The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by. δ tj 1 (s tj s tj 1 ) (9.1) j=1

Similar documents
In chapter 5, we approximated the Black-Scholes model

δ j 1 (S j S j 1 ) (2.3) j=1

A1: American Options in the Binomial Model

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Lévy models in finance

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1 Interest Based Instruments

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Chapter 14. The Multi-Underlying Black-Scholes Model and Correlation

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

1 Geometric Brownian motion

Lecture 15: Exotic Options: Barriers

Non-semimartingales in finance

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

MAS452/MAS6052. MAS452/MAS Turn Over SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS AND STATISTICS. Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

The British Russian Option

King s College London

1 The continuous time limit

Path Dependent British Options

Homework Assignments

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models

Replication strategies of derivatives under proportional transaction costs - An extension to the Boyle and Vorst model.

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

Risk Neutral Measures

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Risk Neutral Valuation

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Lecture: Continuous Time Finance Lecturer: o. Univ. Prof. Dr. phil. Helmut Strasser

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Binomial model: numerical algorithm

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

King s College London

(1) Consider a European call option and a European put option on a nondividend-paying stock. You are given:

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Modeling via Stochastic Processes in Finance

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

Numerical schemes for SDEs

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Futures Options. The underlying of a futures option is a futures contract.

S t d with probability (1 p), where

Stochastic Processes and Brownian Motion

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 6

1. 2 marks each True/False: briefly explain (no formal proofs/derivations are required for full mark).

B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

The Black-Scholes Model

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Probability in Options Pricing

Option Pricing. Chapter Discrete Time

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Analysis of the sensitivity to discrete dividends : A new approach for pricing vanillas

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

Advanced topics in continuous time finance

Binomial Model for Forward and Futures Options

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Lectures on Financial Mathematics. Harald Lang

Results for option pricing

Valuation of performance-dependent options in a Black- Scholes framework

A Classical Approach to the Black-and-Scholes Formula and its Critiques, Discretization of the model - Ingmar Glauche

A Continuity Correction under Jump-Diffusion Models with Applications in Finance

Introduction to Game-Theoretic Probability

Time-changed Brownian motion and option pricing

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Investment Guarantees Chapter 7. Investment Guarantees Chapter 7: Option Pricing Theory. Key Exam Topics in This Lesson.

Introduction to Affine Processes. Applications to Mathematical Finance

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

A Brief Review of Derivatives Pricing & Hedging

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

Transcription:

Chapter 9 The isk Neutral Pricing Measure for the Black-Scholes Model The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by v tk = v 0 + k δ tj (s tj s tj ) (9.) where v tk = e rt k Vtk is the discounted portfolio value at time t k = k t, k = 0,,..., N T = T/ t and s tk = e rt k Stk denotes the discounted asset price. Suppose that the price process S tk is given by a geometric Brownian motion such that s tk = e rt 2 k (µ S 0 e 2 )t k+x tk = S 0 e xt k +( 2 /2)t k =: s(x tk, t k ) (9.2) Suppose further that we have some european option with payoff H or discounted payoff h = e rt H where h = h(s tn ) or more generally h = h(s t0,..., S tn ), N = N T, and suppose that there is a replicating strategy such that δ tk = δ tk (S t,..., S tk ) (9.3) h = v tn = v 0 + Since v 0 = V 0, the price of the option, is a number, we can write v 0 = E v 0 = E h N δ tk (s tk s tk ) (9.4) k= N E δ tk (s tk s tk ) (9.5) k= where the expectation in (9.5) can be choosen arbitrarily. Let us consider (9.5) for the Wiener measure, dw ({x t } 0<t T ) = N T lim Π t 0 k= p t (x (k ) t, x k t ) dx k t (9.6) 65

66 Chapter 9 Because of Theorem 4. we have E W δk (s k s k ) = δ k (x t,..., x tk ) ( s(x tk, t k ) s(x tk, t k ) ) Π k p tj t j (x tj, x tj ) dx tj k ( = δ k (x t,..., x tk ) s(x, t tk k) p (x, x ) dx s(x tk tk tk tk tk tk k )), t k = ( δ k (x t,..., x tk ) E W s(xtk, t k ) x tk s(xtk, t k ) k k Π p tj t j (x tj, x tj ) dx tj ) k Π (9.7) p tj t j (x tj, x tj ) dx tj where we introduced the conditional expectation E W f({xs } 0 s T ) x t := f({x s }) dw ({x s } t<s T ) (9.8) with the obvious definition (t = N t t) dw ({x t } t<s T ) := lim N T Π t 0 j=n t+ p t (x (j ) t, x j t ) dx j t (9.9) In particular, if the function f in (9.8) depends only on a single x s, f = f(x s ), then f(x s ) if t s E W f(xs ) x t = (9.0) f(x s ) p s t (x t, x s ) dx s if t < s Let us compute the conditional expectation E W s(xtk, t k ) x tk in the last line of (9.7). We have, using t = t k t k E W s(xtk, t k ) x tk = s(x tk, t k ) p tk t k (x tk, x tk ) dx tk = t S 0 e xt k +( 2 /2)t k e (x tk x tk ) 2 2 t dx tk = S 0 e xt k +( 2 /2)t k = S 0 e xt k +( 2 /2)t k e 2 2 (t k t k ) e t y e y2 2 = s(x tk, t k ) e ()(t k t k ) (9.) Now, suppose the factor e ()(t k t k ) in (9.) would be absent. Then the round brackets in the third line of (9.7) would be zero for all k and the price of the option v 0 would be

Chapter 9 67 given by the expectation of the discounted payoff. Thus, we would be able to compute the price without knowing the hedging strategy, provided that there is a replicating strategy. Now, this factor is not absent but we can ask the following question: Is there some measure d W such that s(xtk, t k ) x tk = s(xtk, t k ) (9.2) If this is the case then we can compute the price v 0 of the option with discounted payoff h by taking the expectation value with respect to d W, v 0 = h (9.3) since the round brackets in the third line of (9.7) all vanish. There is the following Theorem 9.: Let s tk = s(x tk, t k ) be a discounted geometric Brownian motion given by (9.2). Define the kernels p t (x, y) = p µ,r, t (x, y) by Then: p t (x, y) := t e (x y t)2 2t (9.4) a) The kernels p satisfy p s (x, y) p t (y, z) = p s+t (x, z) (9.5) and p s(x, y) = for all x. That is, the measure is well defined. d W ({x t } 0<t T ) := lim N T Π t 0 k= p t (x (k ) t, x k t ) dx k t (9.6) b) The price process (9.2) is a martingale with respect to d W. That is, s(xt, t ) x t := s(x t, t ) d W ({x s } t<s T ) = s(x t, t) t < t (9.7) The measure d W is called an equivalenartingale measure (with respect to the price process s t ).

68 Chapter 9 Proof: a) Let p t (x, y) be the kernel (4.3). Then p t (x, y) = p t ( x t, y) ( = p t x, y + t) ( = p t x, y + ) 2 2 (9.8) such that, with Lemma 4., p s (x, y) p t (y, z) = p s ( x = p s+t ( x which proves part (a). Part (b) is obtained as (9.), s(xt, t ) x t = s(x t, t ) p t t(x t, x t ) dx t = (t t) s, y) ( p t y, z + t) s, z + t) = p s+t (x, z) (9.9) S 0 e x t +( 2 /2)t e (x t x t (t 2 t) ) 2(t t) dx t = S 0 e xt+( 2 /2)t e 2 2 (t t) e (x t (t t) = S 0 e xt+( 2 /2)t e 2 2 (t t) e t t y e y2 2 = S 0 e xt+( 2 /2)t xt+ (t t)) ( x t x t (t t)) 2 e 2(t t) dx t = s(x t, t) (9.20) This proves the theorem. In chapter 5 where we approximated the Black-Scholes model with a suitable Binomial model, we were able to prove the following pricing formula for some non path dependent option with payoff H = T ), see Theorem 5.2: V BS 0 = e rt H ( 2 (r S 0 e ) 2 )T + T x e x2 2 dx (9.2) Let us rederive (9.2) by using the equivalenartingale measure. Suppose we have a european option with discounted payoff h(s T ) = e rt T ) and that the namics of S is given by the Black-Scholes model with drift µ and volatility, S T = S 0 e x T +(µ 2 2 )T (9.22) Observe that the drift parameter µ does not show up in the pricing formula (9.2). This was actually a quite fundamental result of chapter 5. Here we will come up with the same conclusion:

Chapter 9 69 Let δ be the replicating strategy. Then N T v T = h(s T ) = v 0 + δ tk (s tk s tk ) (9.23) k= We fix some t = t k and take the expectation with respect to d W ({x s } t<s T ). This gives and we get h(st ) x t = v0 + k δ tj (s tj s tj ) = v tk = v t = e rt V t (9.24) V t = e rt h(st ) x t = e r(t t) H ( S 0 e ) x T +(µ 2 2 )T p T t (x t, x T ) dx T = e r(t t) = e r(t t) = e r(t t) = e r(t t) H ( S 0 e ) x T +(µ 2 2 )T e (x t x T (T t) ) 2 2(T t) dx T (T t) H ( S t e (x T x t)+()(t t) e 2 2 (T t) e r(t t)) e (x T x t + (T t) ) 2 H ( 2 y+(r S t e 2 )(T t)) e y2 2(T t) (T t) H ( S t e T t y+(r 2 2 )(T t)) e y2 2 2(T t) dx T (T t) (9.25) and, for t = 0, this coincides with (9.2). More generally, there holds the following Theorem 9.2: Let {x t } 0<t T be a Brownian motion and let t := S 0 e xt+(µ 2 2 )t (9.26) S (µ) Let dw be the Wiener measure and d W be the equivalenartingale measure. Then the following equality (µ) t ) = E W (r) t,..., S (r) ) (9.27) holds for all payoffs H = t,..., S tm ). In particular, the theoretical fair value V 0 = e rt (µ) t ) = e rt (r) E W t,..., S (r) ) (9.28)

70 Chapter 9 does not depend on the (usually not predictable) drift parameter µ, but depends only on the volatility parameter and the interest rate level r. Proof: From the definition of p we have (t 0 := 0) (µ) t ) = Because of m (µ) t ) m Π t + j t j (x t + j t j ) 2 (tj t j ) e x 2(t j t j ) dx tj S (µ) t = S (µ) t (x t ) = S 0 e xt+(µ 2 = S 0 e = S (r) t 2 )t 2 (xt+ t)+(r 2 )t (x t + t) (9.29) the statement follows from the substitution of variables y tj = x tj + t j.