The Economic Program. June 2014

Similar documents
A Guide to Statistics on Historical Trends in Income Inequality

Estimating Inequality with Tax Data: The Problem of Pass-Through Income

Fiscal Fact. Reversal of the Trend: Income Inequality Now Lower than It Was under Clinton. Introduction. By William McBride

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner

Response by Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez to: The Top 1%... of What? By ALAN REYNOLDS

California has one of the largest economies in the world and is home to incredible prosperity,

Economic Security Programs Cut Poverty Nearly in Half Over Last 50 Years, New Data Show

Health Insurance Data

Real Median Family Income is Falling. Family incomes have stagnated since the mid-1980s. Income in 2012 ($51,017) is lower than in 1989 ($51,681).

Federal Minimum Wage, Tax-Transfer Earnings Supplements, and Poverty

MORE THAN HALF OF BLACK AND HISPANIC FAMILIES WOULD NOT BENEFIT FROM BUSH TAX PLAN. by Isaac Shapiro, Allen Dupree and James Sly

Census Data Show Robust Progress Across the Board in 2016 in Income, Poverty, and Health Coverage

ARE TAXES TOO CONCENTRATED AT THE TOP? Rapidly Rising Incomes at the Top Lie Behind Increase in Share of Taxes Paid By High-Income Taxpayers

[ Tax Policy and Boomer Retirement Saving Behaviors ] How Changes in Tax Policy Will Impact Middle-Income Boomers

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t

PUBLIC BENEFITS: EASING POVERTY AND ENSURING MEDICAL COVERAGE By Arloc Sherman

SMALLER DEFICIT ESTIMATE NO SURPRISE New OMB Estimates Do Not Support Claims About Tax Cuts By James Horney

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL INEQUALITY DYNAMICS: NEW FINDINGS FROM WID.WORLD

2009 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

Spain:'Estimates'of'Top'Income'Shares' ,' and'revision'for' ' ' ' Facundo(Alvaredo( and(luis(estévez(bauluz( ( ( September(2014' (

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t

Graduate Public Finance

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Over the last 40 years, the U.S. federal tax system has undergone three

Historical Effective Tax Rates, Preliminary Edition

Poverty & The 2016 Election Joel Schumacher

cepr Analysis of the Upcoming Release of 2003 Data on Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Data Brief Paper Heather Boushey 1 August 2004

ALLOWING HIGH-INCOME TAX CUTS TO EXPIRE ON SCHEDULE WOULD BE SOUND ECONOMIC AND FISCAL POLICY By Chuck Marr

Child poverty in rural America

Working paper series. Simplified Distributional National Accounts. Thomas Piketty Emmanuel Saez Gabriel Zucman. January 2019

Law and Economic Justice

Would the Senate Democrats proposed excise tax on highcost employer-paid health insurance benefits be progressive?

SPECIAL REPORT. TD Economics ECONOMIC GROWTH AFTER RECOVERY: QUANTIFYING THE NEW NORMAL

2007 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

Federal Minimum Wage, Tax-Transfer Earnings Supplements, and Poverty, 2016 Update: In Brief

Income Progress across the American Income Distribution,

CBO MEMORANDUM ESTIMATES OF FEDERAL TAX LIABILITIES FOR INDIVIDUALS AND FAMILIES BY INCOME CATEGORY AND FAMILY TYPE FOR 1995 AND 1999.

Two Americas: One Rich, One Poor? Understanding Income Inequality in the United States

Distributional National Accounts DINA

Summary of Latest Federal Income Tax Data

A $7.25 MINIMUM WAGE WOULD BE A USEFUL STEP IN HELPING WORKING FAMILIES ESCAPE POVERTY by Jason Furman and Sharon Parrott

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2017 preliminary estimates)

Tax Foundation s Average Far More Than What Most Americans Pay in Federal Taxes FIGURE 1: April 2, 2012

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

Why SNAP Matters * January 25, Food Insecurity, Poverty and the SNAP s place in the U.S. Social Safety Net

2011 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

Income and Poverty Among Older Americans in 2008

Increasing the EITC Will Boost New Jersey s Workers and Their Families

Issues 2012 MEASURED INEQUALITY: FALLACIES AND OVERSTATEMENTS. No. 10 April 2012

TOP INCOMES IN THE UNITED STATES AND CANADA OVER THE TWENTIETH CENTURY

Introduction to Taxes and Transfers: Income Distribution, Poverty, Taxes and Transfers. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

