Note. Everything in today s paper is new relative to the paper Stigler accepted

Similar documents
What the Cyclical Response of Advertising Reveals about Markups and other Macroeconomic Wedges

Reference Point May 2015

GOAL 0: GDP GROWTH. By 2028, New Brunswick will experience an upward trend that returns its GDP growth rate to 2008 levels. Status: NOT PROGRESSING

AGM Survey Results NIRI NIRI 2010 Annual Conference Onsite Survey: Annual General Meetings

Insolvency Statistics in Canada. September 2015

Two hours. To be supplied by the Examinations Office: Mathematical Formula Tables and Statistical Tables THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER

Online appendix to Understanding Weak Capital Investment: the Role of Market Concentration and Intangibles

Insolvency Statistics in Canada. April 2013

FINANCIAL RATIOS OF CANADIAN COMPANIES July 26, 2012 Alberto Calva // Acus Consulting Ltd

14.461: Technological Change, Lectures 12 and 13 Input-Output Linkages: Implications for Productivity and Volatility

Topic 3, continued. RBCs

Economic Impacts of the First 5 Placer Children & Families Commission s Funded Programs

Community Colleges of Spokane

EMPLOYEES UNDER LABOUR CONTRACT AND GROSS AVERAGE WAGES AND SALARIES, THIRD QUARTER OF 2017

Wage Scars and Human Capital Theory: Appendix

Figure 1. Gross average wages and salaries by months

EMPLOYEES UNDER LABOUR CONTRACT AND GROSS AVERAGE WAGES AND SALARIES, FOURTH QUARTER OF 2016

Two Hours. Mathematical formula books and statistical tables are to be provided THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER. 22 January :00 16:00

Economic Impact Analysis of Fort Steele National Heritage Town. Final Report. By:

Economics 826 International Finance. Final Exam: April 2007

Michigan Economic Development Corporation

Booth School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Midterm

Technical change is labor-augmenting (also known as Harrod neutral). The production function exhibits constant returns to scale:

The Secure Choice Retirement Savings Program. Compiled by the Office of the Illinois State Treasurer Treasurer Michael W. Frerichs

The Economic. Impact of Veteran-Owned. Franchise. August 30, 2011

April An Analysis of Prince Edward Island s Productivity, : Falling Multifactor Productivity Dampens Labour Productivity Growth

GOAL 6 FIRMS PARTICIPATING IN FOREIGN EXPORT TRADE

Is the Potential for International Diversification Disappearing? A Dynamic Copula Approach

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

Structural unemployment after the crisis in Austria

SELECTED ECONOMIC CHARACTERISTICS American Community Survey 5-Year Estimates

April An Analysis of Saskatchewan s Productivity, : Capital Intensity Growth Drives Strong Labour Productivity Performance CENTRE FOR

Intangible Capital: Complement or Substitute in the Creation of Public Goods?

Appendix B for Acemoglu-Guerrieri Capital Deepening and Non-Balanced Economic Growth (Not for Publication)

Modelling Environmental Extremes

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

On modelling of electricity spot price

SBA s Size Standards Analysis. An Overview on Methodology and Comprehensive Size Standards Review

South Baldwin County, Alabama (Gulf Shores, Orange Beach, Bon Secour, Elberta, and Foley) Are You Diversified?

Characterization of the Optimum

April 2011 CENTRE FOR LIVING STANDARDS. CSLS Research Report i. Christopher Ross THE STUDY OF

Modelling Environmental Extremes

Yukon Bureau of Statistics

Yukon Bureau of Statistics

Michigan Economic Development Corporation

Information aggregation for timing decision making.

April An Analysis of Nova Scotia s Productivity Performance, : Strong Growth, Low Levels CENTRE FOR LIVING STANDARDS

INDIAN INSTITUTE OF SCIENCE STOCHASTIC HYDROLOGY. Lecture -5 Course Instructor : Prof. P. P. MUJUMDAR Department of Civil Engg., IISc.

