Feel No Pain: Why a Deficit In Times of High Unemployment Is Not a Burden

Similar documents
CBO Projects More Severe Downturn

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

Data Brief. Dangerous Trends: The Growth of Debt in the U.S. Economy

Seven Key Facts About Social Security and the Federal Budget

Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain

Economic Theories & Debt Driven Realities

Econ 102 Exam 2 Name ID Section Number

Expansions (periods of. positive economic growth)

OCR Economics A-level

Economy Check-In: Post 2008 Crisis Market Update Special Report

Getting Mexico to Grow With NAFTA: The World Bank's Analysis. October 13, 2004

Briefing Paper. Business Week Restates the Nineties. By Dean Baker. April 22, 2002

The Urgent Need for Job Creation

Testimony of Dean Baker. Before the Subcommittee on TARP and Financial Resources of the House Committee on Oversight and Government Reform

Practice Problems 30-32

b. Financial innovation and/or financial liberalization (the elimination of restrictions on financial markets) can cause financial firms to go on a

The U.S. Economy: An Optimistic Outlook, But With Some Important Risks

The Ryan Medicare Plan: Winners and Losers

Chapter 25 Fiscal Policy Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Lecture 7. Unemployment and Fiscal Policy

Economy In Crisis: How Global Financial Crisis Affects India & The World?

The Taylor Rule: A benchmark for monetary policy?

Usable Productivity Growth in the United States

THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND THE GREAT RECESSION

Short-Term Gain for Long-Term Pain: The Real Story of Rubinomics

The Housing Crash Recession and the Case for a Third Stimulus

CEPR CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH

2012 Economic Outlook. Marney Cox Chief Economist San Diego Association of Governments April 11, 2012

Defining the problem: the difference between current deficit and long-term deficits

THE ROLE OF DEBT IN FARMLAND OWNERSHIP

Module 19 Equilibrium in the Aggregate Demand Aggregate Supply Model

The U.S. Current Account Balance and the Business Cycle

Part VIII: Short-Run Fluctuations and. 26. Short-Run Fluctuations 27. Countercyclical Macroeconomic Policy

2012 Economic Outlook. Marney Cox Chief Economist San Diego Association of Governments December 15, 2011

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

What Should the Fed Do?

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 13. Fiscal Policy

Sub-3% GDP Growth: A Lost Decade For The US Economy

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand

Chapter 10. Fiscal Policy. Macroeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools NINTH EDITION

Analysis of CBO s Budget Outlook: Fiscal Years

Discussion on The Great Recession: What Recovery?

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

Gauging Current Conditions: The Economic Outlook and Its Impact on Workers Compensation

Macroeconomics Mankiw 6th Edition

The Conduct of Monetary Policy

The U.S. Economy After the Great Recession: America s Deleveraging and Recovery Experience

MACROECONOMICS 201 (Fall 2018) NOTES 9

THE INFLUENCE OF MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY ON AGGREGATE DEMAND

Implications of Fiscal Austerity for U.S. Monetary Policy

Should Obama withdraw the Stimulus Package NOW?

Macroeconomic Issues and Policy. Stabilization Policy. Time Lags Regarding Monetary and Fiscal Policy

Causes of The Great Depression

The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand P R I N C I P L E S O F. N. Gregory Mankiw. Introduction

10.2 Recent Shocks to the Macroeconomy Introduction. Housing Prices. Chapter 10 The Great Recession: A First Look

ASSESSING THE RISK OF A DOUBLE-DIP RECESSION: KEY INDICATORS TO MONITOR

Are we on the road to recovery?

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 13. Fiscal Policy

Perspectives on the U.S. Economy

Practical Problems with Discretionary Fiscal Policy

Maneuvering Past Stagflation: Prospects for the U.S. Economy In

In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions

Economic Outlook, January 2016 Jeffrey M. Lacker President, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

On Abenomics and the Japanese Economy. Motoshige Itoh Member, Council on Economic and Fiscal Policy and Professor, University of Tokyo

Macroeconomics Sixth Edition

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, October 2016

2013 San Diego Economic Outlook. Marney Cox Chief Economist San Diego Association of Governments November 15, 2012

Chapter 16. MODERN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS Third Edition

cepr Briefing Paper Paying the Bills in Brazil: Does the IMF s Math Add Up? CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH By Mark Weisbrot and Dean Baker 1