How Progressive is the U.S. Federal Tax System? A Historical and International Perspective

How Closely Do Top Income Shares Track Other Measures of Inequality? Andrew Leigh * Abstract

ec nfip Economists for Inclusive Prosperity

Why the Next US Recession Could Be Worse Than the Last

Federal Taxation of Earnings versus Investment Income in 2004

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract

Income and Wealth Concentration in Switzerland over the 20 th Century

Trump s Tax Scam: What can we expect from the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act and how can we resist it? by Peter Bohmer February 23, 2018

The Fair Tax Benefits Seniors

WikiLeaks Document Release

Ireland's Income Distribution

Aging Seminar Series:

The Material Well-Being of the Poor and the Middle Class since 1980

Many studies have documented the long term trend of. Income Mobility in the United States: New Evidence from Income Tax Data. Forum on Income Mobility

Topic 11: Measuring Inequality and Poverty

New House Republican Tax Proposal Fails Fiscal Responsibility Test, While Favoring the Wealthiest

CRS Report for Congress

Global economic inequality: New evidence from the World Inequality Report

Prospects for the Social Safety Net for Future Low Income Seniors

The Elephant Curve of Global Inequality and Growth *

By eliminating jobs and/or reducing employment growth,

Summary An issue in the development of the new health care reform plan is the effect on small business. One concern is the effect of a pay or play man

Report :: Upside Down & Backwards: Taxes in New Jersey by Jon Shure. January 2003

Testimony before the Equal Employment Opportunity Commission. Heather Boushey, Senior Economist, Center for American Progress Action Fund

Distributional National Accounts: Methods and Estimates for the United States

State Budget Update: What s Next for Illinois?

Fiscal Challenges for State and Federal Governments

Working paper series. Distributional national accounts: Methods and estimates for the United States. Thomas Piketty Emmanuel Saez Gabriel Zucman

2013 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

Health Insurance Coverage in 2013: Gains in Public Coverage Continue to Offset Loss of Private Insurance

Tools of Budget Analysis (Chapter 4 in Gruber s textbook) 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Longman

Analysis of CBO s Budget Outlook: Fiscal Years

Health-Related Revenue Provisions in the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (ACA)

GOVERNMENT POLICIES AND POPULARITY: HONG KONG CASH HANDOUT

Recommendations for the Special Joint Committee on Deficit Reduction

Universal Savings Account Proposal in New Republican Tax Bill Is Ill-Conceived

Room Attendant Training Program

Program on Retirement Policy Number 1, February 2011

The Redistributive State: The Allocation of Government Benefits, Services, and Taxes in the United States

The 2008 Statistics on Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage by Gary Burtless THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION

TRENDS AND ISSUES. Do People Save Enough for Retirement?

A Fair Way to Limit Tax Deductions

Employer Responsibility in Health Care Reform:

Obamacare Tax Subsidies: Bigger Deficit, Fewer Taxpayers, Damaged Economy

Testimony of M. Cindy Hounsell, President Women s Institute for a Secure Retirement

A Condensed Review of New Taxes Coming Your Way

At the end of Class 20, you will be able to answer the following:

Transcription:

The Economic Program TO: Interested Parties FROM: Alicia Mazzara, Policy Advisor for the Economic Program; and Jim Kessler, Vice President for Policy RE: Three Ways of Looking At Income Inequality June 2014 The President has turned a much needed eye to income inequality and the growing share of income accumulated by the top 1%. The government plays a key role in ensuring that the American economy works for everyone, and Democrats are rightly focused on building a post-recession agenda that addresses problems like low upward mobility among the poor and the fact that a middle class job no longer supports a middle class life. In order to respond most effectively to rising income inequality in America, it is useful for policymakers to understand how economists define the first part of that term: income. In this primer, we look at three commonly used but very different measures of income and show how each one impacts the share of total income captured by the top 1%. * All three measures show that inequality is on the rise, but how one defines income significantly affects both the level of income inequality and, most importantly, the actions policymakers can and should take to reduce it. Measure #1: Market Income Market income = money earned through work and investments before taxes What is considered income? Income before taxes and government transfers is often referred to as market income. This measure is derived from gross income, a term used by the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) to record all sources of income on an individual s tax return before deductions. 1 Think of it as what each person earns from their jobs, businesses, private pensions, and investments. What is not considered income? Income from government sources, such as Social Security and unemployment insurance, would not be counted under this definition. Additionally, this measurement does not include employer-provided health care or retirement benefits. Under this definition, a person earning $50,000 a year with employer-provided healthcare and a defined-benefit pension plan would have the same income as a person earning $50,000 a year with no health or retirement benefits. Likewise, a retired couple receiving $30,000 a year in Social Security payments would not have that money counted toward their market income. * We refer to these as measures as market income, market income and benefits, and after tax income. Other authors may use different terminology to describe these concepts.

