Everything You Need to Know About the Financial Crisis: A Guest Post by Diamond and Kashyap

Similar documents
Global Financial Crisis. Econ 690 Spring 2019

How Curb Risk In Wall Street. Luigi Zingales. University of Chicago

Implications of the Bank Stress Tests

Financial Fragility and the Lender of Last Resort

The Financial Crisis and the Bailout

The Lehman Shock Financial Disaster the Effects on Japan. found out an attractive and interesting article, which showed the world economic

Diamond and Kashyap on the Recent Financial Upheavals

ASSESSING THE RISK OF A DOUBLE-DIP RECESSION: KEY INDICATORS TO MONITOR

The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

deposit insurance Financial intermediaries, banks, and bank runs

Comments on Hoshi and Kashyap,

The Great Depression: An Overview by David C. Wheelock

Financial Crises: The Great Depression and the Great Recession

From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

Financial Markets Perspective

b. Financial innovation and/or financial liberalization (the elimination of restrictions on financial markets) can cause financial firms to go on a

Remarks by James K. Galbraith at the Economists for Peace and. Security Bernard Schwartz Symposium on Jobs, Investment and Energy.

Chapter 10. The Great Recession: A First Look. (1) Spike in oil prices. (2) Collapse of house prices. (2) Collapse in house prices

TRUE FACTS AND FALSE PERCEPTIONS ABOUT FEDERAL DEFICITS" Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer Rotary Club of Springfield, Missouri December 6, 1988

Group 14 Dallas Hall, Chuck Dobson, Guy Tahye, Tunde Olabiyi

Don t Raise the Federal Debt Ceiling, Torpedo the U.S. Housing Market

The Great Crash Ch 21-1

Economic Shocks: the Great Depression and Great Recession. Andy Bauer Senior Regional Economist October 19, 2017

ECN 106 Macroeconomics 1. Lecture 10

On Financial Crisis and Economic Recovery Plan. delivered 24 September 2008

Reflections on the Financial Crisis Allan H. Meltzer

Chapter 8. Why Do Financial Crises Occur and Why Are They So Damaging to the Economy? Chapter Preview

10.2 Recent Shocks to the Macroeconomy Introduction. Housing Prices. Chapter 10 The Great Recession: A First Look

Testimony of. William Grant. On Behalf of the. Before the. Of the. United

EC248-Financial Innovations and Monetary Policy Assignment. Andrew Townsend

How to Safely Manage Home Equity to Achieve Financial Freedom & Build Wealth. fast facts

Transcript of Larry Summers NBER Macro Annual 2018

The Bible and Personal Finances Part 3

The Economy and Employment in North Carolina: Is the Worst Over?

PART THREE. Answers to End-of-Chapter Questions and Problems

The Real Problem was Nominal: How the Crash of 2008 was Misdiagnosed. Scott Sumner, Bentley University

1 U.S. Subprime Crisis

Normalizing Monetary Policy

Out of the Shadows: Projected Levels for Future REO Inventory

Chapter Fourteen. Chapter 10 Regulating the Financial System 5/6/2018. Financial Crisis

Macroeconomics Sixth Edition

Small Business Lending Roundtable Committee on Small Business United States House of Representatives

Short run prospects in Europe and the United States

In this alert we want to address some very specific questions for our clients:

ECONOMICS U$A 21 ST CENTURY EDITION PROGRAM #25 MONETARY POLICY Annenberg Foundation & Educational Film Center

Our Interview with Robert Shiller September 9, 2008

Econ 323 Economic History of the U.S. Prof. Eschker Fall 2018

Quarterly Chartbook. September 30, Which way is up? Copyright , All rights reserved. investwithcornerstone.com

To fully understand the dramatic turns in the financial markets that

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments

From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

Incremental Steps Toward a Radical Solution

I. Learning Objectives II. The Functions of Money III. The Components of the Money Supply

Tips for Traders 10/13/ :02:00 AM Stalking Major Moves: Looking for Signs of Where the Market is Headed

Macroeconomic Policy during a Credit Crunch

Money and Banking ECON3303. Lecture 9: Financial Crises. William J. Crowder Ph.D.

