On Principles: Fed does about-face on operational framework and balance sheet strategy

Similar documents
U.S. Interest Rates Chartbook September 2017

December. US Interest Rates. Chartbook

U.S. INTEREST RATES CHARTBOOK MARCH U.S. Interest Rates. Chartbook. March 2017

U.S. Interest Rates Chartbook March 2018

FOMC Statement: December th

U.S. Interest Rates Chartbook January 2018

Monetary Policy Implementation with a Large Central Bank Balance Sheet

Interpreting the Fedspeak: FOMC minutes

How Will the Federal Reserve Adjust Its Balance Sheet During Policy Normalization? 12/10/2015

Policy Implementation with a Large Central Bank Balance Sheet

Implementation and Transmission of Monetary Policy

Implementation and Transmission of Monetary Policy

Federal Reserve Monetary Policy Since the Financial Crisis

The Direction of Interest Rates

November minutes: key signaling language

Responses to Survey of Market Participants

New Operating Framework for Monetary Policy Implementation

Brian P Sack: Managing the Federal Reserve s balance sheet

Workshop Summary Remarks

US Federal Reserve: Feels like the first time

Embracing flat a new norm in long-term yields

Alternatives for Reserve Balances and the Fed s Balance Sheet in the Future. John B. Taylor 1. June 2017

Liquidity is Relevant Again

US Federal Reserve: Feels like the first time

Monetary Policy and Reform in Practice. Remarks by. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Credit cards: trends, profitability and outlook

BOMA National Advisory Council Meeting Seaport Hotel, Boston MA

FOMC Stresses Importance of Data-Dependent Policy in October Minutes

Liquidity Management: Beyond Quantitative Easing

Prudential International Investments Advisers, LLC. Global Investment Strategy May 2008

Policy Implementation with a Large Central Bank Balance Sheet

Explore the themes and thinking behind our decisions.

Natural Interest rate: uncertainties and policy implications

U.S. Recession Probability Rises to 25%

THE FED BALANCE SHEET UNWIND: STRATEGIC CONSIDERATIONS

Jan F Qvigstad: Outlook for the Norwegian economy

The Liquidity Effect of the Federal Reserve s Balance Sheet Reduction on Short-Term Interest Rates

A Monetarist View of Policy Renormalization. Peter Ireland. Boston College and Shadow Open Market Committee. September 2017

Indonesia: Changing patterns of financial intermediation and their implications for central bank policy

Macroeconomics for Finance

Evolution of Unconventional Monetary Policy: Japan s Experiences

U.S. Economic Outlook

EC3115 Monetary Economics

Convergence Long/Short Strategies Q Review and Commentary

The Fed and The U.S. Economic Outlook

Quarterly Currency Outlook

Responses to Survey of Market Participants

Monetary policy normalization in the euro area

Negative Interest Rate Policies: Sources and Implications

Chapter 10. Conduct of Monetary Policy: Tools, Goals, Strategy, and Tactics. Chapter Preview

2014 Annual Review & Outlook

The Yield Curve and Monetary Policy in 2018

Get up off the floor

Why does the Fed do what it does? How could it do better? 1

BBVA Research U.S. Economic Outlook August 2018 / 1. U.S. Economic Outlook August 2018

Central Bank Balance Sheets: Misconceptions and Realities

The state of prolonged low interest rates challenges financial stability

Reconciling FOMC Forecasts and Forward Guidance. Mickey D. Levy Blenheim Capital Management

Views on the Economy and Price-Level Targeting

Predicting a US recession: has the yield curve lost its relevance?

Cash Management Portfolios

Brian P Sack: Implementing the Federal Reserve s asset purchase program

Let s Talk About It: What Policy Tools Should the Fed Normally Use?

Economic & Capital Market Outlook Third Quarter, 2018

Economic impact of Hurricane Harvey

Leumi. Global Economics Monthly Review. Arie Tal, Research Economist. July 12, Capital Markets Division, Economics Department. leumiusa.

TD Economics. The Fed s Balance(ing) Act. Highlights. With QE, size matters

Implementing Monetary Policy: Transition Tools

Macro vulnerabilities, regulatory reforms and financial stability issues IIF Spring Meeting

A sticky situation for banks, but is it really that bad?

Eurozone Economic Watch Higher growth forecasts for January 2018

Alternatives for Reserve Balances and the Fed s Balance Sheet in the Future

Policy Implementation with a Large Central Bank Balance Sheet. Antoine Martin

January minutes: key signaling language

Real GDP Growth Rebounds 4.0% in 2Q14

Why is Investor Confidence Lagging?