Market income includes but is not limited to income from an individual or married couple s: wages and salary, including bonuses; realized capital gains; income from operating a business; pensions and annuities; and interest and dividends. 2 Where does the data come from? The IRS publishes a large dataset of 2 anonymized income tax returns. Economists have been mining this rich trove of data for years, but Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez are perhaps most famous for using tax returns to study income inequality in the U.S. and abroad. Piketty and Saez use a market definition of income. 3 Along with other researchers, they have compiled the World Top Incomes Database which contains information on how much income the top 1% of earners makes. The statistics derived from this database are probably the most oft-cited by policymakers and the media. What are the strengths and weaknesses of this data? Unlike other data sources, the IRS has detailed income information on very high earners. Since much of the rise in income has been among the top 1%, the IRS data is crucial to understanding recent trends in income inequality. IRS data is also available dating back to 1913, allowing researchers to track long-term trends. Moreover, tax returns are usually more accurate than surveys that ask people to report their income from memory. 4 However, the IRS data does not include information on people who make too little money to file taxes. As a result, economists must estimate incomes for low-income persons if they are to calculate certain measures of income inequality. Tax returns may also underestimate incomes as some people engage in tax evasion or underreporting. Additionally, the IRS data does not include any capital gains income that is exempt from taxation, such as the sale of most homes. How does this measure affect income inequality? Under this measurement, the top 1% of all earners captured 20% of all U.S. income in 2010 (the most recent year available for all three measures). 5 Measure #2: Market Income and Benefits Market income and benefits = market income + employer-provided benefits + government transfers What is considered income? The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) uses this metric of income. It builds on Measure #1 (market income) by adding two more sources of income to the equation: government transfers and certain employerprovided benefits. This includes things like health insurance, 401K contributions, Third Way Memo 2

Social Security, and means-tested benefits like food stamps and public housing assistance. In other words, this measurement includes adjustments made by public policy regarding safety net benefits, as well as employer actions on non-wage benefits. Readers familiar with the differences between the official and supplemental poverty measure will likely recognize similarities to these income concepts. This measure of income differs in one other important way from Piketty and Saez s measure of market income. The CBO measures market income and benefits using households instead of tax filing units. * Households may consist of multiple tax filers and consequently tend to have higher incomes than tax filing units. 6 Even so, a family of three making $90,000 arguably has less spending power as a single adult earning the equivalent salary. To better reflect the true spending power of households over time, the CBO adjusts market income and benefits by household size. Market income and benefits includes but is not limited to income from a household s: wages and salary, including bonuses; realized capital gains; income from operating a business; pensions and annuities; interest and dividends. 401K contributions; employer-paid health insurance premiums; employer s share of payroll taxes; and estimated value of government cash transfers and in-kind benefits. 7 What is not considered income? Most items that pertain to the tax code are not included. For example, benefits from the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC) would not show up as income under this measurement. Taxes paid are also not deducted from income. 7 Where does the data come from? The CBO relies on two sources to calculate market income and benefits: IRS income tax returns and the Current Population Survey, a monthly survey of 60,000 households administered by U.S. Census Bureau. The IRS tax returns are the same as those used to calculate market income. The survey data provides information on employer and government-provided benefits. * A tax filing unit may consist of a married couple or a single individual, with or without dependents. In order to adjust for household size, the CBO divides total income by the square root of the number of people in a household. Third Way Memo 3

