Unifying Volatility Models

Similar documents
Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Principal Component Analysis of the Volatility Smiles and Skews. Motivation

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

Exploring Volatility Derivatives: New Advances in Modelling. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

1. What is Implied Volatility?

No-Arbitrage Conditions for the Dynamics of Smiles

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Interest Rate Volatility

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting MarketAFA, Disruptions 1/7/ / 14

Hedging under Model Uncertainty

Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

LOGNORMAL MIXTURE SMILE CONSISTENT OPTION PRICING

Market models for the smile Local volatility, local-stochastic volatility

The stochastic calculus

"Pricing Exotic Options using Strong Convergence Properties

A New Framework for Analyzing Volatility Risk and Premium Across Option Strikes and Expiries

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

Risk managing long-dated smile risk with SABR formula

Rough Heston models: Pricing, hedging and microstructural foundations

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Stochastic Volatility and Jump Modeling in Finance

Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Unified Credit-Equity Modeling

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Beta stochastic volatility model. Artur Sepp Bank of America Merrill Lynch, London

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Valuation of Volatility Derivatives. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 2005 Paris May 24, 2005

Developments in Volatility Derivatives Pricing

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 9: LOCAL AND STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

Lecture 11: Stochastic Volatility Models Cont.

Quadratic hedging in affine stochastic volatility models

A Closed-form Solution for Outperfomance Options with Stochastic Correlation and Stochastic Volatility

DELTA HEDGING VEGA RISK?

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Modeling the Implied Volatility Surface. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives and Risk Management 2003 Barcelona May 22, 2003

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/ / 24

A Consistent Pricing Model for Index Options and Volatility Derivatives

Empirical Approach to the Heston Model Parameters on the Exchange Rate USD / COP

Modeling and Pricing of Variance Swaps for Local Stochastic Volatilities with Delay and Jumps

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Calibration of SABR Stochastic Volatility Model. Copyright Changwei Xiong November last update: October 17, 2017 TABLE OF CONTENTS

Changing Probability Measures in GARCH Option Pricing Models

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Consistently Modeling Joint Dynamics of Volatility and Underlying To Enable Effective Hedging

A Lower Bound for Calls on Quadratic Variation

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

Volatility Surfaces: Theory, Rules of Thumb, and Empirical Evidence

Financial Times Series. Lecture 6

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

The Black-Scholes Model

Implied Volatility Correlations

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Lecture 2: Rough Heston models: Pricing and hedging

Stochastic Volatility Modeling

Analytical Option Pricing under an Asymmetrically Displaced Double Gamma Jump-Diffusion Model

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Models

7.1 Volatility Simile and Defects in the Black-Scholes Model

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Option P&L Attribution and Pricing

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

GARCH Options in Incomplete Markets

Smile in the low moments

Time-changed Brownian motion and option pricing

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

A Brief Introduction to Stochastic Volatility Modeling

LOG-SKEW-NORMAL MIXTURE MODEL FOR OPTION VALUATION

Pricing and hedging with rough-heston models

ARCH and GARCH models

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Skew Hedging. Szymon Borak Matthias R. Fengler Wolfgang K. Härdle. CASE-Center for Applied Statistics and Economics Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin

Stochastic Volatility

Risk Neutral Measures

Implied Volatility Modelling

INTEREST RATES AND FX MODELS

MLEMVD: A R Package for Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Multivariate Diffusion Models

AN INVITATION TO MARKET-BASED OPTION PRICING AND ITS APPLICATIONS

Linearity-Generating Processes, Unspanned Stochastic Volatility, and Interest-Rate Option Pricing

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Stochastic Volatility

On modelling of electricity spot price

Multiscale Stochastic Volatility Models Heston 1.5

Consistent Pricing and Hedging of an FX Options Book

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Nicola Fusari

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

ESTIMATION OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS: MARKET VS. REPRESENTATIVE AGENT THEORY

18. Diffusion processes for stocks and interest rates. MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, References for this Lecture:

Managing Systematic Mortality Risk in Life Annuities: An Application of Longevity Derivatives

Credit-Equity Modeling under a Latent Lévy Firm Process

Transcription:

The University of Reading THE BUSINESS SCHOOL FOR FINANCIAL MARKETS Unifying Volatility Models Carol Alexander (Co-authored works with E. Lazar and L. Nogueira) ISMA Centre, University of Reading Email: c.alexander@ismacentre.rdg.ac.uk Pdfs: www.ismacentre.rdg.ac.uk/alexander Newton Institute, Cambridge, May 2005

I Stochastic Local Volatility 2

Model Acronyms BS: Black-Scholes SV: Stochastic Volatility LV: Local Volatility SD: Sticky Delta ST: Sticky Tree SIV: Scale Invariant Volatility SLV: Stochastic Local Volatility SABR: Stochastic Alpha-Beta-Rho CEV: Constant Elasticity of Variance MM: Market Model of implied volatility 3

Claim Characteristics : k: claim strike T: maturity of claim Notation Model Price of Claim : f = f s, σ, λ s k,t k,t ( ) 0 0 0 : underlying price at time 0 0 σ : instantaneous volatility at time 0 0 λ0: vector of volatility parameters at time t0 t 0 : calibration time t t 4

Scale Invariant Volatility (SIV) s 1 f, σ, λ = f s, σ, λ k k ( ) 0 1,T 0 0 k,t 0 0 0 s 0 k s 0 /k 1 t 0 T time t 0 T time 5

Which Models are Scale Invariant? Most stochastic volatility models: even if price and/or volatility driven by Levy process Local volatility models: but only sticky delta models, not sticky tree models All BS mixture models, e.g.: Merton s (1976) jump diffusion Brigo-Mercurio s (2001) normal mixture diffusion 6

Example: Stochastic Volatility (SV) Heston (1993) is SIV: ds S ( ) σ( ) = r q dt + t db ( ) ( 2 2 2 2 ( ) ( ) )( ) d σ = 1 ς ρξ + ψ ς 1 ς ξ ω σ dt + ξσdz < db,dz > = ρdt SABR Hagan et al. (2002) is not SIV (unless β = 0): ds β = ( r q) dt + αs db S dα = ζ dz α < db,dz > = ρdt 7

Example: Local Volatility (LV) Dupire (1993), Derman and Kani (1994), Rubinstein (1994): ds ( r q) dt σ( t,s ) db S = + LV is SIV σ t,s is a function of time and S/S 0 only. However many parametric deterministic functions σ t,s have the sticky delta property that implied volatility is a function of delta and residual time to maturity only: σ 2 ( t,s ) t = T,s = k ( ) f 2 T = f + ( r q) k + q f k 2 2 f k 2 k S θk,t ( t,s ) = θ,t t k ( ) Sticky Delta (SD) models are SIV, Sticky Tree (ST) models are not SIV. 8

Relationship Between SV & LV σ 0 σ( t,s ) Equivalent Local Volatility Surface t T S(t)=s t 0 σ s 0 2 2 ( ) =E σ ( ) ( ) t,s t S t = s 9

Scale Invariance of Local Volatility How does σ 0 change as we change s 0? σ( t,s ) t T σ 0 S(t )=s Consider the local volatility curve at time t that is equivalent to a scale invariant SV model: t 0 s 0 10

Independence of σ 0 and S 0 ( t ) σ =E σ is the conditional expectation at 2 2 0 un t 0 σ( t,s ) S S/k σ 0 The local volatility depends only on the ratio S/S 0 (and time) Hence when we change the calibration value of S, the local volatility surface moves as shown Hence σ 0 is independent of S 0 S 11

Stochastic Local Volatility (SLV) Dupire (1996), Kani, Derman & Kamal (1997) Local variance calibrated at time t 0 < t expectation of a stochastic instantaneous variance: Q ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) 2 2 2 L = = I 0 t = I0 Ω σ t, s E [σ t,s, x S t s, ]= σ t,s, x h xs t s, dx where x = x(t, S ) is a vector of all sources of uncertainty that influence the instantaneous volatility process. t 12

