The Lévy Libor model with default risk

Similar documents
Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

RATING BASED LÉVY LIBOR MODEL

A new approach to LIBOR modeling

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

A note on survival measures and the pricing of options on credit default swaps

No arbitrage conditions in HJM multiple curve term structure models

DYNAMIC CDO TERM STRUCTURE MODELLING

L 2 -theoretical study of the relation between the LIBOR market model and the HJM model Takashi Yasuoka

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default

Credit Risk. MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management. John Dodson. February 7, Credit Risk. John Dodson. Introduction.

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

A Hybrid Commodity and Interest Rate Market Model

Interest rate models in continuous time

1.1 Implied probability of default and credit yield curves

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Hedging of swaptions in a Lévy driven Heath-Jarrow-Morton framework

Hedging under Arbitrage

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Things You Have To Have Heard About (In Double-Quick Time) The LIBOR market model: Björk 27. Swaption pricing too.

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

Market interest-rate models

Risk Neutral Measures

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Contagion models with interacting default intensity processes

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Term Structure of Credit Spreads of A Firm When Its Underlying Assets are Discontinuous

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

The Black Model and the Pricing of Options on Assets, Futures and Interest Rates. Richard Stapleton, Guenter Franke

CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES

Hedging Basket Credit Derivatives with CDS

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Libor Market Model Version 1.0

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

O N MODEL UNCERTAINTY IN

The value of foresight

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

The Black-Scholes Model

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Pricing Default Events: Surprise, Exogeneity and Contagion

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Valuing volatility and variance swaps for a non-gaussian Ornstein-Uhlenbeck stochastic volatility model

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

The stochastic calculus

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

D MATH Departement of Mathematics Finite dimensional realizations for the CNKK-volatility surface model

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

LOGNORMAL MIXTURE SMILE CONSISTENT OPTION PRICING

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

Introduction Credit risk

Modeling Credit Risk with Partial Information

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

Financial Engineering. Craig Pirrong Spring, 2006

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Transcription:

The Lévy Libor model with default risk Ernst Eberlein, Wolfgang Kluge 2 and Philipp J. Schönbucher 3 Abstract In this paper we present a model for the dynamic evolution of the term structure of default-free and defaultable interest rates. The model is set in the Libor market model framework but in contrast to the classical diffusion-driven setup, its dynamics are driven by a time-inhomogeneous Lévy process which allows us to better capture the real-world dynamics of credit spreads. We present necessary and sufficient conditions for absence of arbitrage in the dynamics of the spreads, and provide pricing formulae for defaultable bonds, credit default swaps and options on credit default swaps in this setup. Introduction The market for credit-related financial instruments and credit derivatives has grown significantly in recent years. In particular, for a large number of reference obligors there exist liquid markets for credit default swaps CDS of different maturities which allow the construction of a term structure of credit spreads. In this paper we present a framework for the modelling of the dynamic evolution of such a full term structure of credit spreads, jointly with the dynamics of a full term structure of forward interest rates. The framework is inspired by the famous Libor market models by Miltersen, Sandmann and Sondermann 997, Brace, Gatarek, and Musiela 997, and Jamshidian 997 for the default-free case and in particular by its defaultable extension presented in Schönbucher 999. For various reasons we believe that an accurate representation of the term structure of credit spreads and their dynamics will become increasingly more important for credit risk models in the near future. First, the market for credit default swaps is moving in this direction: Besides the 5-year point which is still the most liquid reference maturity, for many reference entities there is liquid trading on the standard maturities of,3,5,7 and years, and many brokers also quote CDS spreads for all maturities between and years. Secondly, this increase in liquidity is driven by University of Freiburg, Department of Mathematical Stochastics, Eckerstr., D-794 Freiburg, Germany. Email: eberlein@stochastik.uni-freiburg.de. 2 University of Freiburg, Department of Mathematical Stochastics, Eckerstr., D-794 Freiburg, Germany. Email: kluge@stochastik.uni-freiburg.de. Wolfgang Kluge gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft DFG grant Eb66/9-2. 3 ETH Zurich, D-MATH, Rämistr., CH-892 Zurich, Switzerland. p@schonbucher.de, www.schonbucher.de. Philipp Schönbucher gratefully acknowledges financial support by the National Centre of Competence in Research Financial Valuation and Risk Management NCCR FINRISK, Project 5: Credit Risk. The NCCR FINRISK is a research program supported by the Swiss National Science Foundation.

the fact that the credit risk of a reference entity may indeed vary significantly when viewed over different time horizons, also under objective probabilities: There exists a variety of typical shapes for the term structure of credit spreads for obligors of different risk classes e.g. upward-sloping spreads for high quality credits and downward sloping ones for low credit quality. Additional variations in the shape of the term structure of credit risk may also be caused by obligor-specific circumstances e.g. the maturity of a large fraction of outstanding debt around a particular date. Furthermore, the information about the term structure of credit risk of an obligor is also of importance for the pricing of certain credit-related instruments, for example credit commitments, lines of credit or options on credit protection. And finally, a new class of credit derivatives has recently gained popularity, the so-called constant-maturity credit default swaps which are directly related to the shape of the term structure of credit spreads. Similar points can be made for the ability to capture joint dynamics of interest rates and credit spreads, in particular given the increasing liquidity of CDS markets and the emergence of interest rate/credit hybrid derivatives. While the default mechanism of the model presented in this paper is still an intensity-based model, it allows a direct specification of a full initial term structure of interest rates and credit spreads and of their dynamics, based upon CDS quotes and the pricing formulae given in section 6. This has obvious advantages in terms of calibration and specification of the model, as in purely intensity-based models, the calibration is usually much more involved. This advantage becomes even more compelling in a Lévy-driven framework. The main contribution of this paper is the combination of the Libor market model based discrete-tenor setup with dynamics of the default-free and defaultable term structures that are driven by a much more general stochastic process than the standard Brownian motion which is used in Schönbucher 999 and almost all other models of spread-dynamics: a process with independent increments and absolutely continuous characteristics PIIAC, also known as a time-inhomogeneous Lévy process. As in the case of default-free interest rates, the main advantage of a discrete-tenor setup is a major increase in flexibility in terms of the specification of the volatility functions; in particular, a specification of lognormal dynamics is possible without endangering the existence of solutions of the stochastic differential equations governing the evolution of the term structure of interest rates. This advantage translates directly into the credit risk domain and distinguishes our approach from Schönbucher 998, Bielecki and Rutkowski 2, and Eberlein and Özkan 23. Diffusion-based models may be roughly adequate for models of default-free interest rates, although even in this case there is much evidence in favor of using Lévy processes. Yet in the credit risk area the arguments for models with jumps are even stronger: First, empirical evidence suggests that credit spreads and by extension default hazard rates have features which may be better captured by a process which exhibits jumps in its paths. For example the volatility of spreads is very high Schönbucher 24 finds values between 5 and 8% p.a., and the dependence of volatilities on the level of spreads seems to be very high, too Schönbucher 24 finds an volatility exponent of around.5. Both phenomena can be explained well by introducing jumps in spreads, rather than bending a diffusion-based model to the data. Furthermore, there are good fundamental reasons for including jumps in the dy- 2

