are employed in the manufacturing sector donate less. Although the partial effect of age on donations is positive for all individuals in the sample the relationship is non-linear and reaches a minimum at approximately 89 years. The estimated elasticity of donations with respect to wealth is 1.11. Thus, a 10 percent increase in accumulated income, wealth, in an 11.1 percent increase in giving. The coefficient is statistically significant (p-value below.001). Income elasticity falls in the range of previous studies (.24 to 1.31, Andreoni and Scholz [1998]) and is strongly significant. Everything else equal, the estimate indicates that a 10 percent increase in income results in a 5.3 percent increase in giving. The estimate of price elasticity falls outside the range of estimates of previous studies (-.42 to -1.34, Andreoni and Scholz [1998]). This is probably due to the fact that tax rates (and hence price of donations) are not based on taxable income but, for lack of data, on total income. 4 Summary This paper uses micro-data from the 2001 US Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) to examine the relationship between financial luck and charitable giving. Financial luck is found to increase donations after controlling for relevant socio-demographic variables, income, and wealth. To the extent that experiencing luck in finances is an economically and statistically significant determinant of donations, economic policies that increase the risk borne by individuals by, for example, shifting savings from Social Security to the stock market can have significant effects on the future of charitable organizations and the redistribution of wealth. 5

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics (N = 3,669). Mean Standard Deviation [Mean Log, St. dv.] DONATIONS ($) 57,141.83 482,724.4 [4.99, 4.52] LUCK ( = 1if strongly agree.42.49 lucky in finances) PRICE ($).80.09 [.59,.05] INCOME ($) 697,799.1 3,618,536 [11.55, 1.58] WEALTH ($) 274,386.3 1,828,481 [9.00, 3.03] DEBT ($) 231,994.2 1,532,614 [8.48, 4.82] AGE 48.23 14.53 MARRIED.66.48 SAVE ( = 1 if save every month).86.34 COLLEGE ( = 1 if college.52.50 education) MANUFACTURING ( = 1 if employed in manufacturing sector).14.35 6

Table 2: Regression Results from Tobit Model, Dependent Variable is LogDONATION Coefficient Standard Error LUCK.439 b.184 LogPRICE -3.753 b 1.810 LogINCOME.486 a.095 LogWEALTH 1.111 a.070 LogDEBT.009.018 COLLEGE 1.811 a.185 SAVE.700 a.272 AGE.479 a.148 AGE 2 -.0076 a.003 AGE 3.00004 b.00002 MARRIED.811 a.197 MANUFACTURING -.753 a.240 Constant -26.893 a 2.864 Statistic (p-value) χ 2 = 2675.03 (<.0001) Pseudo R 2.156 Observations 3669 a Significant at the 1 percent level. b Significant at the 5 percent level. c Significant at the 10 percent level. 7

References Alesina, Alberto; Di Tella, Rafael; and MacCulloch, Robert (2004): Inequality and happiness: are Europeans and Americans different? Journal of Public Economics, 88: 2009-2042. Andreoni, James (1990): Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving, The Economic Journal, 100: 464-477. Andreoni, James; Brown, Eleanor, and Isaac Rischall (2003): Charitable giving by married couples: Who decides and why does it matter? Journal of Human Resources, 38(1): 111-133. Andreoni, James, and John Karl Scholz (1998): An econometric analysis of charitable giving with interdependent preferences, Economic Inquiry, 36(3): 410-428. Auten, Gerald, and David Joulfaian (1996): Charitable contributions and intergenerational transfers, Journal of Public Economics, 59(1): 55-68. Becker, Gary S. (1974): A theory of social interactions, Journal of Political Economy, 82: 1063-1093. Boskin, Michael, and Martin Feldstein (1977): Effects of the charitable deduction on contributions by low income and middle income households: evidence from the National Survey of Philanthropy, Review of Economics and Statistics, 59: 351-354. Clotfelter, Charles T. (1980): Tax incentives and charitable giving: Evidence from a panel of taxpayers, Journal of Public Economics, 13: 319-340. Clotfelter, Charles T. (1985): Federal Tax Policy and Charitable Giving. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. McGranahan, Leslie Moscow (2000): Charity and the bequest motive: Evidence from Seventeenth-Century Wills, Journal of Political Economy, 108(6): 1270-1291. Surowiecki, James (2004): The risk society, The New Yorker, November 15, 2005, page 40. 8