MONEY, PRICES AND THE EXCHANGE RATE: EVIDENCE FROM FOUR OECD COUNTRIES

Similar documents
MONEY AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: SOME INTERNATIONAL EVIDENCE. Abstract

PRIVATE AND GOVERNMENT INVESTMENT: A STUDY OF THREE OECD COUNTRIES. MEHDI S. MONADJEMI AND HYEONSEUNG HUH* University of New South Wales

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Sectoral Analysis of the Demand for Real Money Balances in Pakistan

An Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between Macroeconomic Variables and Stock Prices in Bangladesh

The Effects of Oil Shocks on Turkish Macroeconomic Aggregates

The Current Account and Real Exchange Rate Dynamics in African Countries. September 2012

Government Tax Revenue, Expenditure, and Debt in Sri Lanka : A Vector Autoregressive Model Analysis

Cointegration Tests and the Long-Run Purchasing Power Parity: Examination of Six Currencies in Asia

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

A study on the long-run benefits of diversification in the stock markets of Greece, the UK and the US

Asian Economic and Financial Review SOURCES OF EXCHANGE RATE FLUCTUATION IN VIETNAM: AN APPLICATION OF THE SVAR MODEL

Volume 29, Issue 2. Measuring the external risk in the United Kingdom. Estela Sáenz University of Zaragoza

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF THE PUBLIC DEBT RELEVANCE TO THE ECONOMIC GROWTH OF THE USA

Applied Econometrics and International Development. AEID.Vol. 5-3 (2005)

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

The Balassa-Samuelson Effect and The MEVA G10 FX Model

A Study of Inflation Dynamics in India: A Cointegrated Autoregressive Approach

Market Integration, Price Discovery, and Volatility in Agricultural Commodity Futures P.Ramasundaram* and Sendhil R**

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners

Working Paper Series in Finance #00-07 PURCHASING POWER PARITY AND EMERGING SOUTH EAST ASIAN NATIONS. A. Razzaghipour* G.A. Fleming** R.A.

INTERDEPENDENCE OF THE BANKING SECTOR AND THE REAL SECTOR: EVIDENCE FROM OECD COUNTRIES

Why the saving rate has been falling in Japan

The Effects of Japanese Monetary Policy Shocks on Exchange Rates: A Structural Vector Error Correction Model Approach

Vector Autoregression Analysis of Exchange Rate Movement

REAL EXCHANGE RATES AND BILATERAL TRADE BALANCES: SOME EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE OF MALAYSIA

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE EFFECT OF OIL INCOME ON REAL EXCHANGE RATE IN IRANIAN ECONOMY. Adibeh Savari. Hassan Farazmand.

A DISAGGREGATED ANALYSIS OF GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES AND PRIVATE INVESTMENT IN TURKEY. Erdal Karagöl

The Demand for Money in China: Evidence from Half a Century

The Agricultural Sector in the Macroeconomic Environment: An Empirical Approach for EU.

Weak Policy in an Open Economy: The US with a Floating Exchange Rate, Henry Thompson

Does the Unemployment Invariance Hypothesis Hold for Canada?

The Impact of Oil Price Volatility on the Real Exchange Rate in Nigeria: An Error Correction Model

Forecasting Nominal Exchange Rate of Indian Rupee vs. US Dollar

Financial Econometrics Series SWP 2011/13. Did the US Macroeconomic Conditions Affect Asian Stock Markets? S. Narayan and P.K.

Analysis of monetary policy variables with stock returns using var frame work

The Fisher Effect and The Long Run Phillips Curve --in the case of Japan, Sweden and Italy --

ESTIMATING MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION OF BANGLADESH

Monetary Policy Shock Analysis Using Structural Vector Autoregression

Exchange Rates and Uncovered Interest Differentials: The Role of Permanent Monetary Shocks. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé and Martín Uribe

Effect of Treasury Bill Rate on Exchange Rate Level and Volatility in Kenya.

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation?

