April 5, 2005 Keywords: Fiscal Policy, VAR Analysis JEL Classification: E62, H20, H30

Similar documents
Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Fiscal Multipliers in Good Times and Bad Times

The Effects of Fiscal Policy on Consumption and Employment: Theory and Evidence

Identifying of the fiscal policy shocks

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

How does an increase in government purchases affect the economy?

5. STRUCTURAL VAR: APPLICATIONS

Asian Economic and Financial Review SOURCES OF EXCHANGE RATE FLUCTUATION IN VIETNAM: AN APPLICATION OF THE SVAR MODEL

ON THE LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SPENDING IN THE UNITED STATES (*) Alfredo Marvão Pereira The College of William and Mary

What Are the Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks? A VAR-Based Comparative Analysis

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

Uncertainty and the Transmission of Fiscal Policy

Estimating the effects of fiscal policy in Structural VAR models

A Regime-Based Effect of Fiscal Policy

What does the empirical evidence suggest about the eectiveness of discretionary scal actions?

FISCAL POLICY AFTER THE GREAT RECESSION

Macroeconomic Effects of Fiscal Policy

Effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

Bonn Summer School Advances in Empirical Macroeconomics

PRIVATE AND GOVERNMENT INVESTMENT: A STUDY OF THREE OECD COUNTRIES. MEHDI S. MONADJEMI AND HYEONSEUNG HUH* University of New South Wales

Fiscal policy and collateral constraints in an estimated DSGE model:

What determines government spending multipliers?

A survey of the effects of discretionary fiscal policy

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

Hur varaktig är en förändring i arbetslösheten?

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

LONG TERM EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON THE SIZE AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF THE PIE IN THE UK

LECTURE 5 The Effects of Fiscal Changes: Aggregate Evidence. September 19, 2018

Monetary Policy Shock Analysis Using Structural Vector Autoregression

CONFIDENCE AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: THE CASE OF PORTUGAL*

How do stock prices respond to fundamental shocks?

Fiscal Policy Impact in Good and Bad Time of Real Business Cycle: A Case study of Pakistan

National Bank of the Republic of Macedonia Working Paper No. 3/2017

Information Technology, Productivity, Value Added, and Inflation: An Empirical Study on the U.S. Economy,

Workshop on resilience

What Drives Commodity Price Booms and Busts?

How Large is the Government Spending Multiplier? Evidence from World Bank Lending

Measuring the Channels of Monetary Policy Transmission: A Factor-Augmented Vector Autoregressive (Favar) Approach

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FISCAL POLICY IN THE AFTERMATH OF 9/11. Martin Eichenbaum Jonas Fisher

Iranian Economic Review, Vol.15, No.28, Winter Business Cycle Features in the Iranian Economy. Asghar Shahmoradi Ali Tayebnia Hossein Kavand

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

Uncertainty and the effectiveness of fiscal policy

The Effects of Japanese Monetary Policy Shocks on Exchange Rates: A Structural Vector Error Correction Model Approach

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation?

Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It s All in the Timing

Shocking aspects of monetary integration (SVAR approach)

Commentary. Olivier Blanchard. 1. Should We Expect Automatic Stabilizers to Work, That Is, to Stabilize?

The Impact of the Volatility of Monetary Policy on a Small Economy: Some Evidence from New Zealand

Growth Rate of Domestic Credit and Output: Evidence of the Asymmetric Relationship between Japan and the United States

Discretionary fiscal policy: Review and estimates for the EU

On the Measurement of the Government Spending Multiplier in the United States An ARDL Cointegration Approach

Is the Exchange Rate a Shock Absorber or Source of Shocks? New Empirical Evidence

BANCO DE PORTUGAL Economic Research Department

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Fiscal Policy Uncertainty and the Business Cycle: Time Series Evidence from Italy

Fiscal Policy in Open Economies

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University

The Analytics of SVARs: A Unified Framework to Measure Fiscal Multipliers

What Are The Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks in India?*

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IN SEARCH OF THE TRANSMISSION MECHANISM OF FISCAL POLICY. Roberto Perotti

IDENTIFYING GOVERNMENT SPENDING SHOCKS: IT S ALL IN THE TIMING*

A Threshold Multivariate Model to Explain Fiscal Multipliers with Government Debt

Tax multipliers: Pitfalls in measurement and identi cation

Response of Output Fluctuations in Costa Rica to Exchange Rate Movements and Global Economic Conditions and Policy Implications

Does the Confidence Fairy Exist?

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

The Evolution of Fiscal Multipliers during the Global Financial Crisis. The Case of Romania

Commentary: Is There a Role for Discretionary Fiscal Policy?

