Volume Title: Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment. Volume Author/Editor: Jeffrey Brown, Jeffrey Liebman and David A.

Similar documents
HOW DOES 401(K) AUTO-ENROLLMENT RELATE TO THE EMPLOYER MATCH AND TOTAL COMPENSATION?

Automatic enrollment: The power of the default

Do Defaults Have Spillover Effects? The Effect of the Default Asset on Retirement Plan Contributions

DO INDIVIDUALS KNOW WHEN THEY SHOULD BE SAVING FOR A SPOUSE?

How America Saves Small business edition Vanguard Retirement Plan Access TM supplement to How America Saves

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default

Making the Most of Your Match

Defaults and Behavioral Outcomes

How are preferences revealed?

Does Borrowing Undo Automatic Enrollment s Effect on Savings?

Target-date fund adoption in 2014

A NUDGE ISN T ALWAYS ENOUGH

Investor comprehension and usage of target-date funds: 2010 survey

Using Lessons from Behavioral Finance for Better Retirement Plan Design

PPI Briefing Note Number 99 (PhD Series No 2) Page 1

Volume Title: Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment. Volume Author/Editor: Jeffrey Brown, Jeffrey Liebman and David A.

Behavioral effects and indexing in DC participant accounts

Vanguard Research February 2016

Research Report. The Population of Workers Covered by the Auto IRA: Trends and Characteristics. AARP Public Policy Institute.

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Introduction to "Pensions in the U.S. Economy"

Borrowing to Save? The Impact of Automatic Enrollment on Debt

Policy Considerations in Annuitizing Individual Pension Accounts

Stretching the match: Unintended effects on plan contributions

Technology firms Industry benchmark data supplement to How America Saves

SPRING Behavioral Finance Research Digest for plan sponsors and their advisors

ASSESSING AMERICANS FINANCIAL AND RETIREMENT SECURITY

Worker Participation in Employer-Sponsored Pensions: A Fact Sheet

Target-date fund adoption in 2013

CRS Report for Congress

All findings, interpretations, and conclusions of this presentation represent the views of the author(s) and not those of the Wharton School or the

Some Considerations for Empirical Research on Tax-Preferred Savings Accounts.

Chapter URL:

Opting out of Retirement Plan Default Settings

THE IMPACT OF LEAKAGES ON 401(K)/IRA ASSETS

Legal services firms Industry benchmark data supplement to How America Saves

Manufacturing firms Industry benchmark data supplement to How America Saves

The Downside of Defaults

Architecture and engineering firms Industry benchmark data supplement to How America Saves

Retirement funding is at a crossroads. For many years, Why Income Should Be the Outcome of a Defined Contribution Plan. Retirement

Irrational people and rational needs for optimal pension plans

Expectations for Retirement: A Survey of Retirement Investors

John Beshears James J. Choi David Laibson Brigitte C. Madrian Jung Sakong. June 20, 2012

OVER THE PAST TWO DECADES THERE HAS BEEN

THE IMPORTANCE OF DEFAULT OPTIONS FOR RETIREMENT SAVING OUTCOMES: EVIDENCE FROM THE UNITED STATES

BORROWING TO SAVE? UNINTENDED CONSEQUENCES OF AUTOMATIC ENROLLMENT

The Limitations of Defaults

Ambulatory health care services Industry benchmark data supplement to How America Saves

Volume Title: The Effects of Taxation on Capital Accumulation. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press

INCREASING FINANCIAL SECURITY WITH WORKPLACE EMERGENCY SAVINGS

Technology firms 2018

WikiLeaks Document Release

Finance and insurance firms 2018

Legal services firms 2018

Vanguard research August 2015

Information firms 2018

Personalized Retirement Advice and Managed Accounts: Who Uses Them and How Does Advice Affect Behavior in 401(k) Plans?

White Paper on Retirement Highlights Importance of Annuities

Selected Characteristics of Savings and Thrift Plans for Private Industry Workers

TDF adoption in Vanguard Research Note February Introduction

The Financial Literacy Initiative. Annamaria Lusardi (Dartmouth College andnber)

Behavioral Economics and Behavior Change

Small business edition

How America Saves A report on Vanguard 2012 defined contribution plan data

CAN THE ENROLLMENT EXPERIENCE IMPROVE PARTICIPANT OUTCOMES?

Who Uses the Roth 401(k), and How Do They Use It?

Towards a Sustainable Retirement Plan VII

Vanguard s approach to target-date funds

The Benefits of. Presented By:

Written. Before the. Regarding. September 2009

Ambulatory health care services 2018

BeFi Web Seminar for April 30, BeFi Conference Summary. by Shlomo Benartzi Co-Founder, Behavioral Finance Forum

HOW DO INHERITANCES AFFECT THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX?