Imperfect Knowledge, Asset Price Swings and Structural Slumps: A Cointegrated VAR Analysis of their Interdependence

Most recent studies of long-term interest rates have emphasized term

The Monetary Models of the Turkish Lira/ Dollar Exchange Rate: Long-run Relationships, Short-run Dynamics and Forecasting.

Foreign direct investment and profit outflows: a causality analysis for the Brazilian economy. Abstract

ON THE NEXUS BETWEEN SERVICES EXPORT AND SERVICE SECTOR GROWTH IN INDIAN CONTEXT

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Asian Economic and Financial Review EMPIRICAL TESTING OF EXCHANGE RATE AND INTEREST RATE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS IN CHINA

International Business & Economics Research Journal May/June 2015 Volume 14, Number 3

Exchange Rate Pass-Through to Domestic Prices: The Turkish Case ( )

Fixed investment, household consumption, and economic growth : a structural vector error correction model (SVECM) study of Malaysia

Economics Bulletin, 2013, Vol. 33 No. 3 pp

Information Technology, Productivity, Value Added, and Inflation: An Empirical Study on the U.S. Economy,

COINTEGRATION AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: AN APPLICATION TO THE CANADIAN TREASURY BILL MARKET. Soo-Bin Park* Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada K1S 5B6

Testing the Stability of Demand for Money in Tonga

Fiscal deficit, private sector investment and crowding out in India

How do stock prices respond to fundamental shocks?

Impact of Fed s Credit Easing on the Value of U.S. Dollar

Quarterly Journal of Econometrics Research

CURRENT ACCOUNT DEFICIT AND FISCAL DEFICIT A CASE STUDY OF INDIA

Zhenyu Wu 1 & Maoguo Wu 1

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University

An Empirical Study on the Determinants of Dollarization in Cambodia *

Introductory Econometrics for Finance

Personal income, stock market, and investor psychology

A joint Initiative of Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität and Ifo Institute for Economic Research

Response of Output Fluctuations in Costa Rica to Exchange Rate Movements and Global Economic Conditions and Policy Implications

Chapter 1: Introduction

Causal Analysis of Economic Growth and Military Expenditure

Relationship between Oil Price, Exchange Rates and Stock Market: An Empirical study of Indian stock market

Testing the Degree of Openness of the Greek Capital Account: A Cointegration Analysis

Oil Price Effects on Exchange Rate and Price Level: The Case of South Korea

List of tables List of boxes List of screenshots Preface to the third edition Acknowledgements

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

Unemployment and Labour Force Participation in Italy

THE EFFECTIVENESS OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANNEL OF MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION MECHANISM IN SRI LANKA

LINKAGES OF ECONOMIC ACTIVITY, STOCK PRICE AND MONETARY POLICY: THE CASE OF MALAYSIA CHONG CHIN SIENG

Outward FDI and Total Factor Productivity: Evidence from Germany

TECHNICAL TRADING AT THE CURRENCY MARKET INCREASES THE OVERSHOOTING EFFECT* MIKAEL BASK

RE-EXAMINE THE INTER-LINKAGE BETWEEN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INFLATION:EVIDENCE FROM INDIA

Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S.

Determining Pak Rupee Exchange Rates vis-à-vis Six Currencies of the Industrial World: Some Evidence Based on the Traditional Flow Model

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series. Inflation, inflation uncertainty and growth: are they related?

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

CAN MONEY SUPPLY PREDICT STOCK PRICES?

Exchange Rate Market Efficiency: Across and Within Countries

Validity of the Monetary Model of the Exchange Rate: Empirical Evidence from Sri Lanka 1. Sujeetha Jegajeevan. Abstract

Integration of Foreign Exchange Markets: A Short Term Dynamics Analysis

Master of Arts in Economics. Approved: Roger N. Waud, Chairman. Thomas J. Lutton. Richard P. Theroux. January 2002 Falls Church, Virginia

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region

A new approach for measuring volatility of the exchange rate

RISK SPILLOVER EFFECTS IN THE CZECH FINANCIAL MARKET

Relationship between Inflation and Interest Rate: Evidence from Pakistan

An Econometric Analysis of Impact of Public Expenditure on Industrial Growth in Nigeria