A hawkish hold with risks ahead in an unusual context is the best strategy for now

Working Paper. A fundamental interest rate explanation and forecast. July 3, Economic Research & Corporate Development. Dr.

Recent Economic Developments

LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. October 10, 2018

LECTURE 11 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. November 2, 2016

SURVEY OF PRIMARY DEALERS

October 29, Can the Fed Successfully Exit from Its Recent Policy?

Global Macroeconomic Monthly Review

Brian P Sack: The SOMA portfolio at $2.654 trillion

RESPONSES TO SURVEY OF

U.S. Recession Risk Monitor

Monetary and Fiscal Policy: The Impact on Interest Rates

Eurozone Economic Watch. July 2018

FIXED INCOME UPDATE AUGUST 17

SURVEY OF PRIMARY DEALERS

Just what the doctor ordered: real-time recession forecasts

Adjusting to a Stronger Dollar and Weaker Oil Prices

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (July 2018)

Regulatory change and monetary policy

Business cycle investing

BANK OF RUSSIA FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND GOLD ASSET MANAGEMENT REPORT MOSCOW

Economic and Financial Markets Monthly Review & Outlook Detailed Report. June 2014

QUANTITATIVE EASING. 1. Point of departure 2. More on the US 3. Secular Stagnation 4. More on the Euro Area 5. Helicopter money 6.

Will the Fed s Balance Sheet Ever Return to Normal? Part II 1

Transcription:

Economic Analysis On Principles: Fed does about-face on operational framework and balance sheet strategy Boyd Nash-Stacey / Nathaniel Karp After the January meeting, the Federal Reserve Open Market Committee announced a major policy reversal. While this U-turn came as a surprise given the long-standing desire to return to a pre-crisis operating framework, the Fed has incrementally adjusted its approach to normalization as conditions have evolved. In June 211, the Federal Reserve (Fed) communicated the key exit strategy principles" for normalizing both interest rates and its balance sheet, which had reached $2.8 trillion. Under these principles, reinvestments would cease and reserve-draining operations would be initiated before the first increase in the federal funds rate target. The interest rate on excess reserves (IOER) and the level of reserves would be adjusted to bring the federal funds rate toward its target. Sales of agency securities would be "aimed at eliminating [ ] holdings of agency securities over a period of three to five years. In September 214, after the balance sheet ballooned to $4.5 trillion, the Fed released its Policy Normalization Principles and Plans (PNPP), signaling that it would not conduct asset sales or reserve draining operations. Rather, the Fed committed to cease principal reinvestment of their securities portfolio after the start of its interest normalization plans, without outright sales of agency securities, and do so until the committee reach a level that required no more securities than necessary to implement monetary policy. In addition, the Fed would lift rates by increasing the IOER and by using overnight repurchase agreements and other administrative rates until they were no longer needed. In June 217, the Fed once again updated the PNPP and announced the caps for the reinvestment of principal payments. In addition, the Fed stated that the quantity of reserve balances would be reduced, "over time, to a level appreciably below that seen in recent years, but larger than before the financial crisis." Figure 1. Factors Affecting Federal Reserve Balances, $ Trillions 5 4 3 2 1-1 -2-3 -4 5 4 3 2 1-1 -2-3 -4-5 -5 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 21 211 212 213 214 215 216 217 218 Treasury(A) MBS(A) Other(A) Currency(L) Reserves(L) Other(L) Source: BBVA Research U.S. Economic Watch 5 March 219 1