The Effects of Discretionary Fiscal Policy on Macroeconomic Aggregates: A Reappraisal

How do Macroeconomic Shocks affect Expectations? Lessons from Survey Data

The Contagion Effect: A Case Study of China and ASEAN Countries

Fiscal Policy and Asset Returns

Volume 35, Issue 1. Three states of fiscal multipliers in a small open economy. Simon Naitram Central Bank of Barbados

Testing the Stickiness of Macroeconomic Indicators and Disaggregated Prices in Japan: A FAVAR Approach

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES

Debt and the Effects of Fiscal Policy

Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It s All in the Timing

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? Andrew Mountford Harald Uhlig

Government spending shocks and labor productivity

Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Topics and Background

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM

Budgetary Decomposition and Yield Spreads

ESTIMATING THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY

1 In Denmark, between 1983 and 1986, a reduction in the full-employment surplus of 7.2 percent of GDP

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 40, No. 4, Winter, 2009, pp

Economics 442 Macroeconomic Policy (Spring 2018) 3/7-3/12/2018. Instructor: Prof. Menzie Chinn UW Madison

The Price Puzzle and Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism in Pakistan: Structural Vector Autoregressive Approach

Regional Business Cycles In the United States

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: The Case of Oil Price Rise and Italy

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Government Spending Multipliers under Zero Lower Bound: Evidence from Japan

Effects of US Monetary Policy Shocks During Financial Crises - A Threshold Vector Autoregression Approach

Transcription:

FISCAL POLICY AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: U.S. EVIDENCE K.Peren Arin ± Massey University Department of Commerce and Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis (CAMA) Faik Koray Louisiana State University Department of Economics April 5, 2005 Keywords: Fiscal Policy, VAR Analysis JEL Classification: E62, H20, H30 Abstract We investigate the dynamic effects of five different fiscal shocks on the US economy using a structural vector autoregressive (SVAR) model that uses Blanchard-Quah type restrictions. We find that an increase in indirect taxes or in corporate taxes has a contractionary effect on the economy, while an increase in personal taxes is neither contractionary, nor expansionary. These results imply that the Ricardian Equivalence hypothesis holds only for personal taxes. On the spending side, we find that an increase in government wages and salaries has a contractionary effect on the economy, while an increase in defense spending is expansionary. Our results suggest that different fiscal shocks have different and offsetting effects on the economy, and using aggregated data may, therefore, conceal the effects of fiscal policy. We would like to thank Douglas McMillin and Dek Terrell for providing comments on an earlier version of this paper and Sam Jolly for research assistance. ± Address: Massey University, Dept. of Commerce, Private Bag 102 904 NSMC, Auckland, New Zealand. E-mail: k.p.arin@massey.ac.nz Corresponding Author, Address: Louisiana State University, Department of Economics, CEBA 2107, Baton Rouge, LA 70803-6306, USA. E-mail: eokora@lsu.edu

1. Introduction This paper investigates the dynamic response of U.S. output, price level, and interest rate to fiscal policy innovations, using a structural vector autoregressive (SVAR) model for the period 1959:2-2001:2. During the last two decades several experiments led to a revival of interest in fiscal policy. First, the Reagan tax cuts in the U.S. generated a controversy about the supply-side effects of tax policy. Second, fiscal consolidations in Europe and Canada which reduced budget deficits led to an increase in private consumption, which was contrary to the conventional wisdom. Third, the formation of a monetary union in Europe, the Maastricht Treaty, the evolution to single common currency, and the establishment of the European Central Bank reduced the flexibility of monetary policy, made fiscal adjustments crucially important for the member countries and increased the role of fiscal policy. Fourth, the recent Bush tax cuts in the U.S. directed more attention towards the transmission mechanisms of fiscal policy. For a long period of time fiscal policy analysis was carried out within the Keynesian paradigm. Over the last two decades the Keynesian models have been challenged first at a theoretical level and more recently at an empirical level. At a theoretical level, conventional (Keynesian) views were challenged first by neoclassical and neoclassical dynamic general equilibrium models, then by the real business cycle models, and finally by the two-country intertemporal general equilibrium models. 1