namics of credit spreads: Credit risk-related information often arrives in big lumps, e.g. rating adjustments, statements on the financial health of the firm, or surprising credit events in related firms may all cause large, discontinuous changes in the probabilities of survival of the affected obligors. Finally, there is evidence e.g. Mortensen 25 that it is not possible to build a multivariate intensity model with realistic levels of default dependence unless one introduces jumps in the intensity processes of the obligors: Purely diffusion-driven intensity models usually do not exhibit levels of dependence that are high enough to reproduce current market prices of portfolio credit derivatives. All these reasons lead us to believe that the introduction of a time-inhomogeneous Lévy process as driving process is a significant step towards making the dynamics of the model more realistic. The class of time-inhomogeneous Lévy processes is a very rich class of processes with a wide variety of possible patterns of behavior, including amongst others Brownian motions, Poisson jump processes with very general jump size distributions, classical Lévy processes with infinite activity, e.g. generalized hyperbolic Lévy processes, and linear combinations of these. Most of the key results of this paper do not even depend on the defining properties of a PIIAC, the proofs given are directly transferable to a model driven by a general semimartingale subject to certain regularity conditions. However, with a view towards implementation, we stick to the class of time-inhomogeneous Lévy processes. In credit risk modelling, Lévy processes have so far found successful applications mostly in the area of firm s value based models. Cariboni and Schoutens 24, and Hilberink and Rogers 22 consider single-name firm s value based models and by introducing Lévy processes are able to solve the short-term spread problem that diffusion-based firm s value models usually suffer from. By construction, the dynamics of the term structure of credit spreads in these models exhibits Lévy jumps. The approach taken in our paper is very different from these papers as we do not try to explain the reason of the default using the firm s value but only want to describe the term structure of default risk and its evolution. This gives us more flexibility in the specification of the term structure of default risk and its dynamics but at the cost of losing the intuitive appeal and the link to equity prices that firm s value models have. Furthermore, we would like to mention Joshi and Stacey 25 who present an interesting way to use the Gamma process in intensity-based portfolio default risk modelling, leading to a multivariate intensity model with joint default events. By now, the literature on the default-free Libor market models has grown too large to be surveyed here. Besides the original papers mentioned above, we therefore only refer to Eberlein and Özkan 25 who first introduced a Libor market model driven by a Lévy process. The literature on the defaultable version of the Libor market model has also grown. Brigo 24 presents a defaultable version of the Libor market model which is based upon a slightly different representation of the term structure of defaultable assets using forward CDS contracts. This model has the advantage of allowing for cleaner pricing of CDS, but the disadvantage that the prices of defaultable zero coupon bonds are not obtainable in closed-form any more. Schönbucher 24 presents and extends the survival-measure pricing technique introduced in Schönbucher 999 and discusses its application to the pricing of options on CDS, and also presents empirical results on the dynamics of CDS spreads. Jumps in the dynamics of default intensities are usually modelled using exponentially affine 3

models, the idea goes back to Duffie and Garleanu 2 and was used frequently afterwards. Yet these models are models of the spot intensity, so they do not attempt to model a full term structure of defaultable bond prices as we do here. Furthermore, in our specification we allow for much more general jump processes than the class of affine processes. The rest of the paper is structured as follows: We begin with a brief introduction of the variables defining the defaultable and default-free term structures of interest rates and a short description of the driving time-inhomogeneous Lévy process. Then, in section 2, the main assumptions regarding the dynamics of forward Libor rates and default-risk factors are presented. In particular, we quickly recall the setup and results of the default-free Lévy Libor model according to Eberlein and Özkan 25 and then state the setup of the dynamic model for a candidate system of discrete default hazard rates Ĥ, T k. In the next step, we must ensure that the dynamics of the modelled discrete default hazard rates Ĥ, T k coincide with the evolution of the actual H, T k derived from the real probabilities of default. In section 3 we show by construction the existence of a default arrival process which is consistent with these dynamics, provided that the discrete default hazard rates satisfy a martingale/drift restriction under the corresponding forward measures. By explicitly constructing a default time via an extension of the probability space we are furthermore able to cleanly identify a background -filtration which includes no information about default itself but which will yield the full market-filtration when it is combined with the filtration generated by the default arrival process. Section 4 treats the most important tool in the analysis of defaultable Libor market models: the survival measures or defaultable forward measures: We introduce two versions of these measures: an unrestricted version the survival measure of Schönbucher 999 and the restriction of this measure to the background filtration as it is used in Bielecki and Rutkowski 22. We derive the Radon-Nikodym densities of these measures with respect to their default-free counterparts and with respect to measures at different time horizons and show how these measures can be used to price survival-contingent payoffs. The pricing of default-contingent payoffs, i.e. payoffs that are paid at the time of default, is treated in section 5. Such default-contingent payoffs are necessary in order to model recovery payoffs of real-world defaultable securities like coupon-bearing bonds or credit default swaps. In this paper, we chose the recovery of par parametrization of recovery which seemed to us to be the most realistic parametrization of recovery payoffs. This setup leads to an expression for the price of a recovery unit payoff in terms of an expectation of H, T k under the T k+ -survival measure. As closed-form solutions for these expressions do not exist, we provide approximate solutions for them. In order to demonstrate the flexibility and applicability of the modelling approach given here, we turn to the pricing of credit derivatives in the following sections. Section 6 treats the pricing of credit default swaps CDS in this model and section 7 the pricing of options on CDS. Both of these instruments are also important for the practical implementation of this model as an initial term structure of CDS prices would be the obvious calibration instrument for the initial term structure of default hazard rates, and the options on CDS would provide valuable volatility information. 4