Exercises in Growth Theory and Empirics

Choice Probabilities. Logit Choice Probabilities Derivation. Choice Probabilities. Basic Econometrics in Transportation.

American Community Survey 5-Year Estimates

Michigan Economic Development Corporation

Nevada Commerce Tax Narrative. Prepared by Commerce Tax Division

Wisconsin Economic Development Corporation

Deal Stats Transaction Survey

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

1 Roy model: Chiswick (1978) and Borjas (1987)

Tell us what you think. Provide feedback to help make American Community Survey data more useful for you.

Course information FN3142 Quantitative finance

Oil Price Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell. Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions. TA: B. B. Deng

Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Entrepreneurship and Poverty Reduction in Rural America. Nicholas Kacher and Stephan Weiler

Average persons in household. Top three industries Post-secondary education (25 64 years) 7.1% Unemployment rate

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction

Financial Econometrics

Dependence Structure and Extreme Comovements in International Equity and Bond Markets

Version A. Problem 1. Let X be the continuous random variable defined by the following pdf: 1 x/2 when 0 x 2, f(x) = 0 otherwise.

EMPLOYEES UNDER LABOUR CONTRACT AND AVERAGE GROSS WAGES AND SALARIES, FOURTH QUARTER OF Figure 1. Average wages and salaries by months

Michigan Economic Development Corporation

E APPENDIX METHODOLOGY FOR LAND USE PROJECTIONS IN THE BOSTON REGION INTRODUCTION

On the Relationship between Gross Output-based TFP Growth and Value Added-based TFP Growth: An Illustration Using Data from Australian Industries

SOUTH DAKOTA KIDS COUNT BEACOM SCHOOL OF BUSINESS UNIVERSITY OF SOUTH DAKOTA 414 E. CLARK STREET VERMILLION, SD

Description of the Sample and Limitations of the Data

Rhode Island. A publication of the Labor Market Information Unit

CCAA Statistics in Canada. Third Quarter of 2017

Oxford County Labour Market Overview

Tuvalu. Key Indicators for Asia and the Pacific Item

Time Invariant and Time Varying Inefficiency: Airlines Panel Data

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

2015 HEALTH PLANS BENCHMARK SUMMARY 2

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

151 Slater Street, Suite 710 Ottawa, Ontario K1P 5H , Fax September, 2012

The Future is Here: Aging PA Taxpayers and Voters Affect Education Funding

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Percentage Change and Elasticity

**BEGINNING OF EXAMINATION** A random sample of five observations from a population is:

STATISTICS CANADA RELEASES 2016 GDP DATA

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Alaska s Non-Petroleum Corporate Income Tax. Trends in Collections by Sector and Revised Corporate Income Tax Forecast Model

PhD Qualifier Examination

Financial Economics: Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions

Risk management methodology in Latvian economics

The Graying of Hawaii s Workforce 2006

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity

Industry Overview. Austin Community College. Emsi Q Data Set. June Emsi Q Data Set

Transcription:

Note Everything in today s paper is new relative to the paper Stigler accepted

Market power Lerner index: L = p c/ y p = 1 ɛ

Market power Lerner index: L = p c/ y p = 1 ɛ Ratio of price to marginal cost, µ = p c/ y = 1 1 L = ɛ ɛ 1 which maps the Lerner index from L [0, 1] to µ [1, ]

Measuring L Demand side: Measure residual demand elasticity ɛ by some IV strategy based on an oligopoly model

Measuring L Demand side: Measure residual demand elasticity ɛ by some IV strategy based on an oligopoly model Profit margin: Stare at accounting data and decide which costs are marginal

Measuring L Demand side: Measure residual demand elasticity ɛ by some IV strategy based on an oligopoly model Profit margin: Stare at accounting data and decide which costs are marginal Empirical partial derivative: Marginal cost is the ratio of adjusted cost change to adjusted output change