The Fiscal-Monetary Policy and Economic Growth in Algeria: VECM Approach

Transcription:

money 15/10/98 MONEY, PRICES AND THE EXCHANGE RATE: EVIDENCE FROM FOUR OECD COUNTRIES Mehdi S. Monadjemi School of Economics University of New South Wales Sydney 2052 Australia m.monadjemi@unsw.edu.au December 1997 Abstract This study examines the short-run and the long-run responses of price and exchange rate to changes in monetary conditions. The empirical results of the study, based on monthly data from Britain, Canada, Germany and Japan, provide support for overshooting exchange rate in the short-run. Furthermore, the hypothesis of a proportional relationship between price ratio and the exchange rate as indicated by purchasing power parity is not empirically supported. However, the results of the study show that domestic price, foreign price and the exchange rate are cointegrated.

1 1. Introduction In an open economy with a flexible exchange rate system the effects of monetary policy are transmitted to the economy through changes in interest rates and the exchange rate in the short-run, and through changes in the price level in the long-run. The effects of monetary policy in an open economy were initially discussed in Mundell (1963) and Fleming (1962). The Mundell-Fleming model is basically a short-run model since it assumes a fixed price level. Sometimes this model is also called an open economy Keynesian model. With the advents of the 1970s, a fixed price model had very little applicability. Dornbusch (1976) developed a model of an open economy with fixed and flexible price levels. Dornbusch assumed that the price level is flexible in the long-run and rigid in the short-run. With the help of this and some other behavioural assumptions, Dornbusch was able to explain the responses of the price level and the exchange rate to a monetary shock. In Dornbusch s model the exchange rate overshoots its long-run equilibrium in the short-run but retrieves to a new equilibrium in the long-run. The price level remains constant in the short-run and changes in the long-run proportional to the exchange rate and money. Dornbusch s theoretical proposition was subject to several empirical investigations. In particular, recently Eichenhaum and Evans (1995) (EE) provided no support for the overshooting proposal and showed that the exchange rate appreciates persistently after introduction of a contractionary monetary shock. The authors also provided evidence against the uncovered interest parity condition. The purpose of this paper is to examine the effects of a change in interest rates on the exchange rate using an error correction model (ECM). The theoretical discussions of the paper are given in Section 2. The econometric methodology is discussed in Section 3. Data description and empirical results are presented in Sections 4 and 5 respectively. Summary and concluding remarks are offered in Section 6.

2 2. Theoretical Discussion A model of exchange rate determination may be developed using Dornbusch (1976) as a starting point. In Dornbusch s model an LM type of equation representing the monetary equilibrium, the uncovered interest parity condition and an exchange rate adjustment mechanism constitute the main theoretical framework of the model. These basic relationships are presented in equations 1, 2 and 3. * it it = Et 1 et (1) ( M / P) = α βr + γ y (2) t t t ( ) E 1 e = f e e t t t (3) * where i t, i t, Et-1, (M/P) t, y t, e t and e respectively are the domestic rate of interest, the foreign rate of interest, the expectations formed at time t-1, the real value of money stock, the level of output, the nominal exchange rate defined as the domestic price of foreign currency and the equilibrium exchange rate respectively. All variables except the exchange rate are in logarithms. By combining equations 1, 2 and 3 one is able to derive a single equation with six variables including it it *, e t, e t, y t, M t and P t. Data on these variables are available readily with the exception of the long-run equilibrium exchange rate. In Dornbusch s model the deviation of the exchange rate from its long-run equilibrium is proportional to the deviation of price level from its long-run equilibrium. Again, the long-run price level remains as a variable which needs to be quantified. In this paper it is assumed that the long-run equilibrium value of the exchange rate is determined by the current account. This assumption is based on models developed in Kouri (1976), Branson (1979) and Dornbusch and Fischer (1980) in which the path of the exchange rate is determined by the current account. The model used here is similar to EE s, with the