Where do we go from here? Anil K Kashyap 1

Main Points: Revival of research on credit cycles shows that financial crises follow credit expansions, are long time coming, and in part predictable

The Monetary System. Economics CHAPTER. N. Gregory Mankiw. Principles of. Seventh Edition. Wojciech Gerson ( )

Name: Class: U.S. History 2 Date:. Mr. Wallace. 1. is buying stocks with loans from brokers. (Buying on margin/buying short)

HISTORY OF BANK INDONESIA : BANKING Period from

The Great Crash Chapter 11 Sect. 1. Prosperity. The Stock Market

Financial Crises and the Great Recession

An Enhanced Objective Financial Stability

CAUSES of the GREAT DEPRESSION s

Masaaki Shirakawa: Global financial crisis and policy responses by the Bank of Japan

Implications of Low Inflation Rates for Monetary Policy

The Financial System. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () The Financial System 1 / 55

Sycamore Market Analysis

Banking, Liquidity Transformation, and Bank Runs

Empirically Evaluating Economic Policy in Real Time. The Martin Feldstein Lecture 1 National Bureau of Economic Research July 10, John B.

PAGE 42 THE STERN STEWART INSTITUTE PERIODICAL #10 JAMES GORMAN: NAVIGATING THE CHANGING LANDSCAPE OF FINANCE

Balance-Sheet Adjustments and the Global Economy

The Asian Crisis: Causes and Cures IMF Staff

Lecture 26 Exchange Rates The Financial Crisis. Noah Williams

Why Is the Rescue of US Banks Taking So Long?

The International Financial Crises of the 1990s: Analytics

The yellow highlighted areas are bear markets with NO recession.

Takehiro Sato: Toward further development of the Tokyo financial market issues on repo market reform

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

4 BIG REASONS YOU CAN T AFFORD TO IGNORE BUSINESS CREDIT!

Saving, Investment, and the Financial System

A New Capital Regulation For Large Financial Institutions

2. If a bank meets a net deposit drain by borrowing money in the fed funds market it is using purchased liquidity.

: Bank Runs

The Coming Home Equity Line of Credit Crisis

June 24th, Rate Reversal. Author: Benjamin Struck President

CURRENT WEAKNESS OF DEPOSIT INSURANCE AND RECOMMENDED REFORMS. Heather Bickenheuser May 5, 2003

Lecture 12: Too Big to Fail and the US Financial Crisis

joshuakennon.com by JOSHUA KENNON FEB. 6, 2013

The Financial System. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () The Financial System 1 / 52

The following is an excerpt from our letter for the fourth quarter of 2008:

Consumer Price Index

In pursuing a strategy of monetary targeting, the central bank announces that it will

China CHINA S RISING DEBT: WHEN DOES A BUBBLE BECOME TROUBLE?

Debt and Credit - A Matter of Interest

Following a decade of neglect, the Bush administration and Congress moved

Gundlach: Treasuries will Rally When QE2 Ends

Bi-Weekly Economic & Market Report Leading Stock Indicators Just Entered a Bear Market Oil Semiconductor stocks

November Dear Sisters and Brothers,

Transcription:

Everything You Need to Know About the Financial Crisis: A Guest Post by Diamond and Kashyap By STEVEN D. LEVITT When the financial crisis was just beginning to appear, I did one of the smartest things I ve ever done: I asked my colleagues Doug Diamond and Anil Kashyap to explain to me what was happening. What they said was so enlightening that I begged them to write it up for the blog, which they did. Their guest post proved to be wildly popular among readers, rising to be the second-most-emailed article on The New York Times web site. As far I know, no other Freakonomics post has ever come close to making even the bottom of the most-emailed list. Enough important events have occurred since their original post that we asked them whether they couldn t bring us up to speed on where the financial crisis stands today, what the government is doing and why, and the long-term prospects for the economy. I didn t think it was possible, but this second blog post is even better than the first one. Everything You Need to Know About the Financial Crisis By Doug Diamond and Anil Kashyap A Guest Post 1) Why has the stock market been so erratic for the last two weeks? The stock market s value depends on the future profitability of firms. In a sluggish economy, the stock market typically falls well before unemployment peaks. The declines last week reflected the concern that the economy is headed toward a sharp slowdown for an extended period of time. For some time, the basis for this concern was a fear that lending throughout the economy was drying up. Without credit, most businesses would not be able to function, and many individuals would have to cut their spending. Until this week, it appeared to be increasingly possible that there could be widespread bank failures that would impair the lending capacity of the banking system for a long time. We agree with the words of Ben Bernanke this week: As in all past crises, at the root of the problem is a loss of confidence by investors and the public in the strength of key financial institutions and markets Banks are vulnerable to loss of confidence because they rely on short-term funding. This fear causes two problems. First, banks hoard their own cash and become especially reluctant to lend to other banks. Second, nonfinancial institutions pull back

their lending to banks to avoid any chance of being defaulted upon. These problems reinforce the fear and keep lending markets frozen. It is rational for investors to reduce exposure to the stock market in this kind of a cycle. There are several pieces of evidence suggesting that the markets are fragile and especially concerned with the health of the banks. One indication is that lending rates for three-month loans between banks steadily rose during the last month, and they kept rising last week even after central banks around the world cut interest rates. These interbank borrowing rates only started to decline this week after the steps described below were announced. A second is that last Friday afternoon, the Dow Jones industrial average stock index began climbing sharply, precisely at the time of the announcement that no banks were going to fail as a result of settling the credit-default swap contracts that paid off the losses on bonds of Lehman Brothers. Finally, earlier this week, stock markets around the world rallied on the news that the U.S. and European governments had agreed on steps to prevent large banks from failing. These anecdotes hardly prove that the systemic banking concerns were paramount, but they are consistent with that view. 2) What is the government doing about this? The government is working on two different problems. First, it is working to prevent the collapse of the banking system in the near term. Second, it is working to promote lending while the banking system recovers. To prevent a banking collapse, Britain s government and some other countries opted to guarantee all short-term borrowing by banks. The U.S. is also planning to guarantee certain types of debt. These guarantees are temporary up to three years in the U.S. and are aimed at enhancing stability in two ways: They help secure stable funding for the banks because without the ability to borrow, banks cannot operate and they try to create incentives for new investors to lend to banks (more on this point below). The U.S. government has also announced that it will buy preferred stock (non-voting equity with fixed dividends) from banks. The primary assets of a bank are its loans and the securities it owns. Its liabilities the securities it issues in return for the money it gets to pay for the assets are primarily borrowing (using bonds, deposits, and other short-term debt such as commercial paper) and, to a much lesser extent, equity. Buying equity tackles the deeper concern that banks cannot absorb losses from the loans and securities investments they have made without partially defaulting on their