Empirical partial derivative Numerator is the change in cost not associated with changes in factor prices and the denominator is the change in output not associated with the change in Hicks-neutral productivity

Empirical partial derivative Numerator is the change in cost not associated with changes in factor prices and the denominator is the change in output not associated with the change in Hicks-neutral productivity Cost is c = i p i x i

Empirical partial derivative Numerator is the change in cost not associated with changes in factor prices and the denominator is the change in output not associated with the change in Hicks-neutral productivity Cost is c = i p i x i Change in cost is dc = i x i dp i + i p i dx i

Empirical partial derivative Numerator is the change in cost not associated with changes in factor prices and the denominator is the change in output not associated with the change in Hicks-neutral productivity Cost is c = i p i x i Change in cost is dc = i x i dp i + i p i dx i The first summation is the component associated with changes in factor prices, while the second is the desired component purged of effects from changing factor prices: p i dx i i

Adjusted change in output The technology is y = A f(x) so dy y da A is output change adjusted for productivity change

Empirical marginal cost Marginal cost is the ratio of adjusted cost change to adjusted output change, i m = w i dx i dy y da/a

Empirical marginal cost Marginal cost is the ratio of adjusted cost change to adjusted output change, i m = w i dx i dy y da/a The Lerner index is so L = p m p 1 L = = 1 i w i dx i p(dy y da/a). i w i dx i p(dy y da/a)

Let Connect to the Solow residual α i = w ix i p y, the share of factor i in revenue, p y

Let Connect to the Solow residual α i = w ix i p y, the share of factor i in revenue, p y The equation can then be written ( (1 L) dy + y da ) = y A i α i dx i x i.

Let Connect to the Solow residual α i = w ix i p y, the share of factor i in revenue, p y The equation can then be written ( (1 L) dy + y da ) = y A i α i dx i x i. Dividing by y and rearranging yields a useful result, dy y i α i dx i x i = L dy y + (1 L)dA A

Relation to TFP data With discrete time, log y i α i log x i = L log y + (1 L) log A

Relation to TFP data With discrete time, log y i α i log x i = L log y + (1 L) log A This formulation is useful because the left-hand side is the Solow residual, calculated meticulously in productivity accounts

Comments If L > 0, the Solow residual does not measure actual technical progress, because it does not adjust for market power

Comments If L > 0, the Solow residual does not measure actual technical progress, because it does not adjust for market power This derivation of the measurement of L > 0 does not assume anything about optimal choice by the firm, apart from remaining on its production function. The firm is not necessarily satisfying its first-order conditions in the output market or any input market. The Lerner index does not necessarily describe the residual demand function facing the firm, effects of market power by sellers of inputs including labor unions, or monopsony power of the firm in those input markets.

Econometrics The adjusted growth rate of productivity, a = (1 L) log A, is a statistical residual in the equation. It can only be measured with knowledge of the Lerner index

Econometrics The adjusted growth rate of productivity, a = (1 L) log A, is a statistical residual in the equation. It can only be measured with knowledge of the Lerner index The most basic approach is to treat L as a parameter to be estimated in time-series or panel data, with suitable instrumental variables. Eligible instruments are variables that are uncorrelated with productivity growth but are correlated with output and inputs. The residual based on the estimated value of L is the estimated rate of true productivity growth, adjusted for market power

Add firm optimization Assume that the firm is a price-taker in all of its input markets, and the firm equates the marginal revenue product of a factor to its price

Add firm optimization Assume that the firm is a price-taker in all of its input markets, and the firm equates the marginal revenue product of a factor to its price Then the approach yields values of the true Lerner index

Price-taking The assumption that the firm is a price taker in its input markets does not mean that those market are competitive. That property is sufficient but not necessary.