COMMENTARY NUMBER 462 June Trade Balance, Consumer Credit. August 9, Bernanke Bemoans GDP Not Reflecting Common Experience

cepr Analysis of the Upcoming Release of 2003 Data on Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Data Brief Paper Heather Boushey 1 August 2004

An Assessment of the President s Proposal to Stimulate the Economy and Create Jobs. John B. Taylor *

What the National Financial Crisis means for Ohio s Revenues in FY2009, FY2010 and FY2011. Ohio Office of Budget & Management December 1, 2008

Objectives for Chapter 24: Monetarism (Continued) Chapter 24: The Basic Theory of Monetarism (Continued) (latest revision October 2004)

Deflation? Yes. Deflationary spiral? No.

The influence of Monetary And Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand

Don t Raise the Federal Debt Ceiling, Torpedo the U.S. Housing Market

ECN 106 Macroeconomics 1. Lecture 10

"The Continuing Problem of China's Currency Management Policy"

What s the Most Potent Way to Stimulate the Economy?

Economic Policy in the Crisis. Lars Calmfors Jönköping International Business School, 2 November 2009

Why Policymakers Can t Rely On Inflation Data. Dean Croushore, University of Richmond

Answers to Questions: Chapter 8

Aggregate Demand II: Applying the IS- LM Model

BALANCING THE FEDERAL BUDGET: ECONOMIC RATIONALE AND ISSUES

North American Steel Industry Recent Market Developments, Future Prospects and Key Challenges

The Case for Fiscal Policy to Forestall Economic Slowdown

Chart Book: Deficit Reduction, the Economy, And the Budget Negotiations By Sharon Parrott, Richard Kogan, Krista Ruffini, and William Chen

The Productivity to Paycheck Gap: What the Data Show

1 of 24. Modern Macroeconomics: From the Short Run to the Long Run. 2 of 24. They could not have differed more sharply on economic theory and policy.

Chapter 12 Aggregate Demand II: Applying the IS -LM Model

CBPP S UPDATED LONG-TERM FISCAL DEFICIT AND DEBT PROJECTIONS

Global financial crisis and the Great Recession

Modest Economic Growth and Falling GDP Gap

Global Financial Crisis and China s Countermeasures

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

Global Equities PUTTING RECENT MARKET VOLATILITY IN PERSPECTIVE

CORRECTING FIVE MYTHS ABOUT THE STIMULUS BILL By James R. Horney, Nicholas Johnson, and Lawrence J. Haas

Name: Days/Times Class Meets: Today s Date:

Transcription:

Issue Brief September 2010 Feel No Pain: Why a Deficit In Times of High Unemployment Is Not a Burden BY DEAN BAKER* With the economy suffering from near double-digit unemployment, public debate is dominated by concerns over the budget deficit and national debt. This discussion is unfortunate both because there is no reason for people to be concerned about the deficit at present, and more importantly, because it discourages action on the unemployment crisis that is devastating the country. The basic outlines of the current situation are fairly simple. The economy was operating at near full employment levels of output in 2007, before the collapse of the housing bubble threw the economy into the most severe recession since the Great Depression. When the bubble burst, construction plummeted as builders realized that there would be no demand for the houses they were building. There was also a bubble in non-residential real estate leading to a building boom in retail and office space, as well as hotels. Non-residential construction also collapsed in response to this overbuilding. The combined falloff in annual residential and non-residential construction spending has been close to $600 billion. The collapse of the housing bubble also sent consumption plummeting. The bubble had generated more than $8 trillion of additional housing equity. Homeowners spent against the equity created by the housing bubble just as they would against their other housing equity, since they did not know the equity came from a bubble. Economists usually estimate the size of the housing wealth effect as 5-7 percent, meaning that the $8 trillion in bubblegenerated equity would have led to $400 billion to $560 billion a year in annual consumption. Thus far, the bubble is close to two-thirds deflated, meaning that the value of housing has fallen by close to $6 trillion. This would imply a drop in annual consumption of between $300 billion and $420 billion. Center for Economic and Policy Research 1611 Connecticut Ave, NW Suite 400 Washington, DC 20009 tel: 202-293-5380 fax: 202-588-1356 www.cepr.net The decline in consumption was amplified by the plunge in the stock market, which lost more than $6 trillion in wealth (even after its bounceback from 2009 lows) as the economy plunged into recession. With a stock wealth effect of 3-4 percent, this translates into a drop in annual consumption demand of between $180 billion and $240 billion. *Dean Baker is an economist and Co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research in Washington, D.C.