Parametric Stochastic Local Volatility Alexander & Nogueira (2004) studies the general parametric form: ds S ( ) σ ( λ ) = r q dt + t,s, db ( λ ) ( λ ) d λ = µ t, dt + ζ t, dz i i i i < dz,db > = ρ dt < dz,dz > = ρ dt i is i j ij Usual regularity conditions for drift and volatility in the parameter diffusions Strict no-arbitrage conditions 13

Example: CEV-SLV & SABR Model An example of a SLV model is the CEV-SLV: ds β = ( r q) dt + αs db S dα = ζ dz α < db,dz > = ρdt Same parameterization as SABR model! Different no-arbitrage conditions 14

Equivalence with Market Model (MM) Schönbucher (1999): market model of implied volatilities This has the same implied volatility dynamics as the general SLV model n d θ = ξ dt + ψ db + ζ dz Hence the SLV and MM models have the same claim prices and hedge ratios k,t k,t k,t j,k,t j j = 1 But MM has many option specific parameters 15

II Hedging: Theoretical and Empirical Results 16

Hedging with SIV Models Proposition : When a model has been calibrated to the market implied volatilty surface: S0 fk,t ( S 0, σ0, λ0 ) = k f 1,T, σ0, λ0 k S0 θk,t ( S 0, σ0, λ0 ) = θ1,t, σ 0, λ0 k θ S k,t 0 : model implied volatility, calibrated at time : underlying price at the calibration time t 0 17

Proof S0 fk,t ( S 0, σ0, λ0 ) = k f 1,T, σ0, λ0 k f k,t fk,t ( S 0, σ0, λ0 ) = S0 + k S θk,t k θ = S S k 0 0 k,t S 0 θk,t = θ1,t, σ 0, λ0 k 0 f k,t k Euler s Theorem Differentiate f k,t w.r.t S 0 f BS k,t and k : Trivial BS S0 S0 : f 1,T, θk,t f 1,T, σ0, λ0 k k see Fouque et al. (2000). 18

SIV Partial Price Sensitivities are Model Free fk,t fk,t ( S 0, σ0, λ0 ) = S0 + k S 0 2 2 2 k,t 1 k,t k,t k k,t = S0 fk,t k and = 2 2 S0 k S0 S0 k f Partial price sensitivities obtained directly from market data! Hence the only differences in partial price sensitivities, between all SIV models, is in their fit to the smile!!!! k,t k f f f f 19

Relationship with BS Delta We can relate the first (and second) order partial price sensitivities to the BS delta (and gamma): Calibration to smile means setting f k,t f BS k,t Differentiating this: BS BS k,t k,t k,t k,t f f f θ = + S S θ S 0 0 k,t 0 But in any SIV model Hence: f k θ S S k k,t BS BS = δk,t νk,t 0 0 θk,t k θ = S S k 0 0 k,t k,t Slope of smile 20

Models with Model Free Delta In deterministic volatility models, delta partial price sensitivity This holds for SD and deterministic mixture models But these models are also SIV Hence their delta (and gamma) are model free. Conclusions: 1. All of the SD and deterministic mixture models have the same delta (and gamma) 2. This delta is inappropriate in most equity markets 21

Sticky Tree (ST) Delta Sticky tree models are not scale invariant, indeed f f S,, S k ST k,t k,t k,t k,t 0 ( σ λ ) = + S 0 0 0 0 0 S0 k ST BS BS k,t k,t k,t δ = δ ν k S θ ST ST ST k,t k f ST f k,t σ + σ S 0 0 0 0 f σ σ S 0 0 Model Free < 0 in Equity 22

SV Delta At time t > t 0 : ( ) SV SV SV k, T k, T k, T df t, S,σ f f σ = + ds S σ S We define delta at the calibration time t 0 as: δ SV k, T ( t, S,σ) Example: Heston model SV SV k, T k, T SV k, T df f f = lim = + t t ds S σ 0 0 0 t = t 0 lim t t σ S δ SV k, T SV SV 1 SV f k, T f, 0 k, T ξρ k T + 2 k σ0 = S f k ξ: vol of vol ρ: price-vol correlation Model Free < 0 in Equity 23

