Aalborg Universitet. Intergenerational Top Income Persistence Denmark half the size of Sweden Munk, Martin D.; Bonke, Jens; Hussain, M.

Similar documents
IFN Working Paper No. 775, 2008

The intergenerational transmission of wealth

Daniel Waldenström Inheritance and Wealth Taxation in Sweden

Intergenerational Top Income Mobility in Sweden: A Combination of Equal Opportunity and Capitalistic Dynasties

Journal of Public Economics

St. Gallen, Switzerland, August 22-28, 2010

Intergenerational Earnings Persistence in Italy along the Lifecycle

There is poverty convergence

The Association between Children s Earnings and Fathers Lifetime Earnings: Estimates Using Administrative Data

Currency Substitution, Capital Mobility and Functional Forms of Money Demand in Pakistan

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

Class 13 Question 2 Estimating Taxable Income Responses Using Danish Tax Reforms Kleven and Schultz (2014)

Intergenerational Dependence in Education and Income

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017

Heterogeneous Income Profiles and Life-Cycle Bias in Intergenerational Mobility Estimation

IGE: The State of the Literature

Wealth Distribution and Taxation. Frank Cowell: MSc Public Economics 2011/2

THRESHOLD EFFECT OF INFLATION ON MONEY DEMAND IN MALAYSIA

FDI and economic growth: new evidence on the role of financial markets

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Exchange Rate Exposure and Firm-Specific Factors: Evidence from Turkey

Direct Measures of Intergenerational Income Mobility for Australia

Marital Sorting, Household Labor Supply, and Intergenerational Earnings Mobility across Countries

Income Inequality in Korea,

Direct Measures of Intergenerational Income Mobility for Australia

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Wealth Returns Dynamics and Heterogeneity

Redistribution Effects of Electricity Pricing in Korea

Extract from Income Inequality, Equality of Opportunity, and Intergenerational Mobility

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Monetary Policy in an Agent-Based Monetary Production Economy Bruun, Charlotte

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

The Danish National Centre for Social Research

Inequality and the super-rich

Graduate Public Finance

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Labour Supply, Taxes and Benefits

Forecasting Exchange Rate between Thai Baht and the US Dollar Using Time Series Analysis

Gender wage gaps in formal and informal jobs, evidence from Brazil.

Estimating the Value and Distributional Effects of Free State Schooling

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

ROLE OF FUNDAMENTAL VARIABLES IN EXPLAINING STOCK PRICES: INDIAN FMCG SECTOR EVIDENCE

Military Expenditures, External Threats and Economic Growth. Abstract

Stochastic Optimal Regulation Service Strategy for a Wind Farm Participating in the Electricity Market Zhang, Baohua; Hu, Weihao; Chen, Zhe

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Female Labor Force Participation in Pakistan: A Case of Punjab

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Lecture 6: Taxable Income Elasticities

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 109 ( 2014 ) Yigit Bora Senyigit *, Yusuf Ag

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Income Inequality Matters, but Mobility Is Just as Important. Daniel R. Carroll and Anne Chen

Labor economics B Hokkaido University Fall Yukiko Abe Hokkaido University, Japan

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

Volume Title: Bank Stock Prices and the Bank Capital Problem. Volume URL:

Are the social security benefits of pensions or child-care policies best financed by a consumption tax?

Risk-Based Operation and Maintenance Planning for Offshore Wind Turbines Nielsen, Jannie Sønderkær; Sørensen, John Dalsgaard

A multilevel analysis on the determinants of regional health care expenditure. A note.

Fertility Decline and Work-Life Balance: Empirical Evidence and Policy Implications

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

St. Gallen, Switzerland, August 22-28, 2010

The Relative Income Hypothesis: A comparison of methods.