. Notation We consider a fixed time horizon T and a discrete tenor structure = T < T <... < T n = T with δ k := T k+ T k for k =,..., n. We assume that default-free as well as defaultable zero coupon bonds with maturities T,..., T n are traded on the market. By Bt, T k resp. B t, T k we denote the time-t price of a default-free zero coupon bond resp. a defaultable zero coupon bond with zero recovery with maturity T k. Indicate the time of default by τ and the pre-default values of the defaultable bonds by B,, then we have B t, T i = {τ>t} Bt, T i and BT i, T i = for i {,..., n}. In what follows we are not going to model bond prices directly it is only assumed that the processes describing the evolution of the bond prices B, T i and of the predefault prices B, T i are special semimartingales whose values as well as all left hand limits are strictly positive. Instead, we are going to specify the dynamics of forward Libor rates. The following notation will be used: The default-free forward Libor rates are given by Lt, T k := Bt, Tk δ k Bt, T k+ k {,..., n }. The defaultable forward Libor rates are given by Lt, T k := Bt, Tk δ k Bt, T k+ k {,..., n }. The forward Libor spreads are given by St, T k := Lt, T k Lt, T k k {,..., n }. The default risk factors or forward survival processes are given by Dt, T k := Bt, T k Bt, T k k {,..., n}. The discrete-tenor forward default intensities are given by Ht, T k := Dt, Tk δ k Dt, T k+ k {,..., n }..2 The driving process The model is driven by a d-dimensional stochastic process L = L t t T with independent increments and absolutely continuous characteristics, henceforth abbreviated by PIIAC. These processes are also called time-inhomogeneous or non-homogeneous Lévy processes. More precisely, L = L,..., L d has independent increments, and for every t the law of L t is characterized by the characteristic function [ IE e i u,lt ] = exp i u, b s 2 u, c su + 5 e i u,x i u, x F s dx ds.

Here, b s, c s is a symmetric nonnegative-definite d d matrix, and F s is a measure on that integrates x 2 x and satisfies F s {} =. The Euclidian scalar product on is denoted by,, the respective norm by. It is assumed that sup b s + c s + x 2 x F s dx < s T where denotes any norm on the set of d d matrices and that there are constants M, ε > such that for every u [ + εm, + εm] d sup exp u, x F s dx <. 2 s T { x >} We call b, c, F := b s, c s, F s s T the characteristics of L. 2 Presentation of the model Let us begin by building up the default-free part of the model. The dynamics of default-free forward Libor rates are specified in the same way as in the Lévy Libor model introduced in Eberlein and Özkan 25, to whom we refer for a detailed construction. Here, we only give a very brief description of the Lévy Libor model. The model is constructed via backward induction and driven by a non-homogeneous Lévy process L T on a complete stochastic basis Ω, F = F T, F = F s s T, P T. The measure P T should be regarded as the forward measure associated with the settlement day T. Since L T is required to satisfy assumption, it can be written in its canonical decomposition as L T t t = cs dw T s + xµ ν T ds, dx. Here, W T denotes a standard Brownian motion, µ is the random measure associated with the jumps of L T, and ν T dt, dx = F T t dx dt is the compensator of µ. The characteristics of L T are given by, c, F T. Note that without loss of generality L T is assumed to be driftless. The following assumptions are made: LR.: For any maturity T i there is a deterministic and continuous function λ, T i : [, T i ] +, which represents the volatility of the forward Libor rate process L, T i. In addition, n λ j s, T i M for all s [, T ] and j {,..., d}, 3 i= where M is the constant from assumption 2 and we set λs, T i = for s > T i. LR.2: The initial term structure B, T i i {,..., n} is strictly positive and strictly decreasing in i. The dynamics of the forward Libor rates are specified as Lt, T k = L, T k exp b L s, T k, T k+ ds + λs, T k dl T k+ s 4 6

with initial condition L, T k = B, Tk δ k B, T k+. L T k+ equals L T plus some in general non-deterministic drift term which is chosen in such a way that L T k+ is driftless under the forward measure associated with the settlement day T k+, henceforth denoted by P Tk+. More precisely, L T k+ t = cs dw T k+ s + xµ ν T k+ ds, dx, 5 where W T k+ is a standard Brownian motion with respect to P Tk+ and ν T k+ is the P Tk+ -compensator of µ. The drift term b L s, T k, T k+ is specified in such a way that L, T k becomes a P Tk+ -martingale, i.e. b L s, T k, T k+ = 2 λs, T k, c s λs, T k 6 e λs,tk,x λs, T k, x F T k+ s dx. The connection between different forward measures is given by dp Tk+ dp T = n l=k+ + δ l LT k+, T l + δ l L, T l = B, T B, T k+ n l=k+ + δ l LT k+, T l. 7 Once restricted to the σ-field F t this becomes dp Tk+ dp T = B, T eft B, T k+ W T k+ t = W T t n l=k+ + δ l Lt, T l t [, T k+ ]. 8 The Brownian motions and compensators with respect to the different measures are connected via t n cs l=k+ αs, T l, T l+ ds 9 with and ν T k+ dt, dx = αs, T l, T l+ := δ ll, T l + δ l L, T l λs, T l n l=k+ βs, x, T l, T l+ ν T dt, dx =: F T k+ t dx dt, where βs, x, T l, T l+ := δ ll, T l e λs,tl,x +. 2 + δ l L, T l Note that L T k+ is usually not a non-homogeneous Lévy process under any of the measures P Ti except for k = n, since L T is by definition a PIIAC under P T. 7

The construction by backward induction guarantees that B,T j B,T k is a P T k -martingale for all j, k {,..., n}. Our goal in what follows is to include defaultable forward Libor rates in the Lévy Libor model. At first sight, an evident way to build up the defaultable part of the model is to specify the dynamics of the defaultable forward Libor rates by an expression similar to 4. However, LT k, T k < LT k, T k implies BT k, T k+ > BT k, T k+, in which case there is an arbitrage opportunity in the market, provided that B, T k+ has not defaulted until T k. It seems thus natural to specify the model in such a way that defaultable forward Libor rates are always higher than their default-free counterparts. This can be achieved by modelling forward Libor spreads or forward default intensities as positive processes, instead of specifying defaultable forward Libor rates directly. We can then get the defaultable forward Libor rates through or Lt, T k = St, T k + Lt, T k Lt, T k = Ht, T k + δ k Lt, T k + Lt, T k. 3 Unfortunately, H or S cannot be specified directly since their dynamics depend on the specification of the default time τ compare equation 8 and the discussion preceding it. In other words, as soon as τ is specified we cannot freely choose the dynamics of H or S. What we can and will do in the sequel is the following: We give a pre-specification for H and then construct τ in such a way that the dynamics of H implied by τ will match this pre-specification. The following assumptions are made in addition to LR. and LR.2: DLR.: For any maturity T i there is a deterministic and continuous function γ, T i : [, T i ] +, which represents the volatility of the forward default intensity H, T i. We set γs, T i = for T i < s T and tighten condition 3 by assuming that n λ j s, T i + γ j s, T i M for all s [, T ] and j {,..., d}. 4 i= DLR.2: The initial term structure B, T i i {,..., n} of defaultable zero coupon bond prices satisfies < B, T i B, T i for all T i as well as L, T i L, T i, i.e. B, T i B, T i+ B, T i B, T i+. To avoid confusion, let us denote by which we postulate to be given by Ĥ the pre-specified forward default intensities, Ĥt, T k = H, T k exp + b H s, T k, T k+ ds + cs γs, T k dw T k+ s γs, T k, x µ ν T k+ ds, dx 5 8