Interest Rates Tweaks to Fed balance sheet strategy and operational framework For years, given the large expansion of the Fed s balance sheet and the need to respond effectively in future downturns, whereby the likelihood of hitting the Zero Lower Bound (ZLB) is high, the committee has debated what the appropriate operating framework would be. In determining the desired size of the balance sheet, the Fed has to evaluate two concerns. The first consideration is whether the Fed prefers to operate in an environment of abundant or scarce reverses. The second consideration, conditional on choosing the operational framework, is determining bank s preferences for reserves, and at which points the elasticity of the demand curve changes. To transition to an environment where reserves are scarce, as was the strategy up until 218, the Fed faced a number of challenges. The Fed must anticipate at what level the banking system transitions from the current setting, where reserves are abundant, to one were reserves are scarce. If for instance, the Fed failed to anticipate the transition and the level of demand for reserves increases abruptly, there could be a surge in rates. If the demand for reserves plummets, rates would fall significantly. Therefore, unless the Fed has an accurate estimate of the demand for reserves at all times, the likelihood of experiencing a volatile transition is high. Estimates suggests brokered trading in the Fed Funds market is about a third as large as in the pre-crisis. Moreover, the Fed has no explicit target or precedent for the demand for safe assets given both the changes in liquidity requirements (LCR & SLR) and shift in operational framework. In fact, even in the pre-crisis with a more parsimonious operational framework, the demand for reserves was difficult to forecast and unpredictable. In most cases, open market operations were performed on a daily basis. Lastly, if balance sheet tapering lowered reserves to below a level considered relatively scarce by banks, interest rate fluctuations could be determined by the regulatory penalties associated with the reserve requirements and capital short falls rather than supply and demand conditions. Figure 2. Actual and Expected Terminal Level of Reserves and IOER, $ Trillions & % 6. 5. Previous 4. 3. Baseline 2. 1. Actual. Reserves Source: BBVA Research Based on these challenges, the Fed maintained its current floor system whereby the control over the level of the federal funds rate and other short-term interest rates is exercised primarily through the setting of the administered rates IOER and the offering rate on overnight reverse repurchase agreements (ON RRPs)-, and in which active management of the supply of reserves is not required." In essence, the stance of monetary policy remains linked to the quantity of reserves demanded by banks rather than the supply of reserves. The Fed realized that the likelihood of fully disentangling their normalization strategy from the long-run operation framework was not possible in the medium-term and that the best strategy would require a higher terminal level of the balance sheet than would be needed in a corridor system, as was the case before the Great Recession. U.S. Economic Watch 5 March 219 2

Jan-13 Jul-13 Jan-14 Jul-14 Jan-15 Jul-15 Jan-16 Jul-16 Jan-17 Jul-17 Jan-18 Jul-18 Jan-19 The decision to maintain the floor system eliminates the need to precisely estimate the impact that regulation and structural changes have had on the demand for reserves. In addition, the supply of reserves and interest rate policy will be independent, meaning the Fed could use its balance sheet to respond to a liquidity crisis without affecting its other objectives. Administered rates have also been used effectively at other central banks Bank of Canada, Bank of England, Bank of Japan, ECB, Norges Bank, Reserve Bank of Australia, Reserve Bank of New Zealand and Swedish Riksbank. Fed to reach terminal balance level in 219 As mentioned before, up until recently, the Fed s plan was to return reserves to levels that coincided with the downward sloping portion of the bank s demand curve, or in Fedspeak, to a level that satiated bank s appetite for reserves, but that provided no more than was necessary. This implied that the Fed would reduce its balance sheet to around $ trillion in which case reserves decline to around $2 billion, assuming that the growth in currency in circulation remained consistent with nominal growth rates. This level of total liabilities was consistent with the precrisis average plus a small risk-adjustment that reflects the structural change in the demand for reserves. Figure 3. Balance Sheet Assets & Reserves, $ Trillion Figure 4. Federal Reserve Administered Rates, % 4.5 3. 4. 3.5 3. 2. 1.5 2. 1.5 1. 1..5.5.. 22 24 26 28 21 212 214 216 218 2. 1.5 1..5. MBS Treasuries Reserve Balances (RHS) Effective Upper Lower IOER However, with the Fed s commitment to a floor system, the terminal level of the balance sheet is going to be substantially higher than would be needed to execute a true corridor system. Based on the shift in the operational framework and the shift in bank s preferences for cash-like assets, we expect the Fed s balance sheet will decline to around $3.6 trillion before rising again. The reinvestment caps for Treasuries and Mortgaged Backed Securities (MBS) put in place in 217 are unlikely to be changed given that in most months they are not binding, and thus adjusting the caps at this point would likely produce more uncertainty than major benefits to markets. As a result, based on the projected pay down of the Treasury and MBS portfolio, the Fed will reach its target by December 219, at which point around 6% of the portfolio will be Treasuries and around 4% will be MBS. In terms of the liabilities, the level of bank reserves held at the Fed have already declined from $2.8 trillion in 214 to $1.2 trillion today. The substantial decline is the result of three factors. First, the combination of a strong economy and the increased opportunity cost of holding cash at the Fed led banks to lower their reserve balances beginning in 214. Second, the draw down on reserves accelerated in 218 once the balance sheet wind down began in October of 217. To match the decline in assets, liabilities must decline by at least an equal amount, which would imply about a 1:1 rate of attrition. However, in 218, assets declined $375 billion while reserves declined by $515 billion. The difference is explained by the growth in currency in circulation, the last factor. Currency in circulation has increased at a stable pace of around 6.5% over the past five years, consistent with the fluctuations in nominal GDP growth. As a result, currency liabilities at the Fed increased by around $1 billion, leading to a smaller decrease in assets than what would be implied by the decrease in reserves. U.S. Economic Watch 5 March 219 3