Building up Tax Systems: Lessons from the Nordic Countries

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners

Empirical Strategies to Eliminate Life-Cycle Bias in the Intergenerational Elasticity of Earnings Literature

Julio Videras Department of Economics Hamilton College

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES IN POVERTY RESEARCH

Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role

Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis, Vol:1, No:1 (2017) 1-13

Wealth Distribution and Bequests

THE PRICING RELATIONSHIP OF AUDITS AND RELATED SERVICES IN MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENTS

Does an Exchange-Rate-Based Stabilization Programme Help For Disinflation in Turkey?

Jacek Prokop a, *, Ewa Baranowska-Prokop b

THE DESIGN OF THE INDIVIDUAL ALTERNATIVE

News Media Channels: Complements or Substitutes? Evidence from Mobile Phone Usage. Web Appendix PSEUDO-PANEL DATA ANALYSIS

One size doesn t fit all: A quantile analysis of intergenerational income mobility in the US ( )

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.ec] 1 Sep 2014

THE SENSITIVITY OF INCOME INEQUALITY TO CHOICE OF EQUIVALENCE SCALES

Inequality and GDP per capita: The Role of Initial Income

Domestic Accounting Standards, International Accounting Standards, and the. Predictability of Earnings

The Impact of Financial Parameters on Agricultural Cooperative and Investor-Owned Firm Performance in Greece

AIM-AP. Accurate Income Measurement for the Assessment of Public Policies. Citizens and Governance in a Knowledge-based Society

Management Science Letters

Wage Inequality and Establishment Heterogeneity

Citation for published version (APA): Shehzad, C. T. (2009). Panel studies on bank risks and crises Groningen: University of Groningen

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Applied Econometrics and International Development. AEID.Vol. 5-3 (2005)

MEMORANDUM. Department of Economics University of Oslo

The relationship between the government debt and GDP growth: evidence of the Euro area countries

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Lecture 5: Fundamentals of Statistical Analysis and Distributions Derived from Normal Distributions

An Empirical Examination of Traditional Equity Valuation Models: The case of the Athens Stock Exchange

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

Capital Gains Realizations of the Rich and Sophisticated

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

Transcription:

Downloaded from vbn.aau.dk on: april 05, 2019 Aalborg Universitet Intergenerational Top Income Persistence Denmark half the size of Sweden Munk, Martin D.; Bonke, Jens; Hussain, M. Azhar Published in: Economics Letters DOI (link to publication from Publisher): 10.1016/j.econlet.2015.11.038 Publication date: 2016 Document Version Accepted author manuscript, peer reviewed version Link to publication from Aalborg University Citation for published version (APA): Munk, M. D., Bonke, J., & Hussain, M. A. (2016). Intergenerational Top Income Persistence: Denmark half the size of Sweden. Economics Letters, 140, 31-33. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2015.11.038 General rights Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights.? Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research.? You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain? You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal? Take down policy If you believe that this document breaches copyright please contact us at vbn@aub.aau.dk providing details, and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim.

Intergenerational Top Income Persistence: Denmark half the size of Sweden Accepted for publication in Economics Letters Martin D. Munk* Centre for Mobility Research, Department of Political Science, Aalborg University Copenhagen, Frederikskaj 10B, DK-2450 Copenhagen SV, Denmark, Email: mdm@dps.aau.dk, telephone: + 45 99 40 23 35 Jens Bonke Rockwool Foundation Research Unit, Sølvgade 10, DK-1307 Copenhagen K, Denmark M. Azhar Hussain Department of Society and Globalization, Roskilde University Universitetsvej 1, DK-4000 Roskilde, Denmark * Corresponding Author 1