Price-taking The assumption that the firm is a price taker in its input markets does not mean that those market are competitive. That property is sufficient but not necessary. The price-taking assumption would apply if a labor union or dominant seller of another input chose to exercise its market power by sticking to a fixed non-negotiable price quote

Returns to scale Notice that the assumptions do not include constant returns to scale

Returns to scale Notice that the assumptions do not include constant returns to scale But the second-order condition for profit maximization requires that the Lerner index exceed 1 1/γ, where γ is the returns-to-scale index of the production function, the elasticity of f(θx) with respect to θ, at θ = 1

Returns to scale Notice that the assumptions do not include constant returns to scale But the second-order condition for profit maximization requires that the Lerner index exceed 1 1/γ, where γ is the returns-to-scale index of the production function, the elasticity of f(θx) with respect to θ, at θ = 1 A firm with strong increasing returns and weaker market power will not satisfy the second-order condition

Monopsony in input markets Suppose the elasticity of the wage with respect to the firm s level of employment is λ. Then the observed labor share is depressed by the fact that the average wage understates the marginal wage: α = w n p y γ = (1 L) 1 + λ

Monopsony in input markets Suppose the elasticity of the wage with respect to the firm s level of employment is λ. Then the observed labor share is depressed by the fact that the average wage understates the marginal wage: α = w n p y γ = (1 L) 1 + λ This propagates through the rest of the math to the conclusion, dy y αdn n = L λ dy 1 + λ y

Monopsony in input markets Suppose the elasticity of the wage with respect to the firm s level of employment is λ. Then the observed labor share is depressed by the fact that the average wage understates the marginal wage: α = w n p y γ = (1 L) 1 + λ This propagates through the rest of the math to the conclusion, dy y αdn n = L λ dy 1 + λ y Thus the coefficient on the right side of the equation is L λ 1+λ, which is less than L for any positive value of the monopsony parameter λ

Conclusions about applicability Increasing returns to scale. The approach is robust to increasing returns

Conclusions about applicability Increasing returns to scale. The approach is robust to increasing returns Decreasing returns to scale. This occurs when factors, notably capital, involve delays, adjustment costs, or permanent restrictions. The approach is robust to decreasing returns, which will be accompanied by profit in excess of factor costs

Conclusions about applicability Increasing returns to scale. The approach is robust to increasing returns Decreasing returns to scale. This occurs when factors, notably capital, involve delays, adjustment costs, or permanent restrictions. The approach is robust to decreasing returns, which will be accompanied by profit in excess of factor costs Market power held by a seller of an input. If a seller of an input, such as a labor union, exercises its market power by setting a higher price, the approach takes account of the true marginal cost associated with that input, and the calculation uncovers the true Lerner index of the firm.

Conclusions about applicability Increasing returns to scale. The approach is robust to increasing returns Decreasing returns to scale. This occurs when factors, notably capital, involve delays, adjustment costs, or permanent restrictions. The approach is robust to decreasing returns, which will be accompanied by profit in excess of factor costs Market power held by a seller of an input. If a seller of an input, such as a labor union, exercises its market power by setting a higher price, the approach takes account of the true marginal cost associated with that input, and the calculation uncovers the true Lerner index of the firm. Monopsony power in an input market. The average price paid for the input understates the effective marginal price. The employment share is understated and the estimate of L is correspondingly understated

Data KLEMS data in the Solow productivity framework

Data KLEMS data in the Solow productivity framework Annual starting in 1987; 60 distinct non-overlapping industries

Data KLEMS data in the Solow productivity framework Annual starting in 1987; 60 distinct non-overlapping industries Advantages of the data relative to data in earlier work on production-side measurement of market power Rigorous adherence to proper measurement of output no reliance on value added Uniform use of the modern NAICS industry definitions Breakdown of inputs into 5 categories: capital, labor, energy, materials, and services Aggregation of capital and labor inputs from detailed underlying data using appropriate methods Use of Tørnqvist s refinement of the weights applied to log-changes in factor inputs

Instrumental variables log differences Military purchases of equipment Military purchases of ships Military purchases of software Military expenditure on research and development The oil price