CEPR Feel No Pain: Why a Deficit In Times of High Unemployment Is Not a Burden 2 The combined impact of the drop in house prices to date and the loss of stock wealth should be a falloff in annual consumption of between $480 billion and $660 billion. The mid-point of this range would imply a drop in annual consumption of $570 billion. Adding this to the $600 billion drop in construction spending implies a falloff in annual demand of $1,170 billion. This dropoff is shown in Figure 1, which shows the components of GDP before and after the collapse of the housing bubble. (Net exports are excluded for simplicity.) FIGURE 1 Components of GDP, before and after the Collapse of the Housing Bubble 16,000 14,000 12,000 Construction billions of dollars 10,000 8,000 6,000 Investment 4,000 2,000 Consumption 0 Pre-Crash Post-Crash As can be seen, GDP is much lower post-crash since there is nothing to replace the demand lost as a result of the collapse of the housing bubble. In response to a modest downturn, it is possible for the Federal Reserve Board to lower interest rates, which in turn boosts investment and consumption, and also housing construction. In this downturn, the Fed has lowered interest rates as far as it can all the way to zero but it has had relatively little effect. The reason that this drop in rates has had a limited impact is that it cannot make up for the huge amount of lost housing equity. Also, low interest rates are not likely to spur much construction in an economy where there is already a glut of housing, retail stores, office space, and hotels. The drop in interest rates has benefited the economy, but not nearly enough to offset the huge loss in demand from the collapse of the housing bubble. This is the reason that stimulus is needed. The government can bring the economy closer to full capacity by spending money directly. For example, it can spend more on services like education, health care, or police and fire protection or on

CEPR Feel No Pain: Why a Deficit In Times of High Unemployment Is Not a Burden 3 investment in areas like infrastructure or research and development. The government can also boost consumption by giving tax breaks to those who are most likely to spend the money. Through a combination of additional government spending and tax breaks the government can bring the economy back to a full employment level of output. This is shown in Figure 2, which assumes that the gap created by the collapse of the housing bubble (in construction and consumption) is closed with equal amounts of spending increases and consumption generated by tax cuts. FIGURE 2 Filling the GDP Gap 800 600 400 billions of dollars 200 0-200 -400-600 -800 Consumption Construction Additional Stimulus Additional Consumption from Stimulus Figure 3 then updates the post-crash levels shown in Figure 1 to demonstrate the adjustments necessary to get the economy to a level of demand closer to full employment. This effectively assumes that the additional spending, financed through borrowing, has no negative effects on the other components of GDP. In a more typical economic environment, this would be an unreasonable assumption. However, in the extraordinarily deep downturn that the economy is currently experiencing, this is likely to be a reasonable approximation of reality. Increased government borrowing will have little effect on interest rates, and therefore it will not crowd out other components of GDP.

CEPR Feel No Pain: Why a Deficit In Times of High Unemployment Is Not a Burden 4 FIGURE 3 Effects of Additional Spending and Tax Breaks on GDP 16,000 14,000 Construction 12,000 Investment billions of dollars 10,000 8,000 6,000 4,000 2,000 Additional Stimulus Additional Consumption from Stimulus Consumption 0 Pre-C rash Post-Crash While many, if not most, economists would agree with this basic picture, the question raised by those concerned about the debt is that this additional borrowing will impose a substantial interest burden on the United States in future years. Given the extraordinarily low interest rates in the market at present, this concern does not seem terribly realistic. For example, if the United States government borrowed $4 trillion in 30-year bonds at a 3.7 percent interest rate (approximately the current level), then it would imply an annual interest burden of $148 billion. This is less than 0.7 percent of projected GDP for 2020, which is hardly an unmanageable amount. However, it is possible to ensure that the government does not bear even this burden of addition interest expenses. Suppose the Federal Reserve Board were to buy and hold the additional bonds issued to finance a larger stimulus package. For example, suppose the government borrowed an additional $800 billion (beyond what is currently projected) in both fiscal years 2011 and 2012 to pay for more stimulus. The Fed could simply buy up these bonds by issuing more reserves. There is little need to fear that this injection of more reserves into the banking system would lead to inflation in the current situation, since the economy has an enormous amount of unemployed labor and idle resources. Furthermore, it would be beneficial to the economy if the Fed s actions did lead to somewhat more inflation. A higher rate of inflation would reduce the real interest rate, making firms more willing to invest. If inflation rose to a 3.0-4.0 percent range, then it would mean that firms could expect to sell products they produce in 4-5 years at prices that are far higher than current prices. (A 4 percent inflation rate implies that prices will be 20 percent higher in 5 years, before taking into account