subject to the initial condition H, T k = B, Tk B, T k+ δ k B, T k B, T k+. W T k+ and ν T k+ are defined in 9 and. The drift term b H, T k, T k+ will be specified later. For the moment we only assume b H s, T k, T k+ = for T k < s T, i.e. we require that Ĥt, T k = ĤT k, T k for t [T k, T ]. 3 Construction of the time of default The construction of the default time will be done in the canonical way, that is for a given F-hazard process Γ a stopping time τ on an enlarged probability space will be constructed. We will do the construction for a general Γ first. The key question then will be which particular hazard process to choose to make H match Ĥ. For more details on the canonical construction we refer to Bielecki and Rutkowski 22, from whom the notation is adopted. Let Γ be an F-adapted, right-continuous, increasing process on Ω, F, P T satisfying Γ = and lim t Γ t =. Furthermore, let η be a random variable on some probability space ˆΩ, ˆF, ˆP that is uniformly distributed on [, ]. Consider the product space Ω, G, Q T defined by Ω := Ω ˆΩ, G := F ˆF, Q T := P T ˆP and denote by F the trivial extension of F to the enlarged probability space Ω, G, Q T, i.e. each A F t is of the form à ˆΩ for some à F t. We extend all stochastic processes from the default-free part of the model to the extended probability space by setting L T ω, ˆω := L T ω and similarly for all other processes. Define a random variable τ : Ω R + by τ := inf{t R + : e Γt η}. and denote H t := σ {τ u} u t and G t := F t H t for t [, T ]. Then τ is a stopping time with respect to the filtration G := G s s T since {τ t} H t G t. Moreover, for s t T we have compare Bielecki and Rutkowski 22, 8.4 Q T {τ > s F T } = Q T {τ > s F t } = Q T {τ > s F s } = e Γs, 6 i.e. Γ is the F-hazard process of τ under Q T. A question that arises naturally is whether or not L T is a non-homogeneous Lévy process with respect to Q T and the enlarged filtration G. Proposition L T is a non-homogeneous Lévy process with characteristics, c, F T on the stochastic basis Ω, G T, G, Q T. Proof: L T is clearly an adapted, càdlàg process and satisfies L T =. Its characteristic function is given by IE QT [expiul T t ] = expiul T t ω, ˆω dp T ˆP ω, ˆω = eω ˆΩ eω expiul T t ω dp T ω = IE PT [expiul T t ]. 9

Hence, the characteristic function of L T t and thus also the characteristics of L T are preserved. It remains to show that L T t L T s is independent of G s for s < t. Note that equation 6 is equivalent to the following statement see Bielecki and Rutkowski 22, p. 66/67: for any bounded, F T -measurable random variable X we have E QT [X G s ] = E QT [X F s ] s T. 7 Let B B d and A G s, then using 7 with X := B L T t L T t L T s is independent of F s we get Q T A {L T t L T s B} = = = A A A B L T t IE QT [ B L T t IE QT [ B L T t L T s and the fact that L T s dq T = Q T AQ T {L T t L T s F s ] dq T L T s ] dq T L T s B}. In particular, each forward Libor rate Lt, T k t Tk is a martingale with respect to the filtration G s s Tk and the measure Q Tk+, which is constructed from Q T in the same way as P Tk+ is constructed from P T. Γ is not only the F-hazard process of τ under Q T, but also the F-hazard process of τ under all other forward measures, as the following lemma shows: Lemma 2 Γ is the F-hazard process of τ under Q Tk for all k {,..., n}. Proof: Fix a k and denote by ψ the F Tk -measurable Radon Nikodym derivative of Q Tk with respect to Q T. Note that 6 is equivalent to the conditional independence of F T and H s given F s under Q T, that is for any bounded F T -measurable random variable X and any bounded H s -measurable random variable Y we have E QT [XY F s ] = E QT [X F s ] E QT [Y F s ] s T compare Bielecki and Rutkowski 22, p. 66. Using the abstract Bayes rule and this conditional independence plus a dominated convergence argument we get Q Tk {τ > s F s } = IE Q T [ψ {τ>s} F s ] IE QT [ψ F s ] = IE Q T [ψ F s ] IE QT [ {τ>s} F s ] IE QT [ψ F s ] = e Γs. To clarify the relationship between default time and default intensities remember that the time-t value of a defaultable bond is given by B t, T k = {τ>t} Bt, T k. In the model for the default-free Libor rates, the time-t price of a contingent claim X paying {τ>tk } at T k is given by X t := Bt, T k IE QTk [ {τ>tk } G t ] = {τ>t} Bt, T k IE QTk [ {τ>tk } G t ].