SLV Delta Delta is the standard local volatility delta, but adjusted for stochastic movements in local volatility surface: δ SLV k,t LV βiρi = δk,t + i σs LV,S f k,t 0 λ i Similar adjustments for gamma and theta Bias and efficiency? Both δ LV and δ SLV delta hedged portfolios have zero expectation but δ SLV hedged portfolio has smaller hedging error variance. Hence SLV model may be useful for hedging 24

Summary of Deltas Model Model Delta BS Delta Model Delta Sticky Delta & Mixtures 1 f S0 fk,t k k k,t Model Free ν BS k,t k S 0 θ k,t k Sticky Tree f S f k f σ 1 k,t k,t 0 BS 0 k, T + ν k,t k σ0 s0 S0 k θ k,t k f σ k,t σ s 0 0 0 Stochastic Volatility S 1 0 f k, T f k, T f k + k σ k, T σ lim S k θk, T f lim S k S k, T σ t t k, T 0 t = t 0 0 0 σ t t t = t0 ν BS Stochastic Local Volatility: Sticky Delta Stochastic Local Volatility: Sticky Tree 1 fk,t ζ ρ S0 fk,t k + k i σs i i,s f k,t BS k θk,t ζiρi,s f k, T νk, T 0 λ s i 0 k i σs0 λi 1 fk,t fk,t σ ζ ρ 0 i i,s fk,t S 0 fk,t k BS k θk,t f σ ζ ρ f 0 + + νk,t k σ0 S0 i σs0 λ S0 k σ0 s0 i σs0 λ i k,t i i,s k,t i 25

Empirical Results Data on June 2004 European options on SP500: Daily close prices from 02 Jan 2004 to 15 June 2004 (111 business days) Strikes from 1005 to 1200 (i.e. 34 different strikes) All strikes within ±10% of index level used for daily calibration 1180 SP500 Future 1160 1140 1120 1100 1080 16-Jan-04 30-Jan-04 13-Feb-04 27-Feb-04 12-Mar-04 26-Mar-04 09-Apr-04 23-Apr-04 07-May-04 21-May-04 04-Jun-04 26

Hedging Race 7 Models 1. Black & Scholes (BS) 2. Sticky Delta (CEV) 3. Normal Mixture (NM) 4. Sticky Tree (CEV_LV) 5. Heston (SQRT) 6. SABR (CEV_SLV) 7. NM with stochastic parameters: (NM_SLV) 2 Strategies 1. Delta Neutral: Short one call on each strike and delta hedge with underlying 2. Delta-Gamma Neutral: Buy 1125 strike to zero gamma then delta hedge Rebalance daily from 16 Jan 2004 onwards (100 business days) assuming zero transactions costs 27

1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 Comparison of Delta 28 K/S 0.905 0.915 0.925 0.935 0.945 0.955 0.965 0.975 0.985 0.995 1.005 1.015 1.025 1.035 1.045 1.055 1.065 1.075 1.085 1.095 CEV delta NM delta CEV_LV delta SQRT delta BS delta

1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 29 K/S 0.905 0.915 0.925 0.935 0.945 0.955 0.965 0.975 0.985 0.995 1.005 1.015 1.025 1.035 1.045 1.055 1.065 1.075 1.085 1.095 Comparison of Delta CEV_SLV delta NM_SLV delta CEV_LV delta SQRT delta BS delta

Hedged Portfolio P&L Stats Average Std.Dev. Skewness XS Kurtosis Delta Hedge CEV_ST 0.1462 0.5847-0.3424 0.7820 SQRT 0.1370 0.6103-0.5705 1.6737 CEV_SLV 0.1393 0.6280-0.5701 1.6041 NM_SLV 0.1399 0.6329-0.5224 1.2351 BS 0.1401 0.7451-0.7029 2.0370 CEV 0.1367 1.1035-0.6525 1.6691 SI 0.1446 1.1448-0.5395 1.3708 NM 0.1373 1.1788-0.5928 1.4834 Delta-Gamma Hedge BS -0.0014 0.2612-0.4353 2.5297 CEV_ST 0.0098 0.2691-0.0291 3.0850 NM_SLV 0.0182 0.2773 0.1673 3.2069 SQRT 0.0111 0.2789 0.1929 3.6019 CEV_SLV 0.0154 0.2832 0.1304 4.1414 CEV 0.0382 0.4102 0.2501 4.0340 SI 0.0370 0.4205 0.1438 3.7003 NM 0.0428 0.4548 0.0208 4.0123 30