CEPR Feel No Pain: Why a Deficit In Times of High Unemployment Is Not a Burden 5 compounding.) If firms know that they will be able to sell their output at much higher prices in the near future, then it will be far more profitable to invest today. In the same vein, a higher rate of inflation will reduce debt burdens. If wages rise in step with inflation, and inflation averages 4.0 percent over the next 5 years, then wages will be approximately 20 percent higher 5 years from now. This will reduce the burden of mortgages or other debts where the size of the monthly payment remains fixed. In addition, if house prices rise in step with inflation, then a higher rate of inflation will translate into additional home equity (as the value of homes rises, the size of mortgages will remain unchanged). For these reasons, any inflation that resulted from the Fed s decision to buy large amounts of debt at present would be a plus for the economy rather than something to be feared. If inflation threatened to get out of control, then it would be a serious problem, but there is little possibility that this could happen given the depth of the downturn. Furthermore, inflation does not just begin skyrocketing overnight in developed economies. Inflation increases gradually in response to excess demand. If there was evidence that tight labor markets or bottlenecks in production were creating inflationary pressures, then the Fed would have plenty of time to reverse course and adopt policies to slow the economy. In short, the decision to buy large amounts of debt at present holds little risk. Of course the Fed has already been buying large amounts of debt, although most of its purchases have been of mortgage-backed securities, not government debt. As a result of its large holding of debt, the Congressional Budget Office projects that the Fed will rebate $77 billion to the Treasury in 2010. 1 This amount is more than 37 percent of the government s current net interest burden. The Fed s decision to buy large amounts of debt at present is largely non-controversial, however the generally held view is that the Fed will sell this debt back to the public over the next few years. This means that the government debt currently being issued, as well as an increase in the debt needed to finance additional stimulus, will ultimately be in the hands of private investors. At that point, the interest burden on this debt will pose a burden on the government, even if it is a relatively manageable one. However, there is a simple alternative. The Fed can simply commit itself to hold government debt indefinitely. This way the interest on the bonds issued by the government will continue to go to the Fed and then be rebated back to the Treasury. In this scenario, there is no future interest burden on the government whatsoever created by its current stimulus spending. There is a concern that the additional reserves that the Fed has put into the system to buy government debt will create inflation at a future point when the economy is approaching full employment. However, the Fed possesses the same tools to fight inflation in this context as it would otherwise. It can target a higher federal funds rate to slow the economy and it can also raise the amount of required reserves that banks must hold with the Fed, although it would want to make any increases in reserves gradual, and ideally scheduled long in advance, in order to avoid disrupting the financial system. 1 Congressional Budget Office. 2010. Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2011-2020. Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office, Table 4-8.

CEPR Feel No Pain: Why a Deficit In Times of High Unemployment Is Not a Burden 6 While the effort to balance the risks from inflation with the need to sustain growth and high employment may pose problems when the economy recovers, this is always true. If the Fed were to finance a substantial stimulus package by buying and holding debt, this problem would not be qualitatively different than the problem the Fed has faced in other recoveries. If the idea of the Federal Reserve just holding the debt sounds like a free lunch, it should, because it is. We are seeing mass unemployment right now for a simple reason insufficient demand. The problem is not the economy s lack of ability to produce more output, uncertainty of business owners, or a lack of access to credit. The problem is that there is not enough demand for the output that the economy could produce. Before the downturn, this demand was generated in large part by $8 trillion in housing wealth that turned out to be illusory. While the source of the demand was illusory, the additional goods and services that the economy was producing before the recession were real. The problem that we face right now is simply finding another way to generate the same level of demand. This is fundamentally a political problem, not an economic problem. We simply need a way to prompt additional spending from any source whatsoever. If the housing bubble re-inflated, so that people again believed they had an additional $8 trillion in equity, then we would see enough spending to bring the economy back to full employment. This is not likely to happen and would not be sustainable even if it did. (People would build more homes, leading to enough over-supply to crash the bubble, again.) However, it certainly makes no sense for policymakers to be more worried about demand stimulated by the government than demand stimulated by housing bubble wealth. If we can just get policymakers to focus on the economy s real problems, it will be possible to solve them.