Figure 5. Balance Sheet Assets & Reserves, Annual Change $ Brillion 15 Figure 6. Balance Sheet Scenarios, Assets $ Trillion 5. 1 4.5 5 4. 3.5-5 3. -1-15 29 21 211 212 213 214 215 216 217 218 Reserves Currency Assets Total 2. 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 2 U-shaped V-shaped The accelerated decline in reserves may have prompted the Fed to pare down their normalization strategy and consider a more cautious approach. In fact, based on the minutes and the Fed s overly cautious approach to policy normalization, we expect that the Fed will try to engineer a soft landing of its balance sheet as well. This would mean letting assets decline further before levelling off for a short period of time. This will allow currency to continue growing at a market determined rate, but allow the level of reserves to wind down at a slower pace while remaining abundant. After reserves reach a stable level, assets would begin to increase in tandem with growth in currency in circulation. This would mean purchasing Treasury securities outright or possibly reinvesting principal payments in Treasury portfolio above the current caps. As a result, we expect the Fed will pursue a balance sheet normalization path that follows a U-shaped rather than the prior consensus of a V-shaped path. Figure 7. Balance Sheet Projections, Assets $ Trillion 6. 5. 4. 3. 2. 1.. 1 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 2 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 Total Treasury MBS Figure 8. Balance Sheet Projections, Liabilities $ Trillion 3.5 3. 2. 1.5 1..5. 1 1 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 2 21 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 Currency Reserves Other In the long-run, we still anticipate that the Fed will try to transition to a more traditional portfolio, comprised mainly of government securities. In the review of their balance sheet normalization policy: Participants commented that, in light of the Committee's longstanding plan to hold primarily Treasury securities in the long run, it would be appropriate once asset redemptions end to reinvest most, if not all, principal payments received from agency MBS in Treasury securities. U.S. Economic Watch 5 March 219 4

This would require the Fed to purchase Treasury securities at a pace equal to the decline in the agency MBS portfolio, plus the growth in currency in circulation. On average, this would imply $21 billion in purchases per month between now and 229. Meanwhile, the Fed may decide to conduct sales of MBS if the rundown is too slow or if they decide that maintaining large holdings of MBS is not needed to support the mortgage market. New principled approach not without risks Although Fed officials believe that the current unwinding of the balance sheet is having a limited impact on financial markets, some participants have commented that the Fed s ambivalence caused the sharp market correction during 4Q18. In a sense, markets were interpreting the lack of flexibility on the balance sheet as a signal of a more hawkish shift in policy. In the future, adding another dimension to its forward guidance strategy could affect the Fed s ability to manage its communication and the real economy. However, the move to an abundant supply of reserve should moderate these risks in the medium-term, as evidenced by the rebound in financial markets after the Fed s abrupt departure from its hawkish stance at the start of 219. While moving to a floor system with an abundant supply reserves has many advantages, it could present some risks going forward. In addition, it is not clear if this change will generate a net benefit to the economy or require further fine tuning in the future. First, maintaining a large balance sheet entails communicating to markets the committee s strategy with respect to its size, composition and expected influence on the real economy. Second, there are concerns that relying on administrative rates for benchmarking when there is an ample reserve supply can reduce peer-to-peer oversight amongst financial institutions, as there would be little incentive to monitor each other if they are not continuously evaluating counterparty risks in the interbank market. However, the failures leading to the 28 financial crisis suggests this benefit may be overstated. Figure 9. Projected Purchases of Treasury Securities, Annual $ Billion 35 Figure 1. Money Market Interest Rate Dispersion, Absolute deviation from to IOER, bp 8 3 6 25 2 4 15 1 5 2 29 21 211 212 213 214 215 216 217 218 22 221 222 223 224 225 226 Comm Paper (nonfinancial) SOFR Effective Fed Funds Source: BBVA Research & Haver Analytics Comm Paper (financial) LIBOR Third, the floor system may be less effective at transmitting monetary policy to the real economy. While volatility surrounding the administered rates tends to diminish with a floor system, the ability to transfer these rates to money markets and the broader economy tends to be diminished. In fact, Duffe and Krishnamurthy (216) showed that dispersion among money market rates increased by 1bp after the Fed lifted rates away from the ZLB in 215. Furthermore, Basel regulations such as the supplementary leverage ratio (SLR) and the liquidity coverage ratio (LCR) could also dampen the pass through if the supply of safe assets fails to keep up with the increased demand. U.S. Economic Watch 5 March 219 5