Intergenerational Top Income Persistence: Denmark half the size of Sweden Abstract In this paper, we investigate intergenerational top earnings and top income mobility in Denmark. Access to administrative registers allowed us to look at very small fractions of the population. We find that intergenerational mobility is lower in the top when including capital income in the income measure - for the rich top 0.1 % fathers and sons the elasticity is 0.466. Compared with Sweden, however, the intergenerational top income persistence is smaller in Denmark. Keywords: Intergenerational top income persistence, top incomes, piecewise (spline) regression. JEL classification: C2; D3; D6 I. Introduction Intergenerational income mobility is key to the understanding of how individual opportunities and social status vary across groups and between countries. Here, we present novel estimates for the father-son intergenerational top income mobility for Denmark and compare them with similar estimates for Sweden. We find that intergenerational top income persistence in Denmark is smaller than in Sweden and present some possible explanations for this finding. II. Background The literature shows that top income shares in the Western world are increasing (Atkinson et al., 2011; Piketty, 2014; Roine & Waldenström 2015) and that intergenerational father-son income mobility is small for high incomes, reaching a very low level for the top end of the income distribution. In particular, this holds for Sweden, which despite its relatively low income inequality and high intergenerational income mobility, has a 0.1 % top income elasticity of 0.896 compared with an overall elasticity of 0.260 (Björklund et al., 2012). Björklund et al. (2012) further find that 2

capital income is the prominent channel in the transmission at the very top of the income distribution. The question addressed here is whether the high intergenerational top income persistence found for rich Swedes also holds for rich Danes given that Sweden and Denmark can be characterized as Scandinavian welfare regimes with similar levels of earnings mobility (Hussain et al., 2009). Nevertheless, the two countries have different capital income distributions and industrial structures for example, major companies in Sweden are larger than their counterparts in Denmark. III. Empirical framework Based on practice within mobility studies, the intergenerational determination of children s incomes can be expressed by the following regression equation: (1) log y ci = α c + β c log y pi + ε ci, where log y ci denotes the natural logarithm of income of a child in family i and y pi the corresponding measure of the parent. We control for the age and age squared of the parent (p) and child (c). The error term ε ci depicts the combined effect on the child s income of factors orthogonal to parental income, and β c is the intergenerational elasticity of the child s income given the parent s income. Because inheritance is not equally strong across the whole income distribution revealed as nonlinearity (Bratberg et al., 2007) intergenerational income mobility is analysed over the full income range by using piecewise linear regression estimations (spline regressions). This implies separate estimations for parent-child pairs belonging to different parent income percentiles P25, P50, P75, P90, P95, P99, P99.9 which allow the slopes to vary over the earnings and income distributions (Greene, 2012). Therefore, the interpretation of the β-coefficient in equation (1) is the 3

percentage differential in the expected earnings or income of the son, given a percentage differential in earnings or income of the parent, for example, within the top P99.9-100 fractile. IV. Data The data stem from administrative registers at Statistics Denmark including information on earnings, capital income, and benefit payments for the period 1980 2008. A unique personal identification number allows merging of the information of every father and son. The father is in almost all cases the biological father, but if there is no information, then the step father living with the mother at the end of the son s birth year is used. Using register information implies that there are no coverage problems, but the capital incomes may nevertheless suffer from evasion and avoidance and improper imputation of income from owner-occupied housing and other capital goods. In this study, the second generation (sons) is aged 35 42 years in 2008 or, equivalently, 7 14 years in 1980 (father incomes are measured from 1980 to 1984). This relatively broad age bracket is important for minimizing the problem of non-homogeneity in the residuals, see Solon (1992), Zimmerman (1992), Haider & Solon (2006), Hussain et al. (2009) and Lee & Solon (2009): i.e. individuals with high lifetime income tend to have steeper income growth trajectories. Nybom & Stuhler (2014) also stresses that incomes measured around midlife causes the smallest life-cycle bias. However, even permanent income estimates based on 5-year periods may underestimate the intergenerational persistence, see e.g. Hendricks (2007) showing that measures of persistence based on lifetime earnings increase 30% compared with measures using only 5-year periods. Here, fathers are aged between 25 and 88 years in 1984 why we control for their age. The income concepts 4