What are the strengths and weaknesses of this data? This measurement contains information on non-wage benefits, an important barometer of well-being not captured by market income alone. Additionally, the survey data contains information on persons who make too little money to file for federal taxes, unlike the IRS data. By combining both data sources, this measure provides a more complete picture of income in America. However, both data sources may underestimate incomes, either due to tax evasion or underreporting on the tax returns or from human error in the survey. How does this measure affect income inequality? Under this measure, the top 1% of earners captured 15% of all U.S. income in 2010 (the most recent year available). 8 The top 1% captured three times the income share of the bottom 20% and almost the same share of income as the entire middle 20% of earners (see Table 1). 9 Measure #3: After Tax Income After tax income = market income + employer-provided benefits + government transfers federal taxes. What is considered income? After tax income subtracts federal taxes from Measure #2 (market income and benefits). After tax income can be considered a measurement of purchasing power and answers the question: What does a household have once all wages, benefits, and government assistance are combined and federal taxes are removed? The CBO subtracts federal personal income, corporate, payroll, and excise taxes for their calculation of after tax income. Tax credits, including refundable credits like the EITC, are also included in this measure. After tax income includes but is not limited to income from a household s: wages and salary, including bonuses; realized capital gains; income from operating a business; pensions and annuities; 401K contributions; employer s share of payroll taxes; employer-paid health insurance premiums; estimated value of government cash transfers and in-kind benefits; and federal tax refund and credits, minus the household s federal tax liability. Third Way Memo 4

What is not included in income? State and local taxes are the main item missing from this calculation. In high tax states like California, state and local taxes can surpass 10% of income for those at the top. 10 Certain federal taxes like the estate and gift tax are also excluded from the CBO s calculation of after-tax income. In addition, this measure does not include any capital gains income that is exempt from taxation, such as the sale of most homes. * Where does the data come from? The CBO uses this metric of after tax income. They rely on the same sources used to calculate market income and benefits IRS income tax returns and the Current Population Survey. What are the strengths and weaknesses of this data? Because it relies on the same data sources, the after tax income measure is subject to many of the same strengths and weaknesses as Measure #2 (market income and benefits). In an ideal world, there would be data available to estimate all federal, state, and local taxes. In reality, many taxes are very difficult to estimate at this scale especially state and local taxes. However, it is reasonable to expect that state and local taxes affect income inequality in ways that are not captured in the data. For example, 24 states plus the District of Columbia have their own Earned Income Tax Credit for the working poor. 11 This is not included in these calculations. Additionally, the CBO does not include the federal estate tax in their calculations. This tax only affects very high earners, but some readers may want to know how estate taxes impact those in the top 1%. How does this measure affect income inequality? Under this measure, the top 1% of earners captured 13% of all income in 2010. Using after tax income, the top 1% captured over twice the income share of the bottom 20% of earners and slightly less than the share captured by the middle 20% of earners (see Table 1). 12 As shown in Table 1, the share of after tax income going to the top 1% in 2010 was a third smaller than the share measured using market income (20% vs 13%). Table 1 also illustrates the progressive effects of the tax code, with the middle and bottom 20% capturing a slightly larger share of all U.S. income after taxes. Table 1. Income Inequality by Income Measure (2010) 13 Share of all Income going to the Top 1% Middle 20% Bottom 20% #1 Market Income 20% N/A N/A #2 Market Income and Benefits 15% 14% 5% #3 After Tax Income 13% 15% 6% Note: Estimates of market income are not available for the middle and bottom 20%. Source: Alvaredo et al 2013; Congressional Budget Office 2013. * Although this is the most comprehensive income measure discussed in this paper, some economists use an even more inclusive definition of income. This measure would include things like the estimated income a homeowner would receive if they rented out their property; the value of in-kind employer benefits like a gym membership or company car; or any unrealized capital gains on investments. Third Way Memo 5

How Do Different Measures of Income Affect Income Inequality? 25% Figure 1. Share of Income Captured by the Top 1% (1979-2010) 14 20% Market Income: 20% 15% 10% Market Income and Benefits: 15% After Tax Income: 13% 5% 0% 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 Source: Alvaredo et al 2013; Congressional Budget Office 2013. Figure 1 shows the share of income captured by the top 1% of earners from 1979 to 2010, the most recent year available. The graph shows that there has been a clear rise in income inequality since 1980. The share of income accruing to the top 1% has nearly doubled since 1979, regardless of which income measure is used. Although the data sources are not quite comparable *, the graph also indicates that government programs and the tax code have played a role in mitigating some, but not all, of the rising income inequality over the last 30 years. To understand why inequality was not reduced further, we must examine changes in federal taxes and government transfers during this period. Between 1979 and 2010, the growth of universal programs like Social Security and Medicare meant that low-income Americans received a proportionally smaller share of government transfers in 2010 because middle and upper income retirees receive these benefits as well. 15 Meanwhile, the average rate for the individual income tax the most progressive component of our tax system fell between 1979 and 2010 (though it has risen since 2010 based on new taxes in the Affordable Care Act and the 2012 fiscal cliff deal). 16 Policy Implications Each of these measures has very different public policy implications. If policymakers want to reduce income inequality based on a measure of market income (Measure #1), they might pursue proposals like raising the minimum wage or placing limits on the incomes of top earners. This is because market income only captures a * This is because market income is measured using individual tax returns while the other lines are measured using household tax and survey data. Third Way Memo 6