borrowing. Raising the amount of equity reassures the banks other suppliers of credit that they will be repaid and re-establishes their willingness to lend to banks. In parallel, the U.S. government is concentrating on trying to restart lending. The Federal Reserve announced that, for very highly rated companies, it will lend shortterm money directly (through next spring). Many of these borrowers had only been able to obtain funds for very short periods, often having to borrow for only a day at a time instead of months. The Fed s lending is aimed at allowing at least these businesses to be able to resume normal planning and spending. This is an extreme move, and it should become unnecessary (therefore possible to discontinue) if the crisis ends. 3) Why can t the private market do this? Why should the taxpayers have to pay for the mistakes that the banks made? One reason the private market will not inject equity now is out of the same concern that makes banks reluctant to lend to each other: fears that some banks have undisclosed bad assets (which are hard to value because they are not trading now) and may become insolvent. This makes investors fear that they may choose a bank that will soon fail. Moreover, if investors fear that many banks will soon fail, there will be runs on many others. These runs would wipe out the value of the private-equity injection. During a crisis, it is safe to provide capital to a given bank only if all banks become well capitalized (either by raising new capital or being acquired by well-capitalized banks). This makes outside investors hesitate to provide new equity. Government programs that allow large increases in capital in all reasonably healthy banks can remove the risk of many banks failing just after new equity is injected. The government can be viewed as solving a coordination problem (to deal with the entire system s stability) that private investors would not easily be able to do. This type of recapitalization need not be extremely expensive to taxpayers, but the devil is in the details. If bank losses are so large that most are currently insolvent, then private markets will not invest any new capital. In this case, the government can invest to recapitalize the bank after the F.D.I.C. fails the bank and wipes out equity and bondholders (protecting depositors and borrowers). In this extreme case, the government serves as a rapid replacement for bankruptcy courts to keep a banking system in place. We don t think that this is the current situation. This kind of government recapitalization would be very expensive to taxpayers. The inability to value the assets means that there is some ambiguity about which firms will and will not be closed. Banks have been raising equity throughout this

crisis. Washington Mutual and Lehman each raised over $12 billion in new equity over the last year, and these investors got wiped out in the firms failures. Without clear rules on how closures will be handled, private investors are reluctant to gamble on putting money in. In addition, it has become difficult to raise capital in shaky banks because no one knows how investors who inject capital now will be treated if the government later invests capital in their banks. 4) Why are bank assets so hard to value now? This crisis started because of losses related to mortgage-related securities and loans. The value of such assets is very difficult to assess, in large part because the securities are not trading, and so there is some guesswork in establishing their value. For the largest banks, roughly one quarter of their assets are real estate related, so not having good prices is a serious problem. We also know that after Lehman was shut down, it was found to have overstated the value of its assets relative to the conventions all the other banks were using to value the hard-to-price assets. A.I.G. also had some asset problems that only surfaced after the government helped it. 5) Didn t the Treasury initially propose to buy bad assets? Wouldn t that solve the valuation problem so that private money could be used to recapitalize the banks? The original Treasury plan and the successor plans described by the Treasury before this week have been schizophrenic. At times, the Treasury insisted that all it wanted to do was buy troubled assets to help establish a market price and not risk taxpayer money in doing this. If this got the market going and showed that most banks were very solvent (and identified the few that were not solvent), it would solve the problem. In this somewhat unlikely case, the government purchase could possibly make the asset market work today, and it could even increase prices by removing the fear that assets would soon be dumped at very low prices by banks about to fail. If the prices of asset purchases revealed that most banks were either insolvent or close to insolvent, the purchases would accomplish nothing good because private investors would not recapitalize banks (see part three above). Alternatively, the Treasury could have aimed to consciously overpay for the assets it would be buying. This would definitely put taxpayer money at risk and raise the value of the bank. This is a backdoor recapitalization of a bank and is worse for the taxpayer unless the Treasury gets bank equity equal to the value of the overpayment.