Weighted averages across industries Lerner index Standard error Percent of value added in sector Number of industries in sector Sector name -0.13 (0.11) 5.1 3 Health Care and Social Assistance -0.05 (0.10) 0.2 1 Educational Services -0.02 (0.15) 6.5 1 Construction 0.03 (0.07) 3.9 2 Administrative and Support and Waste Management and Remediation Services 0.07 (0.12) 6.0 2 Real Estate and Rental and Leasing 0.08 (0.21) 5.2 4 Information 0.09 (0.39) 1.4 3 0.10 (0.43) 2.7 1 Utilities Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 0.16 (0.26) 2.4 1 Management of Companies and Enterprises 0.19 (0.09) 4.1 8 Transportation and Warehousing 0.21 (0.06) 21.3 18 Manufacturing 0.21 (0.10) 7.0 1 Wholesale Trade 0.23 (0.10) 9.0 3 Professional, Scientific, and Technical Services 0.25 (0.17) 2.8 1 Other Services (except Public Administration) 0.28 (0.28) 8.5 4 Finance and Insurance 0.29 (0.17) 1.0 2 Arts, Entertainment, and Recreation 0.31 (0.15) 8.0 1 Retail Trade 0.35 (0.09) 3.1 2 Accommodation and Food Services 0.46 (0.64) 1.7 2 Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting

Sampling variation 30 percent of the industries have negative values of the estimated Lerner index, L i even though the true value of L cannot be negative

Sampling variation 30 percent of the industries have negative values of the estimated Lerner index, L i even though the true value of L cannot be negative The statistical model is L = L + η where L is distributed as beta(ν, β), with density proportional to L ν 1 (1 L) β 1

Sampling variation 30 percent of the industries have negative values of the estimated Lerner index, L i even though the true value of L cannot be negative The statistical model is L = L + η where L is distributed as beta(ν, β), with density proportional to L ν 1 (1 L) β 1 The measurement error η i accounts for the residual distribution of the measured index

Four assumptions identify the model: 1. The true value of the Lerner index obeys the beta distribution, so it is between zero and one 2. The second shape parameter of the beta distribution of the true Lerner index is β = 8, a reasonable family 3. The two components are statistically independent, a standard assumption 4. The mean of the measurement error η is zero, another standard assumption

The Family of Beta Distributions with Second Shape Parameter = 8 0.14 ν = 0.5 0.12 0.1 ν = 1.0 0.08 0.06 ν = 1.5 0.04 ν = 2.0 0.02 0 0.05 0.15 0.25 0.35 0.45 0.55

The desired untangling is possible Identification Theorem: The mean of the measured Lerner index identifies the first shape parameter of the beta distribution of the true Lerner index; the distribution of the measurement error η is identified by solving a convolution problem

Moments of the Distribution of the Estimated Lerner Index, and Inferred Properties of the Distributions of the True Index and the Error in Measurement Moments of estimated Lerner indexes across industries Shape parameter of true Lerner index Moments of true Lerner indexes across industries Moments of measurement errors Mean 0.15 Stan. dev. 0.31 Skewness -1.84 α 1.36 Mean 0.15 Stan. dev. 0.11 Skewness 1.14 Mean 0.00 Stan. dev. 0.29 Skewness -2.30

Inferred Distributions of True Lerner Index across Industries 5.0 4.5 4.0 Probability density 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 Distribution of true value across industries 1.0 0.5 0.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 Lerner index

Actual Cumulative Frequencies of Estimates and Calculated Cumulative Distribution Functions from the Statistical Model Cumulative frequency 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 Fitted Actual 0.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 Measured Lerner index including sampling error

The change in the Lerner index over time Extend the specification to include an industry-specific linear time trend: log y t i α i,t x i,t = (φ i + ψ i t) log y t a t