To have a consistent model, we thus have to have and consequently at least on {τ > t} or equivalently B t, T k = {τ>t} Bt, T k IE QTk [ {τ>tk } G t ] Bt, T k = Bt, T k IE QTk [ {τ>tk } G t ] Dt, T k = IE QTk [ {τ>tk } G t ], 8 which immediately provides a formula for H and also for S. Let us now turn to the question which hazard process Γ to choose to make H match its pre-specification. As pointed out, to have a consistent model we have to have B t, T k = Bt, T k Q Tk {τ > T k G t } 9 = IE QTk [ {τ>tk } F t ] Bt, T k {τ>t} IE QTk [ {τ>t} F t ], where the last equality follows from Bielecki and Rutkowski 22, 5.2. Let Bt, T k := Bt, T k IE Q Tk [ {τ>tk } F t ] IE QTk [ {τ>t} F t ] = Bt, T k IE Q Tk [ {τ>tk } F t ] e Γt, 2 then Dt, T k = IE QTk [ e Γt Γ T k Ft ]. In particular, [ Ht, T k = Dt, Tk δ k Dt, T k+ = IE Q Tk e Γ ] T k F t [ δ k IE QTk+ e Γ ]. 2 T k+ F t It is clear from the previous equation that, in order to make H match its prespecification Ĥ, we only need to specify the hazard process Γ at the points T k for k {,..., n} in a suitable way. The values of Γ in between these points do not have an influence on the value of H. Moreover, we know from equation 2 that IE QTk [ e Γ T k FTk ] = e Γ T k + δk HT k, T k. We now choose the hazard process and define Γ recursively by setting Γ :=, Γ Tk := Γ Tk + log + δ k ĤT k, T k k {,..., n} = k log + δ l ĤT l, T l, 22 l= and for t T k, T k Γ t := α k tγ Tk + α k tγ Tk,

where α k : [T k, T k ] [, ] is a continuous, strictly increasing function satisfying α k T k = and α k T k =. Obviously Γ is a continuous, strictly increasing since Ĥ, > by construction, and F-adapted process since Γ Tk is F Tk -measurable and can be used for the canonical construction. It still has to be checked whether the implied dynamics of H match those of Ĥ. Using 2 and 22 we get Ht, T = δ IE QT2 [e Γ T 2 +Γ T F t ] = [ ] δ IE QT2 +δ HT b F t,t or, written differently, [ ] IE QT2 F t = + δ ĤT, T + δ Ht, T. Consequently, H, T meets its pre-specification if +δ Ht,T b is a Q T2 - t T martingale. More generally we have the following result. Recall that Ĥt, T i = ĤT i, T i for t [T i, T ]. l Lemma 3 H, T k meets its pre-specification if i= +δ iht,ti b is a Q Tl+ - t T l martingale for all l {,..., k}. Proof: The result for k = has been proven above. prerequisite we get for k > [ Ht, T k = IE k Q Tk i= [ δ k k IE QTk+ i= +δ i b HTi,T i +δ i b HTi,T i Using 2, 22 and the ] F t ] Ft = δ k + δ k Ĥt, T k = Ĥt, T k. Remember that we can still choose the drift coefficients b H, T k, T k+ in 5 in order to satisfy the prerequisite of the previous lemma. This choice is done in appendix A. In the subsequent sections, we assume that the drift terms b H, T k, T k+ are chosen as described in proposition 3 and do not distinguish between H and Ĥ anymore. 4 Defaultable forward measures It is well known that pricing of derivatives in default-free interest rate models can often be facilitated considerably by changing numeraires, i.e. changing measures, in a suitable way. In particular, forward measures prove to be useful in many situations. Similarly, valuation of contingent claims in our model can be simplified by using two counterparts to default-free forward measures. The first definition traces back to Schönbucher 999: 2

Definition 4 The defaultable forward martingale measure or survival measure Q Ti for the settlement day T i is defined on Ω, G Ti by dq Ti dq Ti := B, T i B, T i B T i, T i = B, T i B, T i {τ>t i }. Equation 9 ensures that the preceding expression is indeed a density. Q Ti corresponds to the choice of B, T i as a numeraire. We use quotation marks since B, T i is not a strictly positive process with probability one. Consequently, Q Ti is absolutely continuous with respect to Q Ti, but the two measures are not mutually equivalent. In particular, the set A = {τ t} for t, T i ] has a strictly positive probability under Q Ti but zero probability under Q Ti. The term survival measure is justified by the fact that Q Ti A = Q T i A {τ > T i } Q Ti {τ > T i } = Q Ti A {τ > T i } A G Ti, i.e. Q Ti can be regarded as the forward measure Q Ti conditioned on survival until T i. Once restricted to the σ-field G t, the defaultable forward measure becomes dq Ti = B, T i Bt, T i dq Ti B, T i Bt, T i {τ>t} = B, T i B, T i Q Ti {τ > T i } F t {τ>t} Q Ti {τ > t} F t. Gt The first equality follows from the fact that B,T i B,T i is a Q Ti -martingale, the second equality from 2. Another very useful tool in the context of derivative pricing is the restricted defaultable forward measure, which has already been used in Bielecki and Rutkowski 22, Section 5.2. Note that the defaultable forward measure restricted to the σ-field F t is given by dq Ti = B, T i dq Ti B, T i Q T i {τ > T i } F t Ft and denote by P Ti the restriction of Q Ti to the σ-field F Ti. This notation differs slightly from the notation in the default-free part of the model where P Ti was defined on F Ti. However, this should not cause any confusion since F Ti is the trivial extension of F Ti. Definition 5 The restricted defaultable forward martingale measure P Ti settlement day T i is defined on Ω, F Ti by for the dp Ti = B, T i dp Ti B, T i Q T i {τ > T i } F Ti. We have an explicit expression for this density, namely dp Ti = B, T i dp Ti B, T i e Γ T i = B, T i i B, T i + δ k HT k, T k. 23 k= 3

Restricted to the the σ-field F t this becomes since i k= +δ k H,T k is a P T i -martingale dp Ti dp Ti = B, T i Ft B, T i i k= + δ k Ht, T k. 24 We get the representation compare Kluge 25, A. dp Ti i = E Ti Y l cs γs, T l dw T i s dp Ti l= i + + Y l e γs,tl,x µ ν T i ds, dx with l= Y l s := δ lhs, T l + δ l Hs, T l. Hence, the two predictable processes in Girsanov s Theorem for semimartingales see Jacod and Shiryaev 23, Theorem III.3.24 associated with this change of measure are We can conclude that i βs = Yγs, l T l Y s, x = W T i t l= i l= := W T i t + + Y l i l= and e γs,t l,x. Y l cs γs, T l ds 25 is a P Ti -standard Brownian motion and the P Ti -compensator of µ is given by i ν T i ds, dx = + Y l e γs,tl,x ν T i ds, dx =: F T i s dx ds. 26 l= Similar to the default-free part of the model, we have the following connection between restricted defaultable forward measures for different settlement days: Lemma 6 The defaultable Libor rate Lt, T i t Ti is a P Ti+ -martingale and dp Ti = B, T i+ B, T i + δ ilt, T i t T i. Ft dp Ti+ Proof: From equation 3 we get + δ i Lt, T i = + δ i Ht, T i + δ i Lt, T i = i i + δ k Ht, T k + δ i Lt, T i + δ k Ht, T k. k= 4 k=