It is not clear to us whether this plan, used in isolation, would have been sufficient to recapitalize the banks. Without recapitalization, we doubt the crisis could be ended without massive bank failures. 6) Will the government plan work, or are there risks? There are three risks that must be navigated, and the details of the plan will be very important in attending to them. First, the plan must be set up to make sure that the banks emerge from this process with enough capital to operate normally. Perhaps a worst-case scenario would be to spend a lot of the taxpayer money and still not rehabilitate the banks. This is what happened in Japan; the perverse lending behavior of undercapitalized banks helped depress Japanese growth for a decade. This week, the government announced its intention to purchase $125 billion of preferred equity in the nine largest U.S. institutions. Because the government made the capital injections without having time to inspect the quality of these banks assets, we cannot be sure that $125 billion will be enough to make each wellcapitalized. One pattern throughout the crisis has been that firms have vigorously claimed to have adequate capital, only to fail shortly thereafter. Surprisingly, the banks are still allowed to pay (but not increase) dividends to their stockholders, potentially doing so with the money the government put in. This might undermine the intent to recapitalize the banks (we explain why in the next three paragraphs). Apart from these dividends, the banks shareholders claims only have value after the existing debt holders and the government s preferred-share investments are paid; this is why equity is often dubbed the residual claimants. These claimants get only what is left over after the higher-priority claimants are paid. Their low priority can drive a wedge between their incentives and those of other stakeholders. One challenge will be making sure that the banks have incentives to raise additional equity. Lately, the long-term debt of many of the largest banks is valued at a discount relative to its issue price. If more new equity is raised, it will allow the banks to do more lending and generate more profits. But the first claim on the profits is still owed to the existing long-term debt holders at maturity even though they put in no new money. This debt overhang problem can mean that the new financing might return very little to the investors buying the new equity because it benefits the long-term bond holders. As a result, the owners of undercapitalized banks would not want to issue more equity, and they would rather pay themselves a dividend and thus reduce bank equity. This can impede efforts to recapitalize.

Therefore, if some banks remain undercapitalized even after the government injection of capital, the regulators may need to force them to raise more privatesector equity funding. Paying a dividend to shareholders is the opposite. Second, the plan needs to be set up to avoid creating further panics. Once guarantees are being handed out, investors will prefer to lend and invest in these firms rather than other companies that do not have the guarantees. The excluded firms could see their access to credit dry up. The government determined that A.I.G. was too interconnected to the rest of the financial system to be allowed to fail; there may be other nonbanks that are also deeply interconnected. Care must be taken to make sure the guarantees do not trigger runs against these systemically critical firms. Third, the taxpayer s liability ought to be protected. If the government spends enough money, it can recapitalize all the banks; propping up insolvent and incompetent banks is a waste of taxpayer money. Likewise, injecting equity into banks with serious debt overhang will needlessly raise the cost of recapitalization. The obvious way to lower the costs to the taxpayer is to make sure existing long-term debt holders and equity holders do not capture too much of the windfall that comes from rehabilitating the banks. At the same time, there must be enough gains created so that more new equity can flow in if it is needed. These concerns can be managed in a variety ways. Our plan from last week is one option, but you can find suggestions from some of our colleagues at a web site we have just set up. Rather than focusing on any particular plan, a guiding principle is that a successful plan must deliver recapitalization in the least costly way to the taxpayer without creating additional panics. The freedom to pay dividends means that the current plan may not satisfy this principle. 7) How will we know when it is over? Are we going to have a depression? Interbank lending rates are already creeping down, but they remain severely elevated. These rates matter because they are used in the pricing of many loans, and hence they directly affect the affordability of credit. As these rates fall and other short-term lending resumes, it will mark the start of a return to normalcy. Our guess is that this will take months and not days, so credit seems likely to remain tight for some time. Elevated financing costs will slow growth. In the Great Depression, one-third of the U.S. banks failed, and the unemployment rate got to 25 percent. The economy is going to be in for a rough period, but the policy actions taken over the last week are going to prevent this type of collapse.

Finally, some journalists find it strange that we and many of our colleagues at the University of Chicago have been advocating bold government action to stop the collapse of the banking industry. We suspect that some of these people would be surprised to learn that Milton Friedman blamed timid and wrong-headed government policy for causing the Great Depression. Friedman was more concerned about monetary policy actions, but he and Anna Schwartz also gave a prominent place in the sequence during the contraction to successive waves of [bank] failures. The importance of preventing a banking-sector implosion has long been appreciated not only at Chicago, but also at other leading business schools and economics departments. This is why there has been such strong support for the equity injections from economists with very different political philosophies. It is too early to tell if the enthusiasm will fade once the details become known of how the administration plan is being implemented. Source: Steven Levitt, The New York Times, October 15, 2008.