Portfolio Choice in Retirement: Health Risk and the Demand for Annuities, Housing, and Risky Assets

Volume Author/Editor: Benjamin M. Friedman, ed. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press. Volume URL:

Volume Title: International Taxation and Multinational Activity. Volume URL:

Vanguard s Principles for Financing Retirement

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

Measuring Retirement Plan Effectiveness

Achieving better diversification through reenrollment in a QDIA

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings

LESSONS FROM BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS FOR PROMOTING RETIREMENT INCOME SECURITY

Tax Reform Options: Promoting Retirement Security. Testimony Submitted to United States Senate Committee on Finance. September 15, 2011

Volume Author/Editor: John Y. Campbell and Martin Feldstein, editors. Volume URL:

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Employees' Knowledge of Their Pension Plans

Volume Title: Corporate Profits as Shown by Audit Reports. Volume URL:

USING PARTICIPANT DATA TO IMPROVE 401(k) ASSET ALLOCATION

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

All findings, interpretations, and conclusions of this presentation represent the views of the author(s) and not those of the Wharton School or the

Six Simple Steps: Reforming the Illinois State Universities Retirement System

401(k) PLANS ARE STILL COMING UP SHORT

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research. Volume Title: Tax Policy and the Economy, Volume 20

center for retirement research

Menu Choices in Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Vanguard s approach to target-date funds

The Digital Investor Patterns in digital adoption

Retirement Savings: How Much Will Workers Have When They Retire?

Vanguard Research May 2014

LEARNING FROM BRITAIN S NEXT STEP IN PRIVATIZING SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS

Getting Beyond Ordinary MANAGING PLAN COSTS IN AUTOMATIC PROGRAMS

Age-dependent or target-driven investing?

Transcription:

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment Volume Author/Editor: Jeffrey Brown, Jeffrey Liebman and David A. Wise, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 978-0-226-07648-5 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/brow08-1 Conference Date: October 19-22, 2006 Publication Date: June 2009 Chapter Title: Comment on "The Importance of Default Options for Retirement Saving Outcomes: Evidence from the United States" Chapter Author: Jeffrey R. Brown Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c4540 Chapter pages in book: (195-198)

The Importance of Default Options for Retirement Saving Outcomes 195 U.S. Department of Labor, Employee Benefits Security Administration. 2005. Private pension plan bulletin. http://www.dol.gov/ebsa/pdf/2000pensionplanbulletin.pdf. Utkus, Stephen P. 2002. A recent successful test of the SMarT program. Valley Forge, PA: Vanguard Center for Retirement Research. Utkus, Stephen P. and Jean A. Young. 2004. Lessons from behavioral finance and the autopilot 401(k). Valley Forge, PA: Vanguard Center for Retirement Research. The Vanguard Group. 2001. Automatic enrollment: Vanguard client experience. Valley Forge, PA: The Vanguard Group. Comment Jeffrey R. Brown This chapter provides powerful evidence about a deceptively simple idea: defaults matter. The chapter nicely summarizes the large and growing literature (the lion s share of which was authored by various combinations of the current authors) about the power of default options to influence a wide range of behaviors related to retirement security. Specifically, the authors provide evidence about how defaults influence behavior along every major dimension of the financial planning process related to retirement, including: (1) the decision of whether to participate in a 401(k) plan; (2) how much to contribute, conditional on participating; (3) what portfolio allocation to choose for those contributions; (4) what to do with the money when one leaves an employer; and (5) how to withdraw the money at retirement. The foundation for this chapter is a large set of individual research projects that analyze a variety of natural or designed experiments to determine the effect of default options on individual behavior. To varying degrees, the underlying studies are individually compelling. Taken as a whole, the combined evidence is undeniable and overwhelming. After providing this careful review of the existing evidence, the authors then explore several potential explanations for why defaults have such a strong effect on individual behavior, in contrast to the standard neoclassical model. These explanations include the following: 1. There are low average levels of financial literacy. Many studies indicate that most U.S. citizens are unable to correctly answer fairly basic questions about investment characteristics, such as whether a money market fund holds stocks or whether an individual employer s stock is more or less risky than a diversified stock fund. Jeffrey R. Brown is the William G. Karnes Professor of Finance at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