Applying equations 8 and 24 yields + δ i Lt, T i = B, T i+ B, T i+ = B, T i B, T i+ dp Ti+ dp Ti+ dp Ti dp Ti+ Ft B, T i B, T i+ Ft dp Ti dp Ti+ B, T i Ft B, T i dp Ti dp Ti Ft and both statements are established. As mentioned above, restricted defaultable forward measures can be used to determine prices of contingent claims. Consider a defaultable claim with a promised payoff of X at the settlement day T i and zero recovery upon default. Then its time-t value is given by π X t := {τ>t} Bt, T i IE QTi [X {τ>ti } G t ] t [, T i ]. Consider the general case in which X is G Ti -measurable and the common case of an F Ti -measurable promised payoff X. The following proposition is a typo-corrected version of Bielecki and Rutkowski 22, Proposition 5.2.3: Proposition 7 Assume that the promised payoff X is G Ti -measurable and integrable with respect to Q Ti. Then If X is F Ti -measurable, then π X t = {τ>t} Bt, T i IE QTi [X G t ] = B t, T i IE QTi [X G t ]. π X t = {τ>t} Bt, T i IE PTi [X F t ] = B t, T i IE PTi [X F t ]. Proof: The first statement can be proved along the lines of Bielecki and Rutkowski 22, Proposition 5.2.3. For the second statement observe that π X t = {τ>t} Bt, T i IE QTi [X {τ>ti } G t ] = {τ>t} Bt, T i IE Q Ti [X {τ>ti } F t ] Q Ti {τ > t F t } = {τ>t} Bt, T i IE Q Ti [X {τ>ti } F t ] Q Ti {τ > T i F t } = {τ>t} Bt, T i IE P Ti [XQ Ti {τ > T i F Ti } F t ] Q Ti {τ > T i F t } = {τ>t} Bt, T i IE PTi [X F t ]. We used Bielecki and Rutkowski 22, 5.2 for the second equality, equation 2 for the third and the abstract Bayes rule for the last equality. 5

5 Recovery rules and bond prices In the previous sections we specified the evolution of ratios of pre-default values of defaultable zero coupon bonds with zero recovery. In real markets however, defaultable bonds usually have a positive recovery. In order to adapt our model to this fact, we have to incorporate suitable recovery rules for bonds. An overview on different kinds of recovery rules can be found in Bielecki and Rutkowski 22 and Schönbucher 23. In default-free interest rate models, a coupon bearing bond can be considered as a portfolio of zero coupon bonds. For defaultable coupon bonds the situation is not quite as simple. A coupon bond can still be decomposed into a series of zero coupon bonds, but it does not make much sense to assume the same recovery rate π for all. The claim of a creditor on the defaulted debtor s assets is only determined by the outstanding principal and accrued interest payments of the defaulted loan or bond, any future coupon payments do not enter the consideration. We use the following recovery scheme for coupon bearing bonds: Assumption recovery of par. The recovery of a defaultable coupon bond that defaults in the time interval T k, T k+ ] is given by the recovery rate π [, times the sum of the notional and the accrued interest over T k, T k+ ]. It is paid at T k+. Note that this assumption restricts recovery payments to the tenor dates. This restriction is not strong for a number of reasons. We refer to Schönbucher 999, Section 6.2 for a discussion. Let us denote by e X k t the time-t value of receiving an amount of X at T k+ if and only if a default occurred in the time interval T k, T k+ ]. Lemma 8 Let X be F Tk -measurable. Then, for t T k Proof: We have e X k t = {τ>t}bt, T k+ δ k IE PTk+ [XHT k, T k F t ]. e X k T k+ = X {τ>tk } X {τ>tk+ }. Receiving an amount of X {τ>tk } at T k+ is equivalent to receiving an amount of X {τ>tk }BT k, T k+ at T k. Combining this fact with proposition 7 yields for t T k e X k t = {τ>t} Bt, T k IE PTk [XBT k, T k+ F t ] Bt, T k+ IE PTk+ [X F t ] = {τ>t} Bt, T k+ IE PTk+ [ + δ k LT k, T k XBT k, T k+ F t ] IE PTk+ [X F t ] = {τ>t} Bt, T k+ δ k IE PTk+ [XHT k, T k F t ]. The second equality follows from the abstract Bayes rule, the third follows by using equation 3. With the help of the preceding lemma we can deduce the time- price of a defaultable coupon bond with m coupons of c that are promised to be paid at the dates 6

T,..., T m as m Bfixed π ; c, m := B, T m m + cb, T k+ + π + ce k k= m = B, T m + B, T k+ c + π + cδ k IE PTk+ [HT k, T k ]. k= Similarly, the price of a defaultable floating coupon bond that pays an interest rate composed of the default-free Libor rate plus a constant spread x can be obtained. In order to price defaultable fixed coupon bonds we need to evaluate IE PTk+ [HT k, T k ]: Let us use the abbreviations V i t := δ ilt, T i + δ i Lt, T i and k= Y i t := δ iht, T i + δ i Ht, T i. Combining the equations 5, 38, 25, and 26 yields Ht, T k = H, T k exp b H s, T k, T k+ ds + cs γs, T k dw T k+ s + γs, T k, x µ ν T k+ ds, dx, where b H s, T k, T k+ = 2 γs, T k k, c s γs, T k + + YV l k Y k l= e γs,t k,x γs, T k, x Rd V k Y k k γs, T l, c s λs, T k F T k+ s dx e λs,tk,x + Y k e γs,tk,x l= + Y l e γs,tl,x Making use of Kallsen and Shiryaev 22, Lemma 2.6 we get F T k+ s dx. Ht, T k = 27 k Y l H, T k exp V k γs, T l, c s λs, T k ds + Rd V k Y k E t k l= l= Y k e λs,t k,x + Y l cs γs, T k dw T k+ s + + Y k e γs,tl,x 7 e γs,tk,x ν T k+ ds, dx e γs,tk,x µ ν T k+ ds, dx.