Weighted averages across industries Growth coefficient, ψ Standard error Sector name -0.111 (0.061) Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction -0.021 (0.011) Retail Trade -0.021 (0.011) Wholesale Trade -0.010 (0.011) Professional, Scientific, and Technical Services -0.001 (0.010) Educational Services 0.001 (0.009) Transportation and Warehousing 0.001 (0.007) Manufacturing 0.001 (0.008) Accommodation and Food Services 0.004 (0.028) Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 0.006 (0.015) Other Services (except Public Administration) 0.006 (0.007) Administrative and Support and Waste Management and Remediation Services 0.013 (0.014) Arts, Entertainment, and Recreation 0.015 (0.024) Management of Companies and Enterprises 0.017 (0.016) Construction 0.017 (0.016) Information 0.018 (0.010) Real Estate and Rental and Leasing 0.019 (0.007) Health Care and Social Assistance 0.036 (0.109) Utilities 0.064 (0.035) Finance and Insurance

Evidence about the Statistical Reliability of the Finding of an Upward Trend in the Markup Ratio Weighted average of estimate of trend ψ 0.0061 Standard error 0.0051 t -statistic for hypothesis ψ = 0 1.20 p- value, one-tailed 0.11

Implied Values of the Lerner index by Year 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 1988 1993 1998 2003 2008 2013

Employment at mega-firms SUSB database compiled from business census data

Employment at mega-firms SUSB database compiled from business census data 19 NAICS sectors beginning in 1998

NAICS Description Employment, 2015, millions Mega-firm ratio in 1998 Mega-firm ratio in 2015 Change 11 Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 0.2 0.045 0.038-0.007 21 Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 0.7 0.208 0.161-0.047 22 Utilities 0.6 0.335 0.478 0.143 23 Construction 6.0 0.027 0.044 0.018 31-33 Manufacturing 11.6 0.271 0.220-0.051 42 Wholesale Trade 6.1 0.156 0.195 0.038 44-45 Retail Trade 15.7 0.416 0.531 0.115 48-49 Transportation and Warehousing 4.6 0.369 0.424 0.055 51 Information 3.4 0.491 0.483-0.008 52 Finance and Insurance 6.1 0.418 0.419 0.001 53 Real Estate and Rental and Leasing 2.1 0.132 0.132-0.001 54 Professional, Scientific, and Technical Services 8.8 0.161 0.228 0.067 55 Management of Companies and Enterprises 3.3 0.542 0.485-0.057 56 Administrative and Support and Waste Management 11.1 0.296 0.374 0.079 and Remediation Services 61 Educational Services 3.6 0.141 0.172 0.030 62 Health Care and Social Assistance 19.2 0.190 0.245 0.054 71 Arts, Entertainment, and Recreation 2.2 0.118 0.149 0.031 72 Accommodation and Food Services 13.2 0.210 0.200-0.009 81 Other Services (except Public Administration) 5.4 0.052 0.044-0.007 Weighted average 0.253 0.286 0.034

Ratio of Employment in Mega-Firms to Total Sectoral Employment, 1998 through 2015 0.6 Ratio of mega firm employment to toal sectoral employment 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013

Relation between Employment in Mega-Firms and the Ratio of Price to Marginal Cost, µ 2.0 1.5 Lerner Index for Sector 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 Sector's fraction of employment in mega firms

Slope Coefficients for the Relation between Employment in Mega-Firms and the Trend Coefficient for the Lerner Index Left-hand variable Estimated Lerner index Estimated Lerner index trend coefficient, ψ Right-hand variable Level of megafirm ratio Change in mega-firm ratio Slope, standard error, and 1- tail p value 0.12 (0.15) 0.21 0.045 (0.049) 0.18

Relation between the Change in Employment in Mega-Firms and the Trend Coefficient for the Lerner Index, ψ 0.11 Estimated trend coefficient in sector, ψ 0.06 0.01 0.04 0.09 0.14 0.10 0.05 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 Change in sector's fraction of employment in mega firms