196 John Beshears, James J. Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian 2. Individuals view the default option as an endorsement, that is, as implicit investment advice from the plan sponsor. 3. Defaults provide a shortcut through the tremendous complexity facing individuals trying to make these decisions on their own. 4. Individuals are biased toward the present, and defaults help them to circumvent procrastination. My suspicion is that all of these factors matter both individually and in combination. Nonetheless, the logical next step in this literature is to determine the relative importance of these factors and whether that ranking is the same in all contexts. Understanding the underlying determinants is of more than academic interest it is also important for assessing whether there are other interventions that may influence behavior and possibly lead individuals to make more active decisions that may improve individual welfare. The role of default options is particularly important in the context of retirement planning for at least two reasons. First, developing an optimal life-cycle savings and investment plan is extremely complex, particularly when one accounts for the many sources of uncertainty that one faces (e.g., earnings, rates of return, inflation, health status, medical expenditures, and longevity). The advice of experts is not necessarily the solution to the complexity problem, given the numerous and conflicting sources of investment advice available in the marketplace. Second, unlike many other contexts where one can learn by doing, the opportunity to learn from one s mistakes is limited in this context. The reason is that an individual may not realize their mistakes until it is too late to fix them. For example, it does one little good to learn at age seventy that they should have saved more at age fifty. The authors suggest that the alternative to a default option is to enforce an active decision. My view differs in a subtle way: even with active decision enforcement, there is still a default option. The default is to simply accept whatever penalty or punishment is meted out for a failure to actively decide. More important than the semantics is that the active decision enforcement approach still does not overcome some of the problems that led to the power of defaults in the first place, such as problems associated with a lack of knowledge or the inability of some to grapple with the complexity of the choice set. Thus, my own conclusion from this chapter and the underlying literature is that there is always a default option (although it is not always well-specified) and that intelligent policy design must, therefore, pay careful attention to the behavior that the default will engender. Perhaps out of modesty, the authors do not discuss in this chapter just how influential and pervasive the idea that defaults matter has become in policy circles over the past few years. For example, only in current decade has it become standard for analyses of Social Security personal ac-

The Importance of Default Options for Retirement Saving Outcomes 197 count reform proposals to explicitly distinguish whether participation in the personal accounts is on an opt-in or an opt-out basis, largely because policymakers and analysts now understand that this distinction will likely lead to significantly different participation rates. As another example, the Pension Protection Act, which was signed into law in August 2006, includes numerous changes to the nation s pension laws that are designed to pave the way for employers to adopt automatic enrollment in 401(k) and similar plans. In a related effort, the Department of Labor proposed new regulations in September 2006 that will set the framework that plan sponsors must work within when determining the investment portfolio that individuals can be defaulted into when they are automatically enrolled in a 401(k) plan. There is little question in my mind that the academic literature on the power of defaults has helped generate a tremendous (and largely bipartisan) enthusiasm for automatic enrollment approaches in the discussion of retirement policy in the United States. Looking to the future, the one area of this body of work that has received the least attention, at least relative to its importance to overall retirement security, is the payout phase. The importance of this area is underscored by the large literature exploring the large potential welfare gains from annuitization. A basic empirical fact about the private pension system in the United States is that the vast majority of 401(k) plans do not even offer plan participants an option to annuitize their accounts at retirement. In other words, the current default option is to leave wealth in an unannuitized form. My normative judgment (which has been influenced by the annuities literature) is that this is a suboptimal default option because it leaves individuals suboptimally exposed to longevity risk. Designing an annuitized default option for the payout phase poses a more difficult policy challenge than most other aspects of the retirement planning process, however, because of the irreversible nature of most existing annuity products. For example, we know that there will always be some individuals for whom an annuity is not an attractive option, such as those who are terminally ill or those with very strong bequest motives. If these individuals are automatically annuitized at retirement, their welfare could be substantially reduced if there is no way for them to undo the annuity contract once they have entered into it. This makes the downside risk of being defaulted into an annuity much larger than the downside of being automatically enrolled into a 401(k) plan, which can easily be reversed if the individual later decides to do so. These difficulties, however, should not lead one to think that no annuitization is the better default. For example, one could imagine designing a default with two features. First, make the annuitization gradual, or laddered, such as by converting 20 percent of the account balance into an annuity each year for five years. In addition to helping to smooth out asset price and interest rate fluctuations, such an approach gives an individual

198 John Beshears, James J. Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian the opportunity to opt out of the annuity on at least part of their wealth. If a person had 20 percent of their wealth automatically annuitized, this would focus the mind on the benefits and costs of doing so. At that point, if they realize that full annuitization is not optimal, they can avoid it on the remaining 80 percent of wealth. A second feature would be to allow a limited period of reversibility, such as 6 months after annuitization. Reversibility would allow individuals an opportunity to undo the annuitization if they were opted in and subsequently realized they did not want this. Keeping the time period short would limit the selection costs and administrative costs that such an approach would impose on the system. In summary, the body of evidence discussed in this chapter makes it clear that default options matter at nearly every step in the financial planning process. Going forward, the research agenda in this area should seek to distinguish between the alternative hypotheses for why defaults matter. With this knowledge in hand, policymakers and plan designers will be able to more finely tune the policy levers that may increase average welfare of plan participants.