Fourth, the ability of the Fed to maintain an abundant supply of reserves requires them to pay interest on excess reserves. This is a major shift from the pre-crisis, as the Fed was prohibited from paying IOER. In essence, the policy change moves the system from one that taxed excess reserves to one that subsidizes excess reserves. Fifth, one could argue that if the Federal Reserve maintains its current policy of primarily investing in U.S. Treasuries, the central bank would be encouraging deficit spending by suppressing the costs associated with expansionary fiscal policy. For example, during the period in which the Fed was utilizing unconventional monetary policy tools, interest rates and inflation remained extremely low despite a strong expansion in bank liabilities and increases in fiscal deficits relative to GDP. This suggests that the policy of abundant reserves could dampen the market signal associated with excessive leverage such as higher borrowing costs. However, there is no guarantee that future expansions of the balance sheet would occur under the same favorable macroeconomic conditions, particularly if demand for U.S. assets dwindles. One policy that could limit this distortion would be to broaden the asset classes that the Fed would be willing to hold on its balance sheet. The Bank of Japan implemented a Stock Purchase Program in 22 with some success. However, unwinding these securities was challenging given that, unlike debt securities, there is no maturity date, and thus outright sales are required. Although possible, this policy course would signal an even further departure from conventional operating framework and put the Fed under significant political risk. Sixth, although high levels of bank reserves are needed to comply with financial regulations, there is a tradeoff between financial stability and bank financing of private activities. To the extent that high levels of reserves end up financing government debt through Treasury holdings by the Fed, there could be lower private lending and investment than in an environment of scarce reserves. In addition, the returns from public spending may be lower than private alternatives. In other words, there could be efficiency losses at the aggregate level of the economy from an abundant reserve system if it distorts resource allocation. Seventh, it is not clear what would be the best composition of the Fed s Treasury portfolio. A more neutral composition would be a distribution that resembles issuance. However, if a downturn occurs, the Fed may not have sufficient space to increase its holdings of longer-dated securities as it did during the QE programs, which lowered the risk premium. In contrast, a portfolio of short duration, that provides more flexibility during downturns, could create significant market distortions and influence debt issuance from the Treasury. Bottom Line Given the challenges the Fed currently faces such as increased financial volatility, slowing domestic and global growth, policy uncertainty, declining business and consumer sentiment, and changes in financial regulation, the move to a floor system seems prudent. The short-term costs of squeezing bank s liquidity and potentially pushing market participants into a scant federal funds market presented a nontrivial risk to financial stability and the Fed s ability to fulfill its dual mandate. As a result, the Fed is poised to end its balance sheet normalization plans well before market participants anticipated with a substantially larger balance sheet. We expect the Fed will begin preparing markets shortly for the transition, and end its balance sheet normalization policy in 4Q19. While prudent in the short-run, the shift in the operational framework and strategy could complicate the Fed s ability to effectively implement monetary policy in the longer-term. If this were the case, the Fed will once again adjust the strategy to pursue a more efficient path. DISCLAIMER This document was prepared by Banco Bilbao Vizcaya Argentaria s (BBVA) BBVA Research U.S. on behalf of itself and its affiliated companies (each BBVA Group Company) for distribution in the United States and the rest of the world and is provided for information purposes only. Within the US, BBVA operates primarily through its subsidiary Compass Bank. The information, opinions, estimates and forecasts contained herein refer to the specific date and are subject to changes without notice due to market fluctuations. The information, opinions, estimates and forecasts contained in this document have been gathered or obtained from public sources, believed to be correct by the Company concerning their accuracy, completeness, and/or correctness. This document is not an offer to sell or a solicitation to acquire or dispose of an interest in securities. U.S. Economic Watch 5 March 219 6