To obtain an expression for IE PTk+ [HT k, T k ] we approximate the stochastic terms V i and Y i by their deterministic initial values V i and Y i. Similar approximations have been used by Brace, Gatarek, and Musiela 997, Rebonato 998, and Schlögl 22. This yields IE PTk+ [HT k, T k ] H, T k exp Tk + k l= Rd V k Y k Tk + Y l k l= Y lv k Y k e λs,t k,x where ν T k+ is an approximation for ν T k+ given by γs, T l, c s λs, T k ds + Y k e γs,tl,x e γs,tk,x ν T k+ ds, dx, ν T k+ ds, dx = k l= + Y l n l=k+ e γs,t l,x 28 + V l e λs,tl,x ν T ds, dx. 6 Credit default swaps The market for credit derivatives has increased enormously in volume since the first of these contracts have been introduced in the early 99s. Their success is due to the fact that they allow to transfer credit risk from one party to another and therewith to manage the risk exposure. There are many publications describing various credit derivatives in detail, among which are Schönbucher 23 and Bielecki and Rutkowski 22. Information about the size of the credit derivatives market as well as on the market share that different products have can be found in the credit derivatives survey of Patel 23. The aim of this section is to derive valuation formulae, in our model framework, for the most popular and heavily traded credit derivative: the credit default swaps. Credit default swaps are natural calibration instruments for the term structure of forward default intensities. Thus, the availability of an efficient and accurate pricing formula is of high value for the practical implementation of this model. In the following section we also provide valuation formulae for the most popular spread volatility dependent credit derivative: The credit default swaption. While being much less liquid than the standard credit default swap, the value of this contract depends directly on the specification of the volatility function of the term structure of forward default intensities. Thus, given the necessary data these results can be used to calibrate the dynamics of the model to a given set of credit default swaptions. Alternatively, they serve at least as a case study regarding the pricing of an important spread volatility-dependent credit derivative. Clearly, the employed valuation techniques can also be used to price other creditsensitive swap contracts e.g. total rate of return swaps and asset swaps or other 8

credit options e.g. options on defaultable bonds and credit spread options. For more details we refer to Kluge 25. We use the notational convention that the credit derivative contract is signed between two parties A who will usually receive a payment if a default occurs and B who pays in case of a default. The reference entity e.g. a corporate bond is issued by a third party C. If credit derivatives are traded over-the-counter, each party of the contract is exposed to the risk that the other party cannot fulfill its obligations. In the following, we assume that this counterparty risk can be neglected, i.e. only the risk that the reference entity defaults is considered. Credit default swaps can be used to insure defaultable assets against default. The protection buyer A agrees to pay a fixed amount to the protection seller B periodically until a pre-specified credit event e.g. the default of a bond issued by a reference party C occurs or the contract terminates. In turn, B promises to make a specified payment to A that covers his loss if the credit event happens. There are various types of default swaps differing in the specification of the credit event as well as in the specification of the default payment. Let us consider a standard default swap with maturity date T m whose credit event is the default of a fixed coupon bond issued by C. The default payment is chosen such that it covers the loss of A. More precisely, A receives an amount of π + c at T k+ if a default happens in T k, T k+ ] for k {,..., m }. For this protection A pays a fee s at the dates T,..., T m until default. Our goal is to determine the default swap rate, i.e. the level of s that makes the initial value of the contract equal to zero. The time- value of the fee payments is s m B, T k. k= The initial value of the default payment equals m π + ce k. k= Consequently, the default swap rate is s = π + c m k= B, T k m k= B, T k δ k IE PTk [HT k, T k ]. The expectations in the equation can be obtained as in the previous section. 7 Credit default swaptions The purpose of this section is to price credit default swaptions within our model framework under the following restriction on the volatility functions: CDS with fee payments in arrears, i.e. at the dates T,..., T m, can be treated similarly by adjusting indices. 9

Assumption DLR.VOL. The volatility structures factorize in the following way: for i {,..., n } λs, T i = λ i σs and γs, T i = γ i σs s T i where λ i and γ i are positive constants and where σ : [, T ] + does not depend on i. This condition allows us to derive approximate pricing formulae that can numerically be evaluated fast. As in the previous section we neglect the counterparty risk. A credit default swaption gives its holder the right to enter a credit default swap at some pre-specified time and swap rate. These options are often embedded in other credit derivatives e.g. as an extension option in a credit default swap. For more details we refer to Schönbucher 999. Let us consider a credit default swaption that is knocked out at default with strike rate S and maturity T i on a default swap that terminates at T m i < m n with an underlying fixed coupon bond. Its time-t i value is π CDS T i S, T i, T m := {τ>ti } m st i ; T i, T m S + BT i, T k where st i ; T i, T m denotes the default swap rate at time T i. Note that m {τ>ti }st i, T i, T m BT i, T k = Proposition 7 yields 2 k=i {τ>ti } π + c π CDS := π CDS S, T i, T m m k=i = B, T i IE PTi [ π + c k=i BT i, T k+ δ k IE PTk+ [HT k, T k F Ti ]. m k=i BT i, T k+ δ k IE PTk+ [HT k, T k F Ti ] m S k=i, ] + BT i, T k. As before, we approximate the stochastic terms V i and Y i in 27 by their deterministic initial values V i and Y i and obtain IE PTk+ [HT k, T k F Ti ] C i,k HT i, T k 2 Alternatively, P m k=i BT i, T k can be taken as numeraire for a new probability measure, the default swap measure compare Schönbucher 999. Whereas this can be useful for driving Brownian motions, it does not facilitate calculations for general Lévy processes. 2

with C i,k := exp and ν T k+ Tk k T i l= Tk + T i Y lv k Y k Rd V k Y k k l= γs, T l, c s λs, T k ds e λs,tk,x + Y k e γs,tk,x + Y l given by 28. Consequently, π CDS = B, T i IE PTi [ π + c e γs,tl,x m k=i ν T k+ ds, dx BT i, T k+ δ k C i,k HT i, T k m S k=i = B, T i IE PTi [ π + cδ m C i,m HT i, T m m l=i + δ l LT i, T l + δ l HT i, T l ] + BT i, T k m 2 + π + cδ k C i,k HT i, T k S + k ]. l=i + δ llt i, T l + δ l HT i, T l S k=i To evaluate the preceding expression we use Laplace transformation methods due to Raible 2. For this purpose, we derive a convolution representation of the swaption price first. Combining the equations 4, 6, 5, and 38 with 9 2 and 25 26 yields for l {i,..., n } Ti LT i, T l = L, T l exp b L Ti s, T l, T i ds + λs, T l dl T i s, Ti HT i, T l = H, T l exp b H Ti s, T l, T i ds + γs, T l dl T i s with and j=i L T i t := cs dw T i s + j= xµ ν T i ds, dx b L s, T l, T i = l V j λs, T i j Y j γs, T j, c s λs, T l 2 λs, T l, c s λs, T l [ e λs,t l,x n λs, T l, x j=l+ n j=i i j= + V j e λs,tj,x + V j + Y j 2 e λs,t j,x ] e γs,t j,x F T s dx