3 exception of the choice of monetary variable. In EE s model, the effects of shocks to monetary policy are represented by three measures, including innovations to the federal fund rate, ratio of non-borrowed to total reserves, and a special index for monetary policy contractions suggested by Romer and Romer (1989). Here, it is assumed that the effect of monetary policy on the economy is mainly transmitted through changes in the rate of interest. Hence, the empirical analysis of the model will examine the response of the exchange rate to changes in domestic interest rates relative to the foreign rate. It is argued that the effect of a shock to interest rate differential is similar to the effect of a shock to a monetary variable. Accordingly, by including an interest rate differential in the model, one may capture the effects of a monetary policy shock without explicitly including a proxy. The following vector autoregressive model (VAR) is employed as a framework for analysing the dynamic responses of five bilateral exchange rates. X = A( L) Y + U t t t [ t t t t t t] where X t is a vector of six time series, M, C, y,( i i* ), P, e, ( ) AL is ( p p) polynomial matrix in the lag operator L and V t is a vector of random disturbances with U N( ) t ~, 0 Σ and C t is the balance on the current account. 3. Econometric Methodology Most macroeconomic time series are non-stationary in levels and the use of conventional regression techniques with such data tends to produce spurious results. However, non-stationary time-series data may be cointegrated if some linear combinations of the series become stationary. That is, the series may wander around, but in the long-run there are economic forces that tend to push them to an equilibrium. That

4 is, cointegrated series will not move far away from each other and are linked in the longrun. Johansen (1988 and 1991) suggested tests for determining numbers of cointegrating vectors among a group of variables. Consider the following p variable VAR model: k Y = u+ φ Y + ε t i t i t i= 1 (6) where u is the constant term, Y t is (p 1) vector of the variables under study, and the disturbance vector ε t of dimension (p 1) is distributed as an i.i.d. Gaussian process with zero mean and variance Ω. Assuming that the series are cointegrated, equation 2 may be re-parameterised to give the following ECM representation: k 1 t i t i t k t i= 1 Y = u+ Γ Y + ΠY + ε (7) Γ j j = I φ i i= 1 (8) Π= I k φ i i= 1 (9) where I is the identity matrix. [See Johansen (1991) for details.] The long-run relationship between the series is determined by the rank of Π. If time series are non-stationary and cointegrated, then Π is not full rank, but 0 < rank(π) = r < p, where r is the number of cointegrating vectors. Johansen (1991) proposed two likelihood testing procedures in order to estimate the rank of Π. The first tests the hypothesis that the number of cointegrating vectors is, at most, equal to r (Trace test). The second tests the hypothesis that the number of cointegrating vectors is equal to r (Max Eigenvalue test). When the series are found to be cointegrated, Johansen further demonstrates that Π can be factored as:

5 Π= αβ (10) where β is the matrix of r cointegrating vectors and α is the matrix of weights attached to each cointegrating vector in equation 3. Both α and β are (p r) matrices. 4. Data Description All of the data in this study are monthly time series on OECD countries collected from the Time Series Data Express, dx v2.1, site licence held by the School of Economics, University of New South Wales, Sydney, Australia. The interest rate series are averages of overnight money market rates during the month. The exchange rate series are end of the month bilateral exchange rate against the U.S. dollar measured by the number of U.S. currency in one unit of domestic currency. The price level is the all items consumer price indices. The money stock is the monthly observation on M1. The level of output is measured by the index of domestic production. The balance on current account is approximated by the difference between exports and imports. 5. Empirical Results The Augmented Dickey-Fuller and Phillips-Perron s test for unit-roots were applied to six time series in each individual country, and the results indicated that all variables are non-stationary in levels but stationary in first differences. The results of the Johansen test for cointegration are reported in Table 1. These results indicate that the hypotheses of two cointegrating vectors for Britain, Canada and Japan and one cointegrating vector for Germany cannot be rejected at the 5 percent significant level. Normalized coefficients of cointegration are also reported in Table 1. These results indicate that there is a long-run equilibrium between variables included in the model. The