III GARCH from Discrete to Continuous Time 31

GARCH(1,1) Bollerslev (1986) Generalized Engle s (1982) ARCH model to GARCH(1,1): ε ( ) ln S /S = µ + ε t t 1 t 2 t t 1 0 σt I ~ N(, ) 2 2 2 t = + t 1 + t 1 σ ω αε βσ ω > 0, α, β 0, α + β 1 σ 0 2 2 2 t = + t 1 + t 1 σ ω αε βσ ε t 2 t 32

GARCH Option Pricing Duan (1995), Siu et al. (2005) Discrete time, numerical methods, Esscher transform Heston & Nandi (2000) Closed form, continuous limit is Heston SV model with perfect price-volatility correlation Continuous time limit of GARCH(1,1) conflicting results Nelson (1990) Diffusion limit model Corradi (2000) Deterministic limit model Which? 33

GARCH Diffusion Nelson (1990) Continuous limit of GARCH(1,1) Nelson assumed the following finite limits exist and are positive: ω 1 β α ω h θ h lim lim h = = h 0 h h 0 h α 2 2 h α = lim h 0 h σ 0 ( ) 2 2 2 dσ = ω θσ dt + 2ασ dw where h ω, h α, h β are the parameters using returns with step-length h t 34

Why No Diffusion? 1. GARCH has only one source of uncertainty in discrete time (Heston-Nandi, 2000) 2. The discretization of Nelson s limit model does not return the original GARCH model: it is ARV (Taylor, 1986) 3. GARCH diffusion and GARCH have non-equivalent likelihood functions (Wang, 2002) 4. Nelson s assumptions cannot be extended to other GARCH models 5. Nelson s assumptions imply that the GARCH model is not timeaggregating (Drost and Nijman, 1993). Only the assumptions made by Corradi (2000) are consistent with time-aggregation 6. Related papers: Brown et al. (2002) Duan et al. (2005) 35

Deterministic Limit? Corradi (2000) Continuous limit of GARCH(1,1) (revisited) Different assumptions: h ω 1 hβ ω = lim ψ = lim h 0 h h 0 h +X dσ 2 = ω θσ 2 dt 2ασ 2 dw σ 0 ( ) α h α = lim h 0 h where θ = ψ α t 36

Multi-State GARCH Alexander & Lazar (2004), Haas et al. (2004) y t S S ( S / S ) t t 1 = ln t t 1 St 1 2 2 ( ) ε I ~ NM π,..., π ; µ,..., µ ; σ,..., σ t t 1 1 K 1 K 1t Kt yt = µ + ε t K π = 1 i = 1 i K π µ = 0 i = 1 i i GARCH(1,1): A-GARCH: GJR: σ σ σ 2 it 2 2 = ω i + αiεt 1 + βi σ it 1 2 2 2 it = ωi + αi ( εt 1 λ i ) + βi σ it 1 2 it 2 2 2 = ωi + α iεt 1 + λ id t 1εt 1 + βi σ it 1 + parameter restrictions K K 2 2 2 t = i it + i i i = 1 i = 1 σ π σ π µ for volatility states i = 1,, K 37

Volatilities and Mixing Law SP500 200% 1 150% 0.5 100% 0 volatility 1 volatility 2 p 1 50% -0.5 0% Jan-2001 Jul-2001 Jan-2002 Jul-2002 Jan-2003-1 38

Conditional Skewness and Kurtosis SP500 Jan-2001 Jul-2001 Jan-2002 Jul-2002 Jan-2003 0 11 9 7-0.5 5 3 skewness kurtosis 1-1 -1 39

Features of Multi-State GARCH Endogenous time varying higher moments endogenous term structure in volatility skew surfaces Different component means long-run persistence in volatility skew Different GARCH volatility components regime specific meanreversion of volatility Asymmetric GARCH components regime specific leverage effect (slope of short term volatility skew) NM GARCH is better fit to historical data than single state GARCH models (Alexander & Lazar, 2004) 40

Volatility State Dependence σ p 1 if system is in state i ( st = i ) = ( p 1, p 2,..., p ) : p = otherwise t,t,t n,t i,t For continuous limit, introduce step-length h : p 1 if system is in state i ( h skh = i ) = ( p 1, p 2,..., p ) : p = otherwise h kh h,hk h,hk h n,hk h i,kh Define K continuous volatility states: K ( 1 2 ) ( ) ( ) 2 ( ) 2 ( ) 2 ( ) 2 ( ) 2 2 K t = σ t, σ t,, σ with overall volatility σ π σ π µ 2 K t ' t = i i t + i i i = 1 i = 1 Define the state indicator process: ( ) p t = lim p where p = p for t [ kh, ( k + 1) h ) h t h t h kh h 0 41

Transition Matrix State probabilities p are given by the (conditional) expectation of the state indicator vector: ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) P h skh = i I k 1 h = E h pkh I k 1 h = h p kh, say Introduce state dependence via transition matrix for step-length h: ( ) ( ) ( k 1) h Q q = Ρ s = i s = j ; = q with q = 1, q 0 h ij h kh h h h ij h ij h ij i = 1 K Then and p = Q p ( 1) h kh h h k h h Q ϖ = ϖ Where the unconditional state probabilities are the mixing law, π 42

Transition Rate Matrix Define limit of state probabilities: And the transition rate matrix: Λ ( t ) p = lim p where p = p lim h 0 h = = h 0 h t h t h kh Q h I ( λ ij ) Then the continuous time dynamics of the state probability vector in the physical measure are given by: ( ) = Λ p ( ) d p t t dt And the number of volatility jumps follow a Poisson process: k ( λ jt ) P(k jumps from state j in an interval of length t ) = exp ( λ jt ) k! where λ = λ is the instantaneous probability of a jump from state j. j i j ij 43

GARCH Jump Assume: ω α 1 β ω = lim α = lim ψ = lim µ = lim µ h h h Continuous limit of Markov Switching GARCH(1,1) is: Risk neutral measure: ds S = rdt + σdb * d p = Λ p dt * ( ) h i h i h i i i i i h i h 0 h 0 h 0 h 0 * (( ) ' ) Λ = Λ 1 + η 1 2 2 2 d σ = p' d σ + σ ' d p ( σ ) 2 2 2 dσ = ω + α ψ σ η: vector of conditional state risk premia dt Physical measure: ds = p ' µ dt + σdb S d p = Λ p dt 44

Example: Two Volatility States ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 dσ = p ω + α σ ψ σ dt + 1 p ω + α σ ψ σ dt + σ σ dp p σ ( ) ( ) 1 ( ) 2 ( ) dp t ( t ) ( ) ( ) 1 if s t = 1 t = ( p t, p t ) p ( t ) = 0 if s t = 2 1 if state changes from 2 to 1 = 0 if state does not change 1 if state changes from 1 to 2 2 σ 1 ( t ) in state 1 = 2 σ2 ( t ) in state 2 45

Realised Volatility 30% 20% 10% 0% vol 1 vol 2 realized vol 0 100 200 300 400 500 46

Related Work Option pricing and hedging with Markov switching volatility processes: Naik (1993): Theoretical results in continuous time, stochastic jump arrival rates, constant volatilities and perfectly correlated jumps in price Elliot et al. (2005): MS version of GARCH model of Heston & Nandi (2000) based on Esscher transform 47

Acknowledgements Co-authors: Emese Lazar, ISMA Centre Leonardo Nogueira, ISMA Centre Helpful discussions: Jacques Pézier, ISMA Centre Hyungsok Ahn, Commerzbank London Bruno Dupire, Bloomberg Peter Carr, Bloomberg and NYU Participants at Risk 2005 Europe and at Newton Institute, 2005. 48