person s earnings from working and investments and does not include government and employer-provided benefits or taxes. If policymakers are concerned with income inequality based on a measure of market income and benefits (Measure #2), they may wish to focus on interventions that increase non-wage benefits. Some examples include strengthening safety net programs like TANF, SNAP, or housing assistance; increasing Pell grants; expanding Medicaid eligibility; or creating employer mandates for health insurance and retirement. And if policymakers are concerned with income inequality based on a measure of after tax income (Measure #3), in addition to the policies listed above, they may propose raising taxes for the wealthy; boosting the Earned Income Tax Credit for the working poor; or increasing subsidies for people purchasing insurance through the healthcare exchanges. Will This Policy Lower Income Inequality? Table 2. Income Measures Affect Policy Choices Market Income Market Income + Benefits After Tax Income Raise the minimum wage!!! Place limits on the incomes of top earners!!! Strengthen safety net programs!! Create employer mandates for health insurance and retirement!! Increase Pell Grants!! Expand Medicaid eligibility!! Raise taxes on the wealthy! Increase the Earned Income Tax Credit! Increase Affordable Care Act insurance subsidies! While beyond the scope of this paper, it is important to note that income is just one facet of inequality that policymakers should consider. None of the measures discussed in this paper consider the value of an individual s or household s wealth. Wealth is another important indicator of economic well-being, and the level of wealth disparity and wealth concentration in the U.S. is also shaped by an array of government policies. * * Demographics are another factor that may influence how policymakers understand and respond to income inequality. For instance, households have become smaller over time, meaning that incomes are also supporting smaller families. Additionally, an increase the number of retired Baby Boomers means a growing number of households that no long earn income from work. Third Way Memo 7

Conclusion Over the last 100 years, the U.S. has come to recognize the problems that can be created by unfettered capitalism. Our government plays an important role in the economy by correcting markets so they may function more efficiently and equitably. In the United States, we have tried to correct for capitalism s failings principally through public policies that redistribute income after people have earned it, rather than limit what people can earn. This broad national consensus has given rise to historic government programs like the adoption of the income tax in 1913; Social Security in the 1930s; the Great Society anti-poverty efforts of the 1960s; and the passage of Affordable Care Act in 2010. If one wants to understand the full effect of progressive taxation and other critical government programs of the last century, one must use the after tax income measure (Measure #3). Important policy interventions such as increasing the Earned Income Tax Credit or expanding the number of housing vouchers will affect income disparities under certain measures but won t register on others. For example, the return to the Clinton-era tax rates and the new taxes on the wealthy from the Affordable Care Act would only affect income inequality under the after tax income measure; using either of the other two measures would mask the impact of these and similar crucial policy interventions. Progressives have engaged in ongoing efforts to combat income inequality over the last 100 years. Many leading economists, journalists, and the White House have rightly expressed serious concern over a recent rise in income inequality. But if policymakers do not use the after tax and transfer income measure (Measure #3) as a tool to analyze inequality, they will be left with few options to meet this urgent national challenge. While each measure of income discussed in this memo is legitimate, for the purposes of public policy we view the after tax measure of income (Measure #3) as the most fertile. Progressives should be proud of their accomplishments both in practice and, arguably, in their measurements. Third Way Memo 8

Further Reading Below are a handful of suggested resources for readers interested in exploring this topic further. The Brookings Institution The Center on Budget and Policy Priorities A Guide to Statistics on Historical Trends in Income Inequality. Available at: http://www.cbpp.org/cms/?fa=view&id=3629 The Congressional Budget Office Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007. Available at: http://www.cbo.gov/publication/42729 The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2010. Available at: http://www.cbo.gov/publication/44604 Jared Bernstein Piketty s Arguments Still Hold Up, After Taxes. Available at: Has Rising Inequality Brought Us Back to the 1920s? It Depends on How We Measure Income. Available at: http://www.brookings.edu/blogs/upfront/posts/2014/05/20-rising-inequality-1920s-measuring-income-burtless The Facts on Inequality, Wealth, Income, and Working May Surprise You. Available at: http://www.brookings.edu/research/podcasts/2014/05/facts-inequalitywealth-income-working-may-surprise-you http://www.nytimes.com/2014/05/10/upshot/pikettys-arguments-still-hold-up-aftertaxes.html Clarifying Some Confusion on Inequality over the Ages. Available at: http://jaredbernsteinblog.com/clarifying-some-confusion-on-inequality-over-the-ages/ Robert Samuelson Not Your Grandpa s Inequality. Available at: http://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/robert-samuelson-not-your-grandpasinequality/2014/06/01/2e1c67aa-e821-11e3-a86b-362fd5443d19_story.html Third Way Memo 9