6 results are supportive of Dornbusch s theoretical proposal that suggested the existence of a long-run equilibrium in the model of exchange rate determination. However, Dornbusch showed that the purchasing power parity (ppp) holds in the long-run but not in the shortrun. This issue will be discussed after the dynamic responses of variables to a monetary shock are examined. The dynamic interactions among various variables can be examined by impulse response functions (IRF) and variance decompositions (VDC). To this end, as suggested by Engle and Granger (1987), the estimated coefficients of ECM are converted into levels and are inverted to vector moving average form. However, since coefficients of ECM are reduced form, they can provide little information about the structural coefficients of the model. In order to draw useful structural information, some form of identifying restrictions that are consistent with economic theory should be imposed on the ECM. Orden and Fisher (1993) used a standard Choleski-type of contemporaneous identifying restriction. This type of restriction is less restrictive than the long-run zero identifying restrictions used in King et al. (1991). In this study a Choleski-type of identifying restriction is imposed on the ECM. When this type of restriction is used, the ordering of variables imposes a particular recursive structure on the model, so that variables appearing earlier contemporaneously influence the latter variables, but not vice versa. The recursive order of variables chosen here is M t, y t, C t, P t, r * r and e t. This type of recursive ordering allows the contemporaneous values of M t to affect all of the other variables. t t

Table 1 RESULTS OF COINTEGRATION TEST Hypothesis Trace 95%CV Alternative λ Max 95%CV Britain r 5 3.72 3.76 r = 5 3.72 3.76 r 4 9.16 15.41 r = 4 5.45 14.90 r 3 19.75 29.68 r = 3 10.59 21.07 r 2 46.56 47.21 r = 2 26.81 27.014 r 1 94.77* 68.52 r = 1 40.21* 33.46 r 0 187.06* 94.15 r = 0 92.29* 39.37 Normalized Coefficients of Cointegrating Vectors m t y t * it it P t C t e t 1.00 0.00 0.018-0.77 0.61-0.76 (0.013) (0.18) (0.13) (0.29) 0.00 1.00 0.00-0.04 0.17-0.065 (0.002) (0.02) (0.02) (0.04) Canada r 5 0.83 r = 5 0.83 r 4 5.97 r = 4 5.15 r 3 16.61 r = 3 10.62 r 2 41.47 r = 2 24.86 r 1 77.03* r = 1 35.56* r 0 124.40* r = 0 47.37* Normalized Coefficients of Cointegrating Vectors m t y t * it it P t C t e t 1.00 0.00 0.034-1.35 3.07-0.44 (0.018) (0.15) (0.92) (0.32) 0.00 1.00 0.006-0.58 1.11-0.15 (0.00) (0.05) (0.31) (0.11) Germany r 5 0.04 r = 5 0.04 r 4 8.65 r = 4 8.60 r 3 19.85 r = 3 11.20 r 2 35.54 r = 2 15.70 r 1 63.73 r = 1 28.18 r 0 113.94* r = 0 50.21* Normalized Coefficients of Cointegrating Vectors m t y t * it it P t C t e t 1.00-0.058-0.03-1.41 0.07-0.68 (0.31) (0.006) (0.15) (0.07) (0.11) Japan r 5 2.84 r = 5 2.84 r 4 7.62 r = 4 4.78 r 3 17.77 r = 3 10.15 r 2 37.27 r = 2 19.52 r 1 76.07* r = 1 38.78* r 0 154.62* r = 0 78.55* Normalized Coefficients of Cointegrating Vectors m t y t * it it P t C t e t 1.00 0.00-0.018-0.77 0.61-0.77 (0.01) (0.16) (0.13) (0.29) 0.00 1.00-0.00-0.04 0.17-0.06 (0.00) (0.02) (0.018) (0.04) Sample periods are 1973.1-1993. Number of lags are 4. *indicates significant cases. 7

8 In Table 2 the results of VDC for 1, 5, 10, 15 and 20 quarters ahead are reported. These results show the relative importance of various shocks in forecast error variance of exchange rate. With the exception of Japan, and to some extent Germany, in the other two cases, the interest rate differentials are important variables in explaining forecast error variance of nominal exchange rates. The results of IRF derived from the ECM are presented in Figure 1 1. These functions show the dynamic responses of nominal exchange rate to one standard deviation shock of the interest rate differentials between the U.S. rate and the rates in each particular country. The U.S. rate is treated as the foreign rate. The exchange rate is measured by the number of U.S. currency per unit of domestic currency, so the downwards movement of the exchange rate means appreciation of the domestic currency. The confidence intervals are not produced here. However, a particular response is considered significant if it is located further away from the zero line. Accordingly the IRF results show that the responses of nominal exchange rates to shocks of interest rate differentials were significant in all cases except Japan. Moreover, in the cases of Britain and Canada the exchange rate appreciated and remained high over the long-run. The Deutschmark did not follow this pattern as the exchange rate returned to its initial level over a long period of time. However, in Germany, like the other two countries, the sharpest depreciation occurred during the initial periods. Accordingly, the results of this study show overshooting of the nominal exchange rate in the short-run. These results are in contrast with EE results, in which the sharpest appreciation of the nominal and real exchange rates to a negative innovation in monetary policy instrument occurred roughly about 25-30 months after the shock was introduced.

9 Table 2 VARIANCE DECOMPOSITION OF NOMINAL EXCHANGE RATE Britain Months Ahead m t y t c t p t i * t i t e t 1 0.01 0.56 0.02 0.36 1.65 97.39 5 0.30 10.24 0.47 0.18 9.26 79.55 10 0.77 14.71 0.32 0.67 12.48 71.05 15 1.16 14.92 0.26 1.30 12.50 69.85 20 1.32 14.85 0.35 1.51 12.29 69.68 Canada 1 0.12 0.019 0.12 0.73 2.34 96.65 5 2.11 0.10 4.21 0.72 10.70 82.15 10 3.02 1.40 5.47 0.69 11.21 78.20 15 3.39 2.57 6.50 0.50 10.67 76.37 20 3.76 3.38 7.21 0.36 10.25 75.04 Germany 1 0.28 0.19 0.87 0.56 4.17 93.92 5 2.75 0.60 0.70 3.66 4.44 87.84 10 5.17 0.37 0.95 4.53 3.33 85.63 15 6.92 0.28 1.18 5.54 2.50 83.57 20 8.39 0.29 1.39 6.49 1.95 81.49 Japan 1 0.12 0.35 1.07 0.00 0.05 98.44 5 0.20 0.17 3.60 1.11 0.14 94.78 10 0.24 0.08 4.95 1.29 0.13 93.3 15 0.38 0.08 5.40 1.40 0.09 92.64 20 0.51 0.10 5.62 1.50 0.07 92.20 Sample periods are 1973.1-1993.12. Variables are in log levels as specified in the ECM. Lag length of variables is six for Japan and four for the other three countries. 1 In Figure 1, ED, EC, EG, EJ, and ID are the exchange rates in Britain, Canada, Germany, Japan and the interest rate differential respectively.

10

11 Testing for Purchasing Power Parity (ppp) One of the important implications of Dornbusch s model is the existence of ppp in the long-run. That is, in the long-run the exchange rate and the price level move proportionally, leaving the real exchange rate constant. Kim (1990) examined this hypothesis in the context of cointegration of the exchange rate and the price ratio. Using this approach assumes that the exchange rate and the price ratio are related through the following equation. st = a0 + a1 pt + ut (11) where p t is the log of the ratio of domestic and foreign prices. Kim (1990) argued that the hypothesis of long-run ppp is accepted if a 1 = 1 and u t is a stationary autoregressive process. The empirical results of this study showed that in a group of five OECD countries, ppp was accepted for France, Italy, Japan and U.K. but not for Canada. He argued that the Canadian data against the U.S. showed very little fluctuation and, hence, the resulting regressions failed to produce significant coefficients. A similar approach is followed here using monthly data on four OECD countries. The hypothesis of ppp is accepted if the coefficient of price ratio in an equation similar to equation 11 is equal to 1, and the residual of the regression is a stationary process. These results are presented in Table 3. The price ratio is the log of the ratio of domestic CPI to the U.S. CPI, and the exchange rate is the logarithm of the number of U.S. dollars in a unit of domestic currency. The sign of the coefficient of the price ratio is expected to be negative. This means that as the price ratio rises, the domestic currency weakens against the U.S. dollar.

12 Table 3 TESTS FOR PURCHASING POWER PARITY Coefficient of price ratio ADF T Test ADF T Test for real exchange rate Britain -0.61-2.04-2.17 (-13.7) Canada -0.32-1.37-1.39 (-15.00) Germany -0.48-1.47-1.78 (-11.5) Japan -0.39-2.07-2.20 (-25.3) MacKinnon critical values for rejection of hypothesis of unit root at 1% and 5% significant levels are -3.9984 and -3.4292 respectively. The values in brackets are t ratios. The results presented in Table 3 indicate that the coefficients of price ratio are significantly different from zero, but the values of coefficients are not close to 1. Furthermore, Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) statistics tend to accept the hypothesis of unit-root in residuals. The last column in Table 3 shows ADF test results for stationarity of real exchange rate. In the long-run the hypothesis of ppp is valid if the real exchange rate is a stationary process. Kim (1990) and Frenkel (1986) accepted the stationarity of the real exchange rate, whereas Adler and Lehman (1983) rejected it. The results in Table 3 provide further evidence for the rejection of ppp. All of the ADF statistics indicate that the real exchange rates are non-stationary. A further test of ppp was conducted by applying Johansen s procedure to the Trivariate case of (p, p* and e), where p* is the foreign price. Evidence of cointegration may indicate that there is a long-run equilibrium between domestic price, foreign price

13 and the exchange rate. This evidence also suggests stationarity of the real exchange rate. The results of the Johansen test are reported in Table 4. Table 1 RESULTS OF COINTEGRATION TEST FOR PPP Hypothesis Trace 95%CV Alternative λ Max 95%CV Britain r 2 3.07 3.76 r = 2 3.07 3.76 r 1 12.54 15.41 r = 1 9.28 14.90 r 0 45.12* 29.68 r = 0 32.02 21.07 Canada r 2 2.34 r = 2 2.34 r 1 6.74 r = 1 4.40 r 0 34.51* r = 0 27.77 Germany r 2 1.34 r = 2 1.34 r 1 4.61 r = 1 3.26 r 0 33.96* r = 0 29.34 Japan r 2 1.85 r = 2 1.85 r 1 15.34 r = 1 13.49 r 0 64.60* r = 0 49.25 Sample periods are 1973.1-1993-12. Number of lags are 4. * indicates significant cases. The results of the Johansen test indicate that in all four cases domestic price, foreign price and the exchange rate are cointegrated. These results provide some support for ppp, however, they are in conflict with the results of the ADF test. Similar conflicting results were reported by Cheung and Lai (1993). The authors argued that the conflict is due to the low power of the ADF test. Furthermore, they also showed that the hypothesis of cointegration is more likely to be rejected when the number of variables tested is

14 reduced to one, which simply means testing for cointegration of real exchange rate. The authors state that rejection of ppp may still be supportive of ppp with measurement error. The regression results reported in Table 3, together with the results of the Johansen test, may indicate the existence of a long-run relationship between prices and the exchange rate. The empirical results of this study are in agreement with Cheung and Lai (1993) and are in conflict with Kim (1990). The conflict may be explained in terms of the use of high-frequency data. Most studies in this area agree that ppp should be tested in the long-run rather than short-run. However, there is not a firm agreement on whether high (monthly) or low (annual) frequency data should be used. For example, Glen (1992) employed both monthly and annual data and rejected the hypothesis of random walk in real exchange rate in the long-run. Pippenger (1993) used monthly data over the period 1973-1988 and showed that ppp is a valid proposition for four out of seven OECD countries. Furthermore, Cheung and Lai (1993) found evidence in favour of ppp using monthly data during the post-bretton Woods period. Therefore, there is evidence in the literature indicating that ppp may be accepted using low-frequency as well as highfrequency data. The results of this study, based on four countries, show that when price ratio changes, the exchange rate moves according to the direction predicted by ppp. However, the empirical results fail to provide support for the proportional movements of price ratio and the nominal exchange rate. 6. Summary and Concluding Remarks An attempt was made in this paper to examine the response of nominal exchange rate to change in monetary conditions using monthly data on four OECD countries. In particular, the analysis of the study concentrated on the topic of overshooting exchange rate as advocated by Dornbusch (1976). In contrast to Eichenbaum and Evans (1994), the

15 empirical results of this study support the overshooting hypothesis for three of the four countries under study. The empirical analysis of the study examined the dynamic responses of nominal exchange rate to changes in interest rate differentials between the domestic and foreign rates of interest. The use of interest rates rather than money was justified on the grounds that the effect of changes in monetary conditions is transmitted to the exchange rate via variations in interest rates. In contrast to Dornbusch s proposition, the hypothesis of proportional relationship between price ratios and the exchange rate was not supported by data. However, the empirical results showed a significant, but not proportional, relationship between price ratios and the nominal exchange rates. Moreover, the results of the Johansen test showed that domestic price, foreign price and the exchange rate are cointegrated.

16 References Adler, M. and Leham, B. (1983), Deviations from Purchasing Power Parity in the Long Run, Journal of Finance 83, 1471-87. Branson, W.H. (1977), Asset Markets and Relative Prices in Exchange Rate Determination, Sozialwissenschaftliche Annalen 1, 69-89. Cheung, Y.W. and Lai, K.S. (1993), Long-Run Purchasing Power Parity during the Recent Float, Journal of International Money and Finance 34, 181-192. Dornbusch, R. (1976), Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics, Journal of Political Economy 8, 1161-1176. Dornbusch, R. and Fisher, S. (1980), Exchange Rate and the Current Account, American Economic Review, December, pp.960-971. Driskill, R.A. (1981), Exchange Rate Overshooting, The Trade Balance, and Rational Expectations, Journal of International Economics 11, 361-377. Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C. (1994), Some Empirical Evidence on the Effect of Shocks to Monetary Policy on Exchange Rates, Quarterly Journal of Economics CX, 4, 975-1010. Fleming, J.M. (1962), Domestic Financial Policies under Fixed and Floating Exchange Rates, IMF Staff Papers 9, 369-379. Frankel, J.A. (1986), International Capital Mobility and Crowding-out in the U.S. Economy: Imperfect Integration of Financial Markets or of Good Markets? in How Open Is The U.S. Economy?, edited by Ruth W. Hafer, 33-67, Lexington Mass. Fuller, W.A. (1976), Introduction to Statistical Time Series, New York, Wiley and Sons.

17 Glen, J.D. (1992), Real Exchange Rates in the Short, Medium and Long Run, Journal of International Economics 33, 147-166. Johansen, S. (1988), Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, June-September, 231-254. Johansen, S. (1991), Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of Cointegrating Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models, Econometrica, November, 1551-1580. Kim, Y. (1990), Purchasing Power Parity in the Long Run: A Cointegration Approach, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 22, 4, 491-503. Kouri, P.J.K. (1976), The Exchange Rate and the Balance of Payments in the Short-run and in the Long-run: A Monetary Approach, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 2, 78, pp.280-304. Mundell, R.A. (1963), Capital Mobility and Stabilization Policy under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates, Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science 29, 475-485. Phillips, P. and Perron, P. (1988), Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series Regression, Biometrica 75, 335-46. Pippenger, M.K. (1993), Cointegration Tests for Purchasing Power Parity: The Case of Swiss Exchange Rates, Journal of International Money and Finance 12, 46-61.