Short Traders and Short Investors

Similar documents
Short Trading and Short Investing

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence

Liquidity skewness premium

Short Selling and the Subsequent Performance of Initial Public Offerings

Short Sales and Put Options: Where is the Bad News First Traded?

Short interest, returns, and fundamentals

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts

HOW ARE SHORTS INFORMED? SHORT SELLERS, NEWS, AND INFORMATION PROCESSING *

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information

Benefits of International Cross-Listing and Effectiveness of Bonding

Foreign Fund Flows and Asset Prices: Evidence from the Indian Stock Market

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection

Derivation of zero-beta CAPM: Efficient portfolios

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

The cross section of expected stock returns

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

Which shorts are informed? Ekkehart Boehmer Charles M. Jones Xiaoyan Zhang

High Short Interest Effect and Aggregate Volatility Risk. Alexander Barinov. Juan (Julie) Wu * This draft: July 2013

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract

Yale ICF Working Paper No March 2003

Short Selling and Economic Policy Uncertainty. Xiaping CAO. Lingnan College, Sun Yat-sen University.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

CORPORATE ANNOUNCEMENTS OF EARNINGS AND STOCK PRICE BEHAVIOR: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

DETERMINING THE EFFECT OF POST-EARNINGS-ANNOUNCEMENT DRIFT ON VARYING DEGREES OF EARNINGS SURPRISE MAGNITUDE TOM SCHNEIDER ( ) Abstract

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less?

What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium?

Tracking Retail Investor Activity. Ekkehart Boehmer Charles M. Jones Xiaoyan Zhang

Adjusting for earnings volatility in earnings forecast models

Do Investors Fully Understand the Implications of the Persistence of Revenue and Expense Surprises for Future Prices?

Underreaction, Trading Volume, and Momentum Profits in Taiwan Stock Market

Analysts and Anomalies ψ

Short selling and the price discovery process. Ekkehart Boehmer J. (Julie) Wu. This draft: August 16, 2010 ABSTRACT

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios

REIT and Commercial Real Estate Returns: A Postmortem of the Financial Crisis

Core CFO and Future Performance. Abstract

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Short Selling during Extreme Market Movements

Short Sales Constraints and Price Informativeness

Industry Indices in Event Studies. Joseph M. Marks Bentley University, AAC Forest Street Waltham, MA

Day-of-the-Week Trading Patterns of Individual and Institutional Investors

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Why Investors Want to Know the Size of Your Shorts

Investor Sophistication and the Mispricing of Accruals

A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968): Comparative Analysis of China and the US *

Arbitrage vs. Informed Short Selling: Evidence from Convertible Bond Issuers* John Hackney University of South Carolina

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS

The Effects of Stock Lending on Security Prices: An Experiment

Short Selling Risk. JOSEPH E. ENGELBERG, ADAM V. REED, and MATTHEW C. RINGGENBERG * Forthcoming, Journal of Finance ABSTRACT

Capitalizing on Analyst Earnings Estimates and Recommendation Announcements in Europe

Trinity College and Darwin College. University of Cambridge. Taking the Art out of Smart Beta. Ed Fishwick, Cherry Muijsson and Steve Satchell

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

The Value Premium and the January Effect

Long Run Stock Returns after Corporate Events Revisited. Hendrik Bessembinder. W.P. Carey School of Business. Arizona State University.

Do dividends convey information about future earnings? Charles Ham Assistant Professor Washington University in St. Louis

DO TARGET PRICES PREDICT RATING CHANGES? Ombretta Pettinato

Analysis of Short Sale Determinants along Particular NASDAQ Sectors

Is There a Risk Premium in the Stock Lending Market? Evidence from. Equity Options

Ambrus Kecskés (Virginia Tech) Roni Michaely (Cornell and IDC) Kent Womack (Dartmouth)

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

ANOMALIES AND NEWS JOEY ENGELBERG (UCSD) R. DAVID MCLEAN (GEORGETOWN) JEFFREY PONTIFF (BOSTON COLLEGE)

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

Online Appendix to Do Short-Sellers. Trade on Private Information or False. Information?

Can Short-sellers Predict Returns? Daily Evidence

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

INFORMATION AND INSURER FINANCIAL STRENGTH RATINGS: DO SHORT SELLERS ANTICIPATE RATINGS CHANGES?

MIT Sloan School of Management

Economics of Behavioral Finance. Lecture 3

JACOBS LEVY CONCEPTS FOR PROFITABLE EQUITY INVESTING

Do Equity Short Sellers Anticipate Bond Rating Downgrades?

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability

LIQUIDITY EXTERNALITIES OF CONVERTIBLE BOND ISSUANCE IN CANADA

Discussion Paper No. DP 07/02

Asubstantial portion of the academic

The Journal of Applied Business Research January/February 2013 Volume 29, Number 1

MARKET EFFICIENCY, SHORT SALES AND ANNOUNCEMENT EFFECTS. A Dissertation. Presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School. of Cornell University

SHORT SELLING RISK * Joseph E. Engelberg Rady School of Management, University of California, San Diego

Two Essays on Short Selling and Uptick Rules

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016)

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

Analyst Pessimism and Forecast Timing

Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK. Seraina C.

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Does perceived information in short sales cause institutional herding? July 13, Chune Young Chung. Luke DeVault. Kainan Wang 1 ABSTRACT

Trading Behavior around Earnings Announcements

Short Arbitrage, Return Asymmetry and the Accrual Anomaly

CHAPTER 6 DATA ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION

Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty?

Insider Trading Patterns

Vas Ist Das. The Turn of the Year Effect: Is the January Effect Real and Still Present?

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Beta dispersion and portfolio returns

ARCH Models and Financial Applications

Research Methods in Accounting

The good news in short interest

Internet Appendix to Credit Ratings and the Cost of Municipal Financing 1

Transcription:

Short Traders and Short Investors JESSE BLOCHER *, PETER HASLAG *, AND CHI ZHANG ** ABSTRACT We now know a great deal about short sellers. For example, they are informed and correct overpricing. However, the literature measures short selling as both a constraint and through trading activity (volume or trades). With a novel measure of short selling activity, we show that short-selling constraints and activity capture two distinct groups of short sellers. The first group ( short traders ) consists of unconstrained traders with a short horizon and lower risk tolerance. The second group ( short investors ) has a longer horizon and higher risk tolerance. While both types of short sellers are informed, they incorporate different types of information. Short traders trade in a matter of days to include short lived information (i.e. events) while short investors include more long-lived information (i.e. firm fundamentals). Keywords: Securities Lending, Short Selling, Limits to Arbitrage, Anomalies JEL: G12, G14, G23 First Version: November 18, 2017 Current version: December 4, 2017 * Assistant Professor of Finance, Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University, 401 21 st Avenue South, Nashville, TN 37203. ** Assistant Professor of Finance, Manning School of Business, University of Massachusetts Lowell, MA 01854. This research was supported by the Vanderbilt s Financial Markets Research Center. This work was conducted in part using the resources of the Advanced Computing Center for Research and Education at Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN and Wharton Research Data Services, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. The authors can be contