From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

Similar documents
In pursuing a strategy of monetary targeting, the central bank announces that it will

Lessons from the stabilization process in Argentina,

Francis Cairncross: Professor Friedman, in recent years, we have seen an acceleration in inflation all over the world. What has caused that?

Statement. Thank you, Senator Proxmire.

From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

Macroeconomic Issues and Policy. Stabilization Policy. Time Lags Regarding Monetary and Fiscal Policy

the debate concerning whether policymakers should try to stabilize the economy.

From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

Question 5 : Franco Modigliani's answer to Simon Kuznets's puzzle regarding long-term constancy of the average propensity to consume is that : the ave

made available a few days after the next regularly scheduled and the Board's Annual Report. The summary descriptions of

TRUE FACTS AND FALSE PERCEPTIONS ABOUT FEDERAL DEFICITS" Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer Rotary Club of Springfield, Missouri December 6, 1988

Implications of Fiscal Austerity for U.S. Monetary Policy

An Introduction to the Yield Curve and What it Means. Yield vs Maturity An Inverted Curve: January Percent (%)

Interest Rates during Economic Expansion

Lyle E. Gramley MEMBER, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM. Conrnunity Leaders in Seattle

EC 201 Lecture Notes 7 Page 1 of 1

THE NEW, NEW ECONOMICS AND MONETARY POLICY. Remarks Prepared by Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Are We There Yet? The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy. Remarks by

THE SHORT-RUN TRADEOFF BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT

The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand

GOVERNMENT DEFICITS, MONETARY POLICY, AND INFLATION Remarks by Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Canada s Economic Future: What Have We Learned from the 1990s?

MR. PRICE: Thank you. The Chairman is gone, but Vice Chairman. Papadimitriou, members of the Trade Deficit Commission,

FISCAL POLICY* Chapt er. Key Concepts

Implications of Low Inflation Rates for Monetary Policy

"FOREIGN" BEHAVIOR FOR THE U.S.? Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer Rotary Club of Paducah September 14, 1988

Credit Controls: Reinforcing Monetary Restraint

The Federal Reserve: Independence Gained, Independence Lost. Michael D Bordo Rutgers University

Beyond Estimation Market Outlook Q4 2017

DARRYL R. FRANCIS PRESIDENT OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS BEFORE THE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, HOUSING, AND URBAN AFFAIRS UNITED STATES SENATE

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

Digitized for FRASER Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

SAVING, INVESTMENT, AND THE FINANCIAL SYSTEM

Answers to Questions: Chapter 8

Koji Ishida: Japan s economy, price developments and monetary policy

The Future Performance of the Canadian Economy

Testimony before the Joint Economic Committee at the Hearing on Monetary Policy Going Forward: Why a Sound Dollar Boosts Growth and Employment

INCREASING THE RATE OF CAPITAL FORMATION (Investment Policy Report)

The End of the Business Cycle?

Module C. Monetary Policy: How Is It Conducted and How Does It Affect the Economy?

the U.S. balance of payments deficit showed substantial improvement after midyear.

MCCI ECONOMIC OUTLOOK. Novembre 2017

Objectives THE BUSINESS CYCLE CHAPTER

Normalizing Monetary Policy

Monetary Policymaking in Today s Environment: Finding Policy Space in a Low-Rate World

STAFF PAPERS In addition

Tools of Budget Analysis (Chapter 4 in Gruber s textbook) 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Notes Numbers in the text and tables may not add up to totals because of rounding. Unless otherwise indicated, years referred to in describing the bud

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND

INFLATION, JOBS, AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE*

A NEW MEASURE OF THE MONETARY "VELOCITY" (STOCK/FLOW) RATIO AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR MONETARY POLICY AND ECONOMIC FORECASTING

Macroeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools

Outline of Statement by. Arthur F. Burns. Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. before the. Committee on Banking and Currency

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND

THE JAPANESE ECONOMY AND THE AFTERMATH OF ITS UNUSUAL RECESSION SHIJURO OGATA. Occasional Paper No. 19

Report Documentation Page Form Approved OMB No Public reporting burden for the collection of information is estimated to average 1 hour per re

What Should the Fed Do?

Edward M Gramlich: Macroeconomic policy in recessions - and other times

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, November 2016 Quiz, Unit VI, Stabilization Policies

Gauging Current Conditions:

16-3: Monetary Policy. Notes

ECONOMY REPORT - CHINESE TAIPEI

The text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under the CC BY-NC-SA without attribution as requested by the works original creator or licensee

Haruhiko Kuroda: How to overcome deflation

I don't understand the argument that even though inflation is not accelerating, the world nevertheless suffers from "global excess liquidity":

ECONOMIC UPDATE. Rotary Club of Northern Guam. Bank of Guam. Presented to the. as a Value Added Service by

THE FED AND ECONOMY. Fixed Income Commentary

THE U.S. ECONOMY IN 1986

The New, New Economics And Monetary Policy

U.S. Fiscal Policy in the 1990s

MONETARY POLICY COMING OUT OF RECESSION. Anna J. Schwartz National Bureau of Economic Research

THE ECONOMY AND BANKING IN Remarks of. Philip E. Coldwell. Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. at the

The Recession: How Bad Will It Be?

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Unemployment after the Recession: A New Natural Rate? Murat Tasci and Saeed Zaman

Treasury and Federal Reserve Foreign Exchange Operations

DEFICITS AND DEBT Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

HOW CAN THE FED INFLUENCE INTEREST RATES AND SUSTAIN GROWTH? Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer President, Federal Reserve Bank of St.

Financial Economics. Runs Test

Ms Hessius comments on the inflation target and the state of the economy in Sweden

The Economy, Inflation, and Monetary Policy

Business Cycle Theory

PROSPECTS FOR THE UNITED STATES ECONOMY

Things you should know about inflation

Potential Output in Denmark

William C Dudley: A bit better, but very far from best US economic outlook and the challenges facing the Federal Reserve

STEPHEN NICKELL BANK OF ENGLAND MONETARY POLICY COMMITTEE. The Budget of 1981 was over the top

Economic Outlook 2002

INFLATION AND THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK By Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

The Real Estate Report Volume 41, Number 2 Fall 2017 GENERAL SUMMARY

Let me turn now to the main questions that you have raised.

Monetary Policies in a Diversifying Global Economy:

economist International Monetary Coordination Allan H. Meitzer and Jeremy P. Fand Coordination by Policy Rule

PRESENTATION BY PROF. E. TUMUSIIME-MUTEBILE, GOVERNOR, BANK OF UGANDA, TO THE NRM RETREAT, KYANKWANZI, JANUARY

REGULATION Q AND THE BEHAVIOR OF SAVINGS AND SMALL TIME DEPOSITS AT COMMERCIAL BANKS AND THE THRIFT INSTITUTIONS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE CASE AGAINST TRYING TO STABILIZE THE DOLLAR. Martin Feldatein. Working Paper No. 2838

How Is Global Trade Financed? (EA)

Seasonal Factors Affecting Bank Reserves

Part VIII: Short-Run Fluctuations and. 26. Short-Run Fluctuations 27. Countercyclical Macroeconomic Policy

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Transcription:

A Memorandum to the Fed by Milton Friedman Wall Street Journal, 30 January 1981 Reprinted from The Wall Street Journal 1981 Dow Jones & Company. All rights reserved. On Oct. 6, 1979, the Federal Reserve announced a change in the method used to conduct monetary policy to support the objective of containing growth in the monetary aggregates. Despite vigorous efforts by the Fed to implement the policy, monetary growth has varied over a wider range since Oct. 6, 1979, than in any period of comparable length for at least the last two decades. That fact is recognized by the Fed itself, by its defenders and by its critics. There is, however, much disagreement about, first, why monetary growth has varied so widely and, second, whether the Fed has the ability to achieve steady monetary growth in line with its targets over periods measured in weeks or months rather than quarters or years. Chairman Paul Volcker, in testimony to Congress, blamed last year s abnormal fluctuations in money supply and interest rates on a sharp second quarter recession followed by a stronger-thananticipated recovery, the temporary imposition of credit controls last spring, market uncertainty over the Fed s decision to let interest rates fluctuate more widely and irresponsible inflationary expectations. This explanation reminds me of the man on trial for murdering his parents who asked for mercy on the ground that he was an orphan. The sharp second-quarter recession very likely was produced, and certainly was intensified, by the Fed s own actions: first, a decline in M1-B at the annual rate of 5.1% from February to May the sharpest decline during any three-month period in at least the last two decades; second, the imposition of credit controls in March at the request, it is true, of President Carter but under the authority of the independent Fed. The stronger-than-anticipated recovery was sparked by a rise in M1-B at the annual rate of 15.9% from May to October the most rapid rise during any five-month period in at least the last two decades reinforced by the removal of credit controls. These were entirely the Fed s doing. By sharply intensifying the recession, the initial decline in money supply led the Fed to overreact in the opposite direction a pattern that has frequently occurred in the past. As to irresponsible inflationary expectations, what is irresponsible about such expectations in view of (1) the past record of inflation a roller coaster about a rising trend; (2) the past record of government monetary policy a similar roller coaster about a rising trend? The wide swings in interest rates also were not, in my opinion, a result of the Fed s decision to let interest rates fluctuate more widely but rather of the Fed s failure to match the change in its announced objectives with a comparable change in its operating procedures. Of this, more later. 1

Over the years, two major excuses have repeatedly been offered by the Fed and its defenders for erratic and inflationary monetary policies: first, large federal government deficits; second, unpredictable changes in the demand for money. The first excuse has merit on a political level, none whatsoever on a technical level. The same political forces that have fostered rising deficits pressures to increase government spending without legislating additional taxes and to react promptly to offset any increases in unemployment have also affected the Federal Reserve and induced it to become an erratic engine of inflation. On the technical level, however, there is no necessary connection between deficits and monetary growth. To illustrate: As a percentage of GNP, deficits in the U.S. have varied from a low of 0.4% for the fiscal year ended June 30, 1974, to a high of 4.6% for the year to June 30, 1976. But growth in M1-B was almost the same in the two years: 4.3% from July 1973 to July 1974; 4.7% from July 1975 to July 1976. For the year ended Sept. 30, 1979, the deficit was 1.8% of GNP, yet M1-B grew 7.8% from October 1978 to October 1979. To illustrate in a different way: Deficits have been running about 6% of gross national product in Japan, or roughly three times ours, and about 2% in Germany, or the same as ours. Yet both countries have a better recent record than we do of achieving monetary growth targets and holding down inflation. In short, there is no technical reason why the Fed must monetize deficits. Insofar as it does so, it is because of political pressures to hold down interest rates or to stimulate the economy. The second excuse, alleged instability in the demand for money, involves a serious intellectual confusion between money and credit. Most credit is not money, by any definition of money; much money is not credit (as is clearest with a commodity standard such as gold). Federal Reserve notes used to be described as promises to pay. They are clearly not that today. They are simply flat, not in any meaningful sense a credit instrument, and that is equally true of deposits at Federal Reserve Banks. Interest rates are the price of credit, not the price of money. The price of money is the quantity of goods and services that will buy a piece of money (the reciprocal of the price level). Fluctuations in interest rates reflect instability in the demand for credit rather than for money properly defined, though interest rate changes may indirectly affect the quantity of money demanded. The so-called money market is really a credit market. Yet the excuse in terms of instability in the demand for credit does have some validity because and only because the Fed continues to try to control the money supply through interest rates, in particular the federal funds rate. That is neither the only nor the best way to control the money supply. The key defect in trying to control the money supply by pegging the federal funds rate is that mistakes are cumulative and self-reinforcing, and so lead to the kind of wide swings in monetary aggregates that we have increasingly experienced in recent years. If the Fed picks too low a federal funds rate, it has to add excessively to the supply of federal funds, that is, the monetary base (currency plus Federal Reserve deposits), in order to maintain that rate. As the money supply responds, monetary expansion tends to stimulate spending and the 2

demand for loans and to increase inflationary expectations. The result, after an interval, is upward pressure on market interest rates. To peg the federal funds rate at the initial level, the Fed must add more and more to the base, increasing still further the upward pressure on interest rates. Similarly, if the Fed picks too high a funds rate, it must drain an excessive amount from the base, discouraging spending, decreasing demand for loans and ultimately adding to downward pressure on interest rates. The short-term effect of higher monetary growth is to lower interest rates and of lower monetary growth is to raise interest rates. But the longer-term effects are in the opposite direction. These opposite effects mean that in using the federal funds rate as its operating target, the Fed is always balancing on a knife-edge. That is why this policy has produced such wide swings in both interest rates and monetary growth. The Fed unquestionably has the power to peg the federal funds rate within very narrow limits over short periods but only by surrendering control of the base in the short run, and of the interest rate itself in the longer run. It can regain control only by changing the pegged rate which it sooner or later does. But it takes time to recognize a mistake and further time to overcome bureaucratic inertia, so the ultimate changes in the pegged rate have to be sizable and are typically overdone. Last year provides an almost textbook example. The money supply peaked in mid-february 1980, when the funds rate was about 15%. But the Fed did not recognize promptly what was happening and kept pushing the funds rate up to over 19% by early April, which is just when the money supply started collapsing. The money supply reached its trough at the end of April, at which point the federal funds rate was again about 15%. Again, the Fed was late and kept pushing the funds rate down for two more months, to less than 9% by late July. By that time the money supply had exploded, rising at an annual rate of over 13% from the end of April to the end of July. The Fed then belatedly started pushing the federal funds rate up. The money supply peaked in mid-november when the funds rate was again about 15%. Again the Fed was late in recognizing the change and kept pushing the funds rate up to nearly 20% in mid-december and again in January. It looks as if the springtime pattern is being repeated. The money supply declined from mid-november to the end of December, at an annual rate of 15%. If history continues to repeat, we shall again have a precipitous drop in money and the economy followed by an inflationary overreaction. Had money supply growth been steadier during the year, interest rates would have been steadier as well and conversely. Note that a 15% interest rate in 1980 corresponded to a real interest rate, corrected for inflation, of about 3%, in line with long-run experience. These wide swings are unnecessary. An alternative procedure of controlling the base directly and letting the market determine interest rates could produce steady and predictable monetary growth and at the same time avoid wide swings in interest rates. The base consists of the Fed s own liabilities, on which it has accurate day-to-day figures. The Fed can add to its liabilities by purchasing government securities or making loans to banks; it can 3

subtract from its liabilities by selling securities or reducing lending. The only limitations to its ability to determine how much to add or subtract from the base are self-imposed: first, its policy of pegging the federal funds rate; second, its decision in 1968 to base reserve requirements on deposits two weeks earlier which means that the total reserves for the current week are predetermined, so that the only practical option the Fed has is whether to supply them through open-market operations or through the discount window. Eliminate these obstacles and the Fed can exercise highly precise and prompt control over the size of the base. Control of the monetary base will not produce rigid and precise control of a monetary aggregate such as M1-B. The link between the base and M1-B has elements of looseness deriving from changes in the public s desired ratio of currency to deposits, the banks management of their liabilities, which affects required reserves, and the banks desired ratio of excess reserves to deposits. Nevertheless, controlling the supply of money through the monetary base avoids the chief technical defect of trying to control the demand for money through the federal funds rate. Mistakes in controlling the base are not cumulative and self-reinforcing. If the Fed increases the base by, say 6%, when 7% would have been the amount required to achieve its target growth rate in M1-B, the error does not cumulate. The growth in M1-B simply falls short of its target by one percentage point, nothing more. Moreover, such errors are likely to be random from month to month and hence to average out, even if not corrected, whereas errors in the federal funds rate tend to get larger until corrected, and the correction itself is generally too little at first and then too much. Just as the Fed can control the federal funds rate only by surrendering control over the base, so it can control the base only by surrendering control over the federal funds rate or any other interest rate. If it did so, and thereby produced steadier growth in the monetary aggregates, interest rates might be more volatile over intervals of days or weeks. Almost certainly, however, interest rates would be far less volatile over periods of months and years, and possibly even weeks. The belief that the Fed can or does control interest rates is a myth that dies hard. But surely if it could, the prime rate would never have hit 21.5%. These are the specific steps that I believe the Fed should take to improve its control of the money supply and to become a major source of stability in economic policy instead of the unguided missile it has so often been: Announce that it will no longer specify a target range for the federal funds rate (or any other interest rate). Specify in advance the amount it proposes to add to, or subtract from, the monetary base week by week over a substantial future period. It should determine these target amounts by estimating as best it can the additions or subtractions necessary to achieve a desired target for a single selected monetary aggregate. (It matters far less whether that aggregate is M1-A or M1-B or M-2 or M-n than that a single aggregate be chosen.) Numerous studies have demonstrated that the necessary additions or subtractions to the base can be calculated fairly accurately. 4

To improve the link between the monetary base and the selected monetary aggregate, the Fed should specify that required reserves are to be calculated from contemporaneous deposits, not from deposits two weeks earlier as at present. There is essential unanimity among experts, including most of those employed by the Fed, that the introduction of lagged reserve accounting in 1968 has made monetary control more difficult with little if any compensating advantage. Only bureaucratic operating problems have prevented a correction of this mistake. The Fed announced its intention to make this change some months ago, but has repeatedly postponed the effective date. To avoid indirectly pegging the federal funds rate, the Fed should convert the discount rate (the rate at which it lends to banks) to a penalty rate and link it to a market rate so that it moves automatically and gradually, not as now at discrete intervals, generally too late. For example, it might set the discount rate each week at two percentage points above the average rate on threemonth Treasury bills during the prior week. In cooperation with other responsible agencies, the Fed should seek to accelerate the elimination of Regulation Q controls on interest rates, as already provided for by current law. I have said nothing about the precise monetary growth targets the Fed should specify because that is not where the problem is. The Fed has known what monetary growth it should aim for. But it has been reluctant to adopt procedures that would enable it to achieve those goals. Improvement in Federal Reserve performance would not by itself enable the Reagan administration to achieve its goals of reduced inflation and healthier economic growth. But failure of the Fed to improve its performance could frustrate achievement of those goals. And, fortunately or unfortunately, moral suasion is the only instrument the new President has to induce the Fed to make changes in its procedures that are so badly needed and so long overdue. Reprinted in Milton Friedman, Bright Promises, Dismal Performance, pp. 241-249. Edited by William R. Allen. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1983. 10/10/12 5