Appendix Share of National Income Captured By the Top 1%, 1979-2010 17 Year Market Income Market Income + Benefits After Tax Income 1979 10.0% 8.9% 7.4% 1980 10.0% 8.8% 7.6% 1981 10.0% 8.9% 7.9% 1982 10.8% 9.4% 8.6% 1983 11.6% 10.1% 9.3% 1984 12.0% 10.5% 9.7% 1985 12.7% 11.2% 10.4% 1986 15.9% 13.7% 13.0% 1987 12.7% 11.0% 9.7% 1988 15.5% 13.1% 11.8% 1989 14.5% 12.2% 11.1% 1990 14.3% 11.9% 10.8% 1991 13.4% 11.0% 9.9% 1992 14.7% 12.0% 10.6% 1993 14.2% 11.6% 9.8% 1994 14.2% 11.7% 9.7% 1995 15.2% 12.2% 10.1% 1996 16.7% 13.4% 11.2% 1997 18.0% 14.5% 12.3% 1998 19.1% 15.3% 13.3% 1999 20.0% 16.3% 14.1% 2000 21.5% 17.4% 15.2% 2001 18.2% 14.4% 12.3% 2002 16.9% 13.1% 11.1% 2003 17.5% 13.8% 11.9% 2004 19.8% 15.6% 13.6% 2005 21.9% 17.4% 15.2% 2006 22.8% 18.1% 15.9% 2007 23.5% 18.7% 16.7% 2008 21.0% 16.0% 14.1% 2009 18.1% 13.3% 11.5% 2010 19.9% 14.9% 12.8% Source: Alvaredo et al 2013; Congressional Budget Office 2013. Third Way Memo 10

Endnotes 1 Chad Stone, Danilo Trisi, Arloc Sherman, and William Chen, A Guide to Statistics on Historical Trends in Income Inequality, Center for Budget and Policy Priorities, September 2013. Accessed March 26, 2014. Available at: http://www.cbpp.org/cms/?fa=view&id=3629. 2 26 U.S. Code 61 - Gross income defined, 2006. Accessed March 26, 2014. Available at: http://www.law.cornell.edu/uscode/text/26/61. 3 Stone et al; See also Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez, "Income Inequality in the United States, 1913-2002", in Top Incomes Over the 20 th Century: A Contrast Between Continental European and English- Speaking Countries, Eds. Anthony B. Atkinson and Thomas Piketty, Oxford University Press, 2007. Accessed March 26, 2014. Available at: http://elsa.berkeley.edu/users/saez/. 4 Stone et al. 5 Facundo Alvaredo, Anthony B. Atkinson, Thomas Piketty, and Emmanuel Saez, The World Top Incomes Database. Accessed March 14, 2014. Available at: http://topincomes.gmond.parisschoolofeconomics.eu/. 6 Piketty and Saez. 7 United States, Congressional Budget Office, The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2010, Report, December 2013. Accessed March 26, 2014. Available at: http://www.cbo.gov/publication/44604. 8 Ibid. 9 Ibid. 10 The Tax Policy Center, "Individual State Income Tax Rates 2000-2014," May 28, 2014. Accessed June 23, 2014. Available: http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/taxfacts/displayafact.cfm?docid=406. 11 United States, Internal Revenue Service, States and Local Governments with Earned Income Tax Credit, April 24, 2014. Accessed May 13, 2014. Available at: http://www.irs.gov/individuals/states-and- Local-Governments-with-Earned-Income-Tax-Credit. 12 Ibid. 13 Alvaredo et al. See also: Congressional Budget Office, The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2010 Supplemental Data, Excel Spreadsheet, December 2013. Accessed March 26, 2014. Available at: http://www.cbo.gov/publication/44604. 14 Ibid. 15 United States, Congressional Budget Office, Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007, Report, October 2011. Accessed June 17, 2014. Available: http://www.cbo.gov/publication/42729. See also: Congressional Budget Office, The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2010. Data. 16 Ibid. 17 Alvaredo et al; The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2010, Supplemental Third Way Memo 11