as well as b H s, T l, T i = l Y j γs, T j + V j λs, T j, c s γs, T l 2 γs, T l, c s γs, T l j=i l + j= + + Y j V l [ Y l γs, T l, x γs, T j, c s λs, T l n j=i i j= e γs,tl,x + V j + Y j n j=l+ e λs,t j,x e γs,t j,x + V j e λs,t j,x ] e γs,t j,x l j= + Y j [ V l n Y l e λs,tl,x + V j j=l+ l j= e λs,tj,x ] + Y j e γs,tj,x F T s dx F T s dx. Again, we approximate the stochastic terms V k and Y k in the drift terms b L s, T l, T i and b H s, T l, T i by their initial values and call the resulting deterministic drifts b L s, T l, T i and b H s, T l, T i respectively. Then, due to the assumption on the volatility structure, we get λl LT i, T l L, T l exp X Ti + Bl L, σ sum γl HT i, T l H, T l exp X Ti + Bl H σ sum with and σ sum := X Ti := B L l := m λ l + γ l, l=i Ti m Ti l=i λs, T l + γs, T l dl T i s b L s, T l, T i ds, B H l := = σ sum Ti Ti σs dl T i s, b H s, T l, T i ds. The price of the credit default swaption now depends on the distribution of one random variable only, namely on the distribution of X Ti with respect to P Ti. Assume that this distribution possesses a Lebesgue-density ϕ we refer to Eberlein and Kluge 26 for a discussion on this assumption. The option price can then be written as a convolution, namely π CDS = B, T i g xϕx dx = B, T i g ϕ 29 R 22

with gx := vx + and vx := π + cδ m C i,m H, T m exp γ m σ sum x + Bm H m l=i + δl L, T l exp λ l σ sum x + Bl L m l=i + δl H, T l exp γ l σ sum x + Bl H + m 2 k=i π + cδk C i,k H, T k exp γ k σ sum x + Bk H S k l=i + δl L, T l exp λ l σ sum x + Bl L k l=i + δl H, T l exp γ S. l σ sum x + Bl H The next step is to determine for which values the bilateral Laplace transform of g exists. Note that v is continuous, tends to S as x and to m is as x. Consequently, g has compact support and the bilateral Laplace transform of g exists for all z C. In a numerical evaluation of v, for large values of m i, we can save computational time by applying the multiplication scheme m 2 c k k=i l=i k d l = d i c i + d i+ c i+ + d i+... c m 3 + d m 2 c m 2. Putting pieces together, we obtain the following formula for the price of the credit default swaption: Proposition 9 Suppose that the distribution of X Ti possesses a Lebesgue-density. Denote by M X T i T i the P Ti -moment generating function of X Ti. Choose an R R such that M X T i T i R < e.g. R =. Then the price of the credit default swaption is approximately given by π CDS K, T i, T m = B, T i R L[g]R + ium X T i T π i R iu du, 3 where L[g] denotes the bilateral Laplace transform of g. Furthermore, we have for z C with real part Rz = R with M X T i T i z exp z 2 σsum 2 ν Ti ds, dx := Ti Ti + n l=i i l= σs, c s σs ds 3 e zσsum σs,x zσ sum σs, x ν Ti ds, dx + V l e λs,t l,x + Y l e γs,t l,x νt ds, dx. 32 Proof: Using the convolution representation 29 and performing Laplace and inverse Laplace transformations compare the proof of Theorem 4. in Eberlein and 23

Kluge 26, we arrive at 3. It remains to derive an expression for the moment generating function: Ti zσ sum with M X T i T i z = IE PTi [ exp ν T i ds, dx = n l=i i l= +zσ sum Ti σs dw T i s ] σs, x µ ν T i ds, dx + V l e λs,t l,x + Y l e γs,t l,x νt ds, dx. We approximate the random compensator ν T i by the non-random compensator given in 32. Expression 3 then follows e.g. by using Kluge 25, Proposition.9. A Specification of the drift We specify the drift recursively starting with b, T, T 2. More precisely, we look for a process b, T, T 2 such that + δ Ĥt, T becomes a Q T2 -martingale. t T Next, b, T 2, T 3 is specified such that + δ Ĥt, T + δ 2 Ĥt, T 2 t T2 becomes a Q T3 -martingale, and so on. Let us begin with two lemmata: Lemma Let X be a real-valued semimartingale with X = and X >. Then EX = E X + X c, X c + + x + x µ X. Proof: Use Lemma 2.6 in Kallsen and Shiryaev 22 twice plus the fact that exp X = exp X. Lemma For k {2,..., n} and i {,..., k } where Ĥt, T i = H, T i E t as, T i, T k ds + cs γs, T i dw T k s + e γs,ti,x µ ν T k ds, dx, as, T i, T k := b H s, T i, T k + 2 γs, T i, c s γs, T i 33 + e γs,ti,x γs, T i, x F T k s dx. and b H s, T i, T k is given by 34. 24

Proof: From the default-free part of the model we know that t k cs and W T i+ t = W T k t ν T i+ dt, dx = k l=i+ l=i+ βs, x, T l, T l+ αs, T l, T l+ ds ν T k dt, dx with α and β given by and 2. Consequently, equation 5 implies Ĥt, T i = H, T i exp b H s, T i, T k ds + cs γs, T i dw T k s + γs, T i, x µ ν T k ds, dx, where b H s, T i, T k := b H s, T i, T i+ 34 k γs, T i, c s αs, T l, T l+ l=i+ k γs, T i, x l=i+ βs, x, T l, T l+ The claim now follows from Kallsen and Shiryaev 22, Lemma 2.6. Proposition 2 b H s, T, T 2 = +δ b Ht,T where Y s := δ b Hs,T +δ b Hs,T. Y + Proof: Lemma gives us F T k s dx. is a Q T2 -martingale if for s [, T ] t T γs, T, c s γs, T 35 2 e γs,t,x γs, T, x + Y e γs,t,x F T 2 s dx, with Ĥt, T = H, T E t as, T, T 2 ds + cs γs, T dw T 2 s + e γs,t,x µ ν T 2 ds, dx as, T, T 2 = b H s, T, T 2 + 2 γs, T, c s γs, T 36 + e γs,t,x γs, T, x F T 2 s dx. 25