In neoclassical dynamic general equilibrium models the effects of fiscal policy disturbances are closely related to the financing decisions of the government. Using a one-sector neoclassical model with variable labor and endogenous capital accumulation, Baxter and King (1993) show that a permanent increase in government purchases financed by lump sum taxes leads to an increase in employment and output and a decrease in real wages. Output falls, however, when government purchases are financed by distortionary income taxes. Dotsey (1994) demonstrates that when current government deficits are financed by future distortionary taxation, lower tax rates and higher deficits lead to reductions in investment and output. Ludvigson (1996), on the other hand, indicates that if the labor supply is elastic, deficit financed cuts in distortionary income taxes may increase output. In a similar way, Ohanian (1997), using an intertemporal general equilibrium model, shows that using a tax-financed fiscal policy during World War II instead of a debt-financed fiscal policy would have resulted in much lower output and welfare. Christiano and Eichenbaum (1992) use a RBC model and show that when aggregate demand shocks arising from stochastic movements in government consumption are incorporated into the analysis, the model generates a strong positive correlation between hours worked and average productivity. Braun (1994) uses a RBC model finds that the first-order effect of an increase in the corporate income tax rate is to lower the after-tax interest rate. This produces an intertemporal substitution effect on the labor supply. The labor supply shifts left, the after-tax real wage rate rises, and employment falls. An increase in the personal income tax rate produces a much larger response because households reduce current consumption as well. Finn (1998) 2

investigates the question of government spending on cyclical economic activity within the context of a quantitative real business cycle model of the U.S. economy. She reaches the conclusion that while shocks to government goods and purchases lead to an increase in private output, employment, and investment, shocks to government employment have the opposite effect. In a recent work, Barry and Devereux (2003) present a dynamic general equilibrium model where fiscal spending reductions may be expansionary. The lack of consensus which exists among theoretical studies about the effects of fiscal policy is also found in empirical studies. As mentioned in Baldacci et al. (2001), although the literature generally suggests small, positive spending multipliers and small, negative tax multipliers, there is some evidence for both negative spending multipliers and positive tax multipliers. Vector autoregressive (VAR) models have been extensively used in the literature to analyze the effects of monetary policy shocks. It is only recently, however, that attention has been directed towards estimating the effects of fiscal policy using VAR models. Ramey and Shapiro (1998) identify three dates of military buildup that are associated with the Korean War, the Vietnam War, and the Carter-Reagan military spending buildup. The exogenous shocks are measured by a dummy variable corresponding to these dates. They find that both total and private GDP increase in response to military buildups. Employing the same approach, Edelberg, Eichenbaum, and Fisher (1999) find that employment, output, and nonresidential investment rise, while real wages, residential investment and consumer expenditures fall in response to an exogenous increase in U.S. government purchases. Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Fisher 3

(2004) identify fiscal policy shocks in a similar manner and find that exogenous changes in military purchases lead to a persistent increase in government purchases and tax rates on capital and labor income, a rise in aggregate hours worked, and a decline in real wages. Yuan and Li (2000) and Fatas and Mihov (2001) examine the effects of government spending innovations for the U.S. economy by employing VAR models where identification is based on Choleski ordering. Yuan and Li (2000) find that positive innovations in U.S. government spending increase U.S. output and the total hours worked. Fatas and Mihov (2001) find that output responds positively and persistently to a government spending shock and the GDP deflator declines slightly but returns to its trend. An increase in government spending is followed by an increase in consumption, investment, employment, real wages, and the real interest rate. Garcia-Mila (1989) identifies fiscal policy shocks by Choleski decomposition and finds a positive multiplier effect of state and local government purchases on output. Military purchases, on the other hand, are found to be only slightly expansionary in the very short term. Despite a number of studies incorporating government spending into VAR models, only a few studies have attempted to investigate the effects of tax policy innovations. Blanchard and Perotti (2002) incorporate an aggregate tax revenue variable into the VAR framework by employing U.S. data. They estimate the effects of exogenous shocks to real government purchases and real net taxes on economic activity within a structural VAR model by computing impulse response functions (IRFs). They use institutional information about tax and transfer systems and the timing of tax collections to identify the automatic stabilizing aspects of fiscal policy and use this in 4

deriving fiscal shocks. Their results consistently show that positive government spending shocks have a positive effect on output, while positive tax shocks have a negative effect. Perotti (2002) studies the effects of fiscal policy on GDP, prices and interest rates in five OECD countries using a structural VAR approach. He argues that the effects of fiscal policy on GDP and its components have become substantially weaker in the last twenty years. He also contends that the tax multipliers tend to be negative but small, and that there is some evidence on positive tax multipliers while the net tax shocks have negative small effects on prices. Finally, he indicates that the U.S. is an outlier in many dimensions, so the responses to fiscal shocks estimated on U.S. data are often not representative of the average OECD country. Economic theory suggests that different tax groups have different effects on the economy. For instance, Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980) develop a basic intertemporal model, which shows that income taxes and consumption taxes have different effects on household saving decisions. Neoclassical dynamic general equilibrium models developed by Baxter and King (1993), among others, indicate that lump sum taxes and distortionary taxes have different effects on the economy. There is also empirical support for different effects by different tax groups. Using a panel of twenty two OECD countries, Kneller, Bleaney and Gemmell (1999) argue that distortionary taxation (income taxes and social security taxes) reduces growth whereas non-distortionary taxation (corporate taxes and indirect taxes) does not, and productive government expenditures (such as expenditures on infrastructure) enhance growth, while non-productive government expenditures (such as recreational expenditures) do not. 5

Baxter and King (1993) Ahmed and Yoo (1995), and Ohanian (1997) distinguish between government consumption expenditures on goods and services and government investment expenditures. Finn (1998) Ardagna (2001), and McGrattan and Ohanian (2003) distinguish between government consumption expenditures with and without compensation of government employees. Alesina and Perotti (1995, 1997) and Alesina and Ardagna (1998) show that cuts in government employment are expansionary, and stimulate business investment. Alesina, Ardagna, Perotti, and Schiantarelli (2002) find that spending cuts, particularly in government wages and transfers, lead to expansions in output. In this paper, we investigate the response of output, price level, and interest rate to innovations in different revenue and spending instruments within a SVAR model which uses Blanchard and Quah (1989) type long-run restrictions. Our results indicate that different taxes and different categories of government expenditures have different effects on macroeconomic activity. When we estimate a SVAR with total taxes and total government expenditures for the U.S. economy, we find that fiscal policy is neither expansionary, nor contractionary. Nonetheless, when we decompose total taxes into three groups (personal taxes, corporate taxes, and indirect taxes) and estimate three different SVAR models, each with a different tax group, we find that an increase in indirect taxes or in corporate taxes has a contractionary effect on the economy, while personal taxes have neither expansionary, nor contractionary effects. Likewise, when we estimate a SVAR with government wages and salaries, an increase in government wages and salaries has a contractionary effect on the economy. On the other 6

hand, when we estimate a SVAR with defense spending, defense spending has an expansionary effect on the economy. This evidence implies that choosing total taxes or total government expenditures as a measure of fiscal policy variable could be misleading and decomposing total taxes or total government expenditures into sub-categories would yield a more accurate picture. The remainder of the chapter is organized as follows: Section 2 explains the data and methodology used, Section 3 presents the empirical results, and Section 4 provides some concluding remarks. 2. Data and Methodology 2.1. Data The data used in this paper are obtained from two different sources: the data for four different types of government revenues, namely personal, corporate, and indirect taxes, government consumption expenditures and gross investment, national defense expenditures, government wages and salaries, real and nominal GDP are obtained from the DRI database. The data for the CPI and the 3-month Treasury bill rate are obtained from the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank Fred II data base. The different types of taxes, national defense expenditures, and government wages and salaries are deflated by the GDP deflator which is obtained after dividing nominal GDP by real GDP. The exact definitions of the variables and their source codes are presented in Table 1. The data consist of quarterly observations for the 1959:1-2001:2 period. 2.2. Methodology To investigate the response of macroeconomic variables to fiscal policy innovations, we use a SVAR model. Our structural VAR model imposes long-run identifying restrictions, pioneered by Blanchard (1989) and Blanchard and Quah (1989), 7

on an ordinary VAR model in order to infer structural shocks from it. The long-run restrictions are based on neutrality restrictions. Prior to implementing this procedure, the model is transformed into first differences. Then, real variables are ordered before nominal variables, and output is ordered before the policy variables. The long-run effect of a shock on the level of a variable is simply the cumulative sum of the relevant moving average representation. As there is more agreement upon the long-run relationships between the economic variables, there is less controversy over the use of long-run restrictions relative to contemporaneous restrictions. Assume an unrestricted VAR model written in moving average form: X = A( L), (1) t e t where X is a vector of macroeconomic variables, A(L) is a polynomial matrix of laglength l, L is the lag operator and e is a vector of reduced form shocks in the elements of X with variance-covariance matrix E(e t e t ) = Σ. These reduced form shocks are likely to be correlated so they cannot be interpreted as pure structural shocks. Imposing identifying restrictions, the SVAR model obtains: X = B( L), (2) t u t where B(L) is a polynomial matrix in L, u t is a vector of serially and contemporaneously uncorrelated, normalized structural residuals with E(u t u t ) = I, and A Σ A' = BB'. Here A and B are k x k matrices to be estimated and the expression on either side is symmetric This model only requires a minimum number of k.(k+1)/2 restrictions, and it enables us to make the same assumptions regarding each and every fiscal policy instrument. In 8

addition, in many cases, economic theory provides more guidance about long-run relationships between economic variables rather than their short-run dynamics. The vector X of macroeconomic variables comprises of the following variables. Output (Y, measured by real GDP), the price level (P, measured by the CPI), the 3-month Treasury-bill rate (R), tax revenue (T, measured by tax revenue of the i th group measured in U.S dollars, deflated by the GDP deflator), and real government expenditures (G, in US dollars, deflated by the GDP deflator). As mentioned above, each model was differenced before being included in the estimation. In order to choose lag-lengths, the results of the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) were used, and the lag length for all models was chosen as 5. To identify the structural shocks from the VAR model, ten identifying restrictions are required. These are: Tax revenue innovations do not have a permanent effect on output (1); government expenditure shocks do not have a permanent effect on output (2), and on tax revenues (3); monetary shocks, as proxied by the interest rate, do not have a permanent effect on output (4), on tax revenues (5) and on government expenditures (6); and finally, price level shocks do not have a permanent effect on output (7), on tax revenues (8), on government expenditures (9) and on the interest rate (10). These restrictions can be illustrated in the matrix form: Y b T b G = b R b P b 11 21 31 41 51 b b b b 0 22 32 42 52 0 0 b b b 33 43 53 0 0 0 b b 44 54 0 u 0 u 0 u 0 u b 55 u Y T G R P (3) 9

Impulse response functions (IRFs) are calculated from the SVAR estimation. This approach has recently been implemented by Aarle et al. (2003), without estimating the Monte-Carlo confidence bands. In our paper, one-standard deviation confidence intervals are obtained from a Monte Carlo simulation based on 1000 draws. 3. Empirical Results 3.1. The Effects of Tax Innovations The IRFs of all model variables to a one-standard deviation shock to total taxes and different tax groups are presented in Figures 1-4. Figure 1 presents the IRFs of Y, T, G, R, and P to a positive innovation in T. The response of output is negative, indicating that an increase in taxes has a negative impact on output. As indicated by the onestandard deviation confidence band, however, the response of output is not significantly different from zero. The response of T is positive and significant, implying that the innovation is permanent. The response of G is positive, indicating that government expenditures rise in response to a permanent increase in tax revenues, but this is not significantly different from zero. Interest rates fall, and again this is not significantly different from zero. The response of the price level is negative. This result is significant especially between the 3 rd and 5 th quarters. Figure 2 presents the IRFs of Y, T P, G, R, and P to a positive innovation in personal taxes T P. The initial response of output is positive. It becomes negative after the 10 th quarter; however, in both cases the response of output is not significantly different from zero. The response of T P is positive and significant, implying that the innovation to personal taxes is permanent. The response of G is positive, but this is not 10

significantly different from zero. The response of the interest rate is not significantly different from zero. The response of the price level is negative, and this is significant in the 3 rd quarter. The initial response of output, even though it is not significantly different from zero, is somewhat puzzling. One reason could be due the aggregated nature of the data. Personal income taxes include taxes on all sorts of income, which may have different response patterns. Since income tax data reported by individuals reflect the tax liability on the cumulative sum of personal income, we do not have the means to estimate the response of output to changes in the components of personal income taxes. Figure 3 presents the IRFs of Y, T I, G, R, and P to a positive innovation in indirect taxes T. The response of output is negative and significantly different from zero I until the 15 th quarter. The response of T is positive and significant, implying that the I innovation to indirect taxes is permanent. The response of G is positive, but it is not significantly different from zero. The interest rate and price level both fall in response to an increase in indirect taxes. Figure 4 presents the IRFs of Y, T C, G, R, and P to a positive innovation in indirect taxes T. The response of output is negative and significantly different from C zero until the 6 th quarter. The response of T is positive and significant, implying that the innovation to corporate taxes is permanent. The response of G is negative and significantly different from zero. The response of G to T innovations is very different from other innovations. The IRFs indicate that government expenditures fall in response to an increase in corporate taxes. This may happen if the government is using corporate C C 11

taxes as a tool of last resort to reduce the deficit. The interest rate and price level both fall in response to an increase in corporate taxes. We can draw two important conclusions from the analysis of impulse response functions analyzed above. First, different taxes may have different effects on the economy. Aggregating these taxes and using the sum as a measure of fiscal policy may actually add more noise to the system and prevent us from seeing the different effects of these taxes on the economy. The second conclusion that emerges from the above findings is related to the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis. The Ricardian equivalence hypothesis states that a switch from lump-sum tax finance to bond finance has no effect on the macro economy, holding everything else constant. The IRFs above indicate that while the economy contracts in response to increases in indirect and corporate taxes, it is not affected by personal taxes. In this sense, the evidence from IRFs is inconclusive. On the other hand, indirect taxes are the least distortionary and they can be regarded as lumpsum taxes. In this sense, we get the best evidence from the IRFs of indirect tax innovations, which reveal that the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis does not hold. 3.2. The Effects of Government Spending Innovations The impulse response functions of all model variables to a one-standard deviation shock to government expenditures and to two components of government expenditures are presented in Figures 5-7. Figure 5 presents the impulse response functions of Y, T, G, R, and P to a positive innovation in government expenditures G. The response of output is negative, indicating that an increase in government expenditures has a negative impact on output. As indicated by the one-standard deviation confidence band, however, the 12

response of output is not significantly different from zero. The response of T is negative and it is not significantly different from zero. The response of G is positive and significant, indicating that the innovation to government expenditures is permanent. The interest rate falls, and the negative response of the interest rate is significantly different from zero. The response of the price level is negative, but it is not significantly different from zero. We get a more interesting picture when we make a distinction between the wage component of government expenditures and defense expenditures. Figure 6 presents the impulse response functions of Y, T, G, R, and P to a positive innovation in government W wages and salaries G. The response of output is negative, and it is significantly W different from zero until the 9 th quarter, indicating that an increase in government wages and salaries has a negative impact on output. The response of T is positive and significant. The response of G W is positive and significant, indicating that the innovation to government wages and salaries is permanent. The responses of both the interest rate and the price level are negative and significant. Figure 7 presents the impulse response functions of Y, T, G D, R, and P to a positive innovation in defense spending G D. The response of output is positive and significantly different from zero for the first two quarters. The response of T is not significantly different from zero. The response of G D is positive and significant, indicating that the innovation to defense spending is permanent. The response of the interest rate is not significantly different from zero but the response of the price level is positive and significant. 13

While it is difficult to reach a conclusion as to whether an increase in government expenditures have an expansionary or contractionary effect on the economy, by analyzing the effects of different components of government expenditures we can make more convincing arguments. We find that while increases in wages and salaries have a contractionary effect on the economy, increases in defense spending have an expansionary effect. 3.3. Residual Analysis Do estimated tax shocks make sense? As the history of tax policy is most wellknown for the U.S., we compared the estimated shocks with the dates of actual policy changes. Figures 8-9 display the residual analysis for the U.S. The top income tax rate in the U.S was reduced in the following years: 1964 (from 91% to 77 %), 1965 (from 77% to 70%), 1970 (from 77 to 71.75%), 1981 (from 70% to 69.13%), 1982 (from 69.13% to 50%). and 1987 (from 50% to 38.5%). All of these policy changes are captured by our estimated shocks. In addition, we managed to capture the tax resurges of 1968 and 1975. When we look at the corporate tax shocks, our estimated shocks capture the corporate tax rate cuts of 1965 (top rate was decreased from 50% to 48%), 1970 (from 52.8 % to 49.2 %), 1979 (from 48% to 46%), 1987 (from 46% to 40%) and finally 1988 (from 40% to 34%). We also capture the increases in the corporate tax rate in 1968 (from 48% to 52%) and 1993 (from 34% to 35%). The biggest estimated negative shocks (1975 and 1992), however, do not coincide with actual policy changes. 14

4. Conclusion This paper investigates the dynamic response of U.S. output, price level, and interest rate to fiscal policy innovations, using a structural vector autoregressive (SVAR) model for the period 1959:2-2001:2 which uses Blanchard-Quah type restrictions. We consider three types of tax innovations and two types of government spending innovations: on the revenue side innovations to personal, corporate, and indirect taxes and on the expenditure side innovations to government wages and defense spending. We find that an increase in indirect taxes or corporate taxes has a contractionary effect on the economy, while an increase in personal taxes is neither contractionary, nor expansionary. These results imply that the Ricardian Equivalence hypothesis holds only for personal taxes. On the spending side, we find that an increase in government wages and salaries has a contractionary effect on the economy, while an increase in defense spending is expansionary. Our results suggest that different fiscal shocks have different and offsetting effects on the economy, and that using aggregated data may conceal the effects of fiscal policy. 15

References: Aarle, B. van, Garretsen, H., Gobbin, N. (2003) Monetary and Fiscal Policy Transmission in the Euro Area: Evidence from a Structural VAR Analysis, Journal of Economics and Business 55(5-6), 609-638. Ahmed, S., Yoo, B.S. (1995) Fiscal Trends in Real Economic Aggregates, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27(4), 985-1001. Alesina A., Ardagna, S. (1998) Fiscal Adjustments: Why They Can Be Expansionary, Economic Policy: A European Forum 27, 487-517. Alesina A., Ardagna, S., Perotti, R. and Schiantarelli, F. (2002) Fiscal Policy, Profits and Investment, American Economic Review 92(3), 571-589. Alesina A., Perotti, R. (1995) Fiscal Expansions and Adjustments in OECD Countries, Economic Policy: A European Forum 21, 205-240. Alesina A., Perotti, R. (1997) Fiscal Adjustments in OECD Countries: Composition and Macroeconomic Effects, IMF Staff Papers 44(2), 210-248. Ardagna, S. (2001) Fiscal Policy Composition, Public Debt and Economic Activity, Public Choice 109(3-4), 301-325. Atkinson, A. and Stiglitz, J., (1980) Lectures on Public Economics, McGraw Hill, NY. Baldacci, E., Cangiano, M., Mahfouz, S., Schimmelpfennig, A. (2001) The Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy in Stimulating Economic Activity an Empirical Investigation, paper presented at the IMF Annual Research Conference (Washington: IMF). Barry, F., Devereux, M. B. (2003) Expansionary Fiscal Contraction: A Theoretical Exploration, Journal of Macroeconomics 25(1), 1-23. Baxter, M., King R. G. (1993) Fiscal Policy in General Equilibrium, American Economic Review 83(3), 315-334. Blanchard, O. (1989) A Traditional Interpretation of Macroeconomic Fluctuations, American Economic Review, 79(5), 1146-1164. Blanchard, O., Perotti, R. (2002) An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending and Taxes on Output, Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4), 1329-1368. 16

Blanchard, O., Quah, D. (1989) The Dynamic Effects of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Shocks, American Economic Review 79(4), 655-673. Braun, A. (1994) Tax Disturbance and Real Economic Activity in the Postwar United States, Journal of Monetary Economics 33(3), 441-462. Burnside, C., Eichenbaum, M., Fisher, J. (2004) Fiscal Shocks and Their Consequences, Journal of Economic Theory 115(1), 89-117. Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M. (1992) Current Real-Business Cycle Theories and Aggregate Labor-Market Fluctuations, American Economic Review 82(3), 430-450. Dotsey, M. (1994) Some Unpleasant Supply Side Arithmetic, Journal of Monetary Economics 33(3), 507-524. Edelberg, W., Eichenbaum, M., Fisher J. D. M. (1999) Understanding the Effects of a Shock to Government Purchases, Review of Economic Dynamics 2(1), 166-206. Fatas, A., Mihov, I. (2001) The Effects of Fiscal Policy on Consumption and Employment: Theory and Evidence, CEPR Discussion Paper #2760. Finn, M. G. (1998) Cyclical Effects of Government s Employment and Goods Purchases, International Economic Review 39(3), 635-657. Garcia-Mila, T. (1989) Some Empirical Evidence on Government Purchase Multipliers, Economics Letters 31(4), 375-380. Kneller, R., Bleaney, M.F., Gemmell, N. (1999) Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: Evidence from OECD Countries, Journal of Public Economics 74(2), 171-190. Ludvigson, S. (1996) The Macroeconomic Effects of Government Debt in a Stochastic Growth Model, Journal of Monetary Economics 38(1), 25-45. McGrattan, E., Ohanian, L. E. (2003) Does Neoclassical Theory Account for Wartime Economic Booms? Evidence from World war II, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Staff Report: 315. Ohanian, L. E. (1997) The Macroeconomic Effects of War Finance in the United States: World War II and the Korean War, American Economic Review 87(1), 23-40. 17

Perotti, R., 2002. Estimating the Effects of Fiscal Policy in OECD Countries Forthcoming in the Journal of European Economic Association. Ramey, V. A., Shapiro, M. D. (1998) Costly Capital Reallocation and the Effects of Government Spending, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 48, 145-194 Yuan, M., Li, W., (2000) Dynamic Employment and Hours Effects of Government Spending Shocks, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 24(8), 1233-1263 18

TABLE 1: Definition and Data Source for the Variables Used Variable Definition Data Source and Code Personal Taxes Corporate Taxes Indirect Taxes Federal, state, and local; income, other, Billions of dollars, SAAR Federal, state, and local, Billions of dollars, SAAR Federal, state, and local; excise taxes, custom duties, sales taxes, property taxes, billions of dollars, SAAR DRI, TXP DRI, TXCORP DRI, TXIM Government wages and salaries National Defense Expenditures Real Government Expenditures Real GDP Compensation of government employees, billions of dollars, SAAR Government consumption expenditures and gross investment, billions of dollars, SAAR Government consumption expenditures and gross investment, billions of dollars, SAAR Gross Domestic Product, billions of chained 2000 dollars, SAAR DRI, YPCOMPWSG DRI, GFML DRI, GR DRI, GDPR Nominal GDP Billions of dollars, SAAR DRI, GDP Treasury-bill rate CPI 3-Month Treasury bill, secondary market rate Consumer price index for all urban consumers, all items, SA FRED II, TB3MS FRED II, CPIAUSL 19

Figure 1: Shock to Total Taxes Shock to Total Taxes, 1959:2-2001:2, LL=5 0.0018 Response of Y 0.24 Response of R 9 0.12 0-9 0.00-0.0018-0.0027-0.12-0.0036-0.24-0.0045-0.0054-0.36 0.016 Response of T 0.002 Response of P 0.014 0.012-0.002 0.010-0.004 0.008-0.006 0.006-0.008 0.004 0.002-0.010-0.012 0.0075 Response of G 0.0050 0.0025 0-0.0025-0.0050 20

Figure 2: Shock to Personal Taxes Shock to Personal Taxes, 1959:2-2001:2, LL=5 0.0045 Response of Y 0.50 Response of R 0.0036 0.0027 0.25 0.0018 9 0 0.00-9 -0.0018-0.0027-0.25 0.040 Response of T 0.0064 Response of P 0.0048 0.035 0.0032 0.030 0.0016-0 0.025-0.0016-0.0032 0.020-0.0048 0.015-0.0064 0.0075 Response of G 0.0050 0.0025 0-0.0025-0.0050 21

Figure 3: Shock to Indirect Taxes Shock to Indirect Taxes, 1959:2-2001:2, LL=5 0.001 Response of Y 0.16 Response of R 0.08-0.001 0.00-0.002-0.08-0.003-0.16-0.004-0.24-0.005-0.32-0.006-0.40-0.007-0.48-0.008-0.56 0.014 Response of T 0.0025 Response of P 0 0.012-0.0025 0.010-0.0050 0.008-0.0075 0.006-0.0100-0.0125 0.004-0.0150 0.002-0.0175-0.0200 0.010 Response of G 0.008 0.006 0.004 0.002-0.002-0.004 22

Figure 4: Shock to Corporate Taxes Shock to Corporate Taxes, 1959:2-2001:2, LL=5 0.002 Response of Y 0.09 Response of R 0.001-0.00-0.001-0.09-0.002-0.18-0.003-0.004-0.27-0.005-0.36-0.006-0.007-0.45 7 Response of T 0.002 Response of P 6 5-0.002 4-0.004 3-0.006 2-0.008 1-0.010 0-0.012 0.0025 Response of G 0-0.0025-0.0050-0.0075-0.0100-0.0125 23

Figure 5: Shock to Government Expenditures Shock to Government Expenditures, 1959:2-2001:2, LL=5 0.0016 Response of Y 0.2 Response of R 8 0.1-0 -0.0-8 -0.1-0.0016-0.2-0.0024-0.3-0.0032-0.0040-0.4-0.0048-0.5 0.002 Response of T 0.004 Response of P 0.002-0.002-0.002-0.004-0.004-0.006-0.006-0.008-0.008 0.0208 Response of G 0.0192 0.0176 0.0160 0.0144 0.0128 0.0112 0.0096 0.0080 0.0064 24

Figure 6: Shock to Government Wages and Salaries Shock to Government Employment, 1959:2-2001:2, LL=5 0.001 Response of Y 0.18 Response of R 0.09-0.001-0.00-0.002-0.09-0.003-0.18-0.004-0.27-0.005-0.36-0.006-0.45-0.007-0.54 0.002 Response of T 0.002 Response of P -0.002-0.002-0.004-0.004-0.006-0.006-0.008-0.008-0.010-0.010-0.012-0.012-0.014 0.0175 Response of G 0.0150 0.0125 0.0100 0.0075 0.0050 0.0025 25

Figure 7: Shock to Government Defense Spending Shock to Defense Spending, 1959:2-2001:2, LL=5 0.005 Response of Y 0.50 Response of R 0.004 0.003 0.25 0.002 0.001 0.00-0.001-0.002-0.003-0.25 0.008 Response of T 0.014 Response of P 0.006 0.012 0.010 0.004 0.008 0.002 0.006 0.004-0.002 0.002-0.004 0.050 Response of G 0.045 0.040 0.035 0.030 0.025 0.020 0.015 0.010 26

Figure 9: The Residual Analysis 30 Corporate Tax Residuals 20 10 0-10 -20-30 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00.2 Personal Tax Residuals.1.0 -.1 -.2 -.3 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 27