include individual earnings from work, business, and capital income (incl. capital gains of stocks), see Björklund et al. (2012) using similar definitions, and Roine & Waldenström (2012), who demonstrate that realized capital gains are very important in the Swedish setting. Moreover, only individuals with positive earnings or income in each of the five years (2004 2008 for the child and 1980 1984 for the parent) are included. Incomes are inflated to 2008 by the CPI from Statistics Denmark. We exclude observations if the absolute dfbeta diagnostic, which detects individual observations with unusually high influence on parameter estimates (Belsley, Kuh and Welsch, 2005), is above 2/n ½ and the absolute standardised residual is above 3. These outliers count for only 1½ % of the observations, but the exclusion has no impact on the estimated coefficients structure, i.e. the correlation coefficients for the estimates with and without the outliers are above 0.96. The number of observations is 1,993 (earnings) and 2,612 (income) in the top percentile and, thereby, 199 261 in the 0.1 top income percentile (fewer observations for earnings). V. Results Table 1 show that the intergenerational earnings and income elasticities for father-son increase up to a certain point and then decrease, leaving the top percentile out of consideration: The father-son income elasticity is 0.065 for the P0-25 group, 0.428 for the upper-middle P50-75 group, and 0.199 for the P99-99.9 group. At the very top end of the distribution (P99.9-100), we found that only the income elasticity for father-son is significant, and high, i.e. a 10% higher income among the P99.9-100 group of fathers implies on average a 4.66% (estimated β c =0.466) higher income among their sons. In comparison, the intergenerational income elasticity at the P99.9-100 fractile (0.1%) in Sweden is 0.896 for father-son (Björklund et al., 2012) and hence is nearly double the size of that for Denmark 5

(a t-test =1.92 significant on a 5.5 % level shows a difference). For the group P99-99.9, the income elasticity for Sweden is also greater than that for Denmark (0.392 versus 0.199). The top earnings elasticity for Denmark is insignificant, whereas it is positive and significant (0. 447) for Sweden; accordingly, top earnings mobility is less likely in Sweden than in Denmark. For the lower and middle part of the father-son income and earnings distributions, we found similar nonlinearities in Denmark as in Sweden. Table 1. Earnings and total income elasticities for father and son. Spline regression. Denmark OLS=IGE P 0-25 P 25-50 P 50-75 P 75-90 P 90-95 P 95-99 P 99-99.9 P 99.9-100 Earnings (n=199336): Estimate 0.171*** 0.022** 0.304** 0.413** 0.243** 0.281** 0.220** 0.162** -0.076 St. error 0.002 0.003 0.016 0.016 0.019 0.034 0.024 0.037 0.085 Income 1 (n=261248): Estimate 0.241*** 0.065** 0.390** 0.428** 0.345** 0.252** 0.288** 0.199** 0.466** St. error 0.002 0.004 0.015 0.015 0.018 0.031 0.020 0.031 0.071 1 Earnings, capital income and income transfers. ** 0.01<p<0.05, ***<0.0001. The persistence for the two measures increases along the income distribution and reaches a maximum at the P50-75 knot after which it decreases to the same levels up to the P99-P99.9 fractile in both countries. Additionally, the differentials between the income and earnings coefficients are of similar magnitude. Moreover, the overall (regression to the mean) intergenerational income elasticity is of the same magnitude in Sweden (0.260) (Björklund et al., 2012) as in Denmark (0.241). Capital income is found to be the most important channel of top income intergenerational persistence, but apparently more so in Sweden than in Denmark. A possible explanation is that inheritance of capital income and large companies over generations play a bigger role in Sweden than in Denmark given thatcapital income in Sweden constitutes a bigger share of total income in the top 0.1 % end of the distribution than in Denmark (Figure 1)and the structure of businesses is different in the two 6

countries. The largest Swedish enterprises (250+ employees) represent 41% of total value added, while the largest Danish enterprises represent relatively less value added (33%) (OECD, 2014). Figure 1. Share of capital income in Denmark and Sweden. P99.9-100 Share of total income, % 4,5 4,0 3,5 3,0 2,5 2,0 1,5 1,0 0,5 0,0 Denmark Sweden 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Source: Own calculations: Swedish data based on the The World Top Incomes Database (http://topincomes.parisschoolofeconomics.eu/) Danish data based on register data from Statistics Denmark. Hence, Sweden s largest private enterprises are bigger than their counterparts in Denmark. The inheritance of the bigger enterprise ownerships (sometimes incl. CEO positions) and capital income in the top may explain the lower top intergenerational mobility among Swedes. VI. Conclusion and Summary Here, we considered the intergenerational elasticities between fathers and sons earnings and incomes in the top end of the distributions in Denmark and compared them with findings for Sweden. We found that intergenerational elasticity is higher for income than for earnings, and that the elasticity increases with higher levels of earnings and income. For both Denmark and Sweden, 7

nonlinearities in the father-son relationships over the income distribution are found, and at the very top end of the distribution P99.9-100 the father-son income persistence in Denmark is about half the size of that in Sweden. A possible explanation for the lower intergenerational income persistence in the top end of the income distribution in Denmark compared with Sweden is an inheritance of more capital income and bigger companies in Sweden. 8

References Atkinson, A.B., Piketty, T., Saez, E., 2011. Top Incomes in the Long Run of History. Journal of Economic Literature. 49(1), 3 71. Belsley, D.A., Kuh, E., Welsch, R.E., 2005. Regression Diagnostics: Identifying Influential Data and Sources of Collinearity. John Wiley & Sons, New York. Björklund, A., Roine, J., Waldenström, D., 2012. Intergenerational top income mobility in Sweden: Capitalistic dynasties in the land of equal opportunity? Journal of Public Economics. 96(5-6), 474-484. Bratberg, E., Røed, K., Raaum, O., Naylor, R., Jäntti, M., Eriksson, T., Österbacka, E., 2007. Nonlinearities in Intergenerational Earnings Mobility: Consequences for Cross-Country Comparisons. The Economic Journal. 117(518), 72-92. Greene, W.H., 2012. Econometric Analysis. 7 th edition. Pearson, Upper Saddle River, NJ. Hendricks, L., 2007. The Intergenerational Persistence of Lifetime Earnings. European Economic Review, 51(1), 125-144. Haider, S., Solon, G., 2006. Life-Cycle Variation in the Association between Current and Lifetime Earnings. The American Economic Review. 96(4), 1308-1320. Hussain, M.A., Munk, M.D., Bonke, J., 2009. Intergenerational earnings mobilities - how sensitive are they to income measures? Journal of Income Distribution. 18(3-4), 79-92. Lee, C.-I., Solon, G., 2009. Trends in Intergenerational Income Mobility. The Review of Economics and Statistics. 91(4), 766 772. Nybom, M., Stuhler, J., 2014. Heterogeneous Income Profiles and Life-Cycle Bias in Intergenerational Mobility Estimation. Journal of Human Resources (forthcoming). OECD (2014). stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?datasetcode=sdbs_bdi. Viewed on 31 May 2014. Own calculations based on published statistics. Piketty, T. 2014., Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass.. 9

Roine, J., Waldenström, D., 2012. On the role of capital gains in Swedish income inequality. The review of income and wealth. 58(3), 569-587. Roine, J., Waldenström, D., 2015. Long-Run Trends in the Distribution of Income and Wealth, in: Atkinson, A.B., Bourguignon, F. (Eds.), Handbook of Income Distribution. Vol. 2A. Elsevier, North- Holland, Amsterdam, pp.471-592 Solon, G., 1992. Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States. The American Economic Review. 82(3), 393-408. Zimmerman, D. J., 1992. Regression Toward Mediocrity in Economic Stature. The American Economic Review. 82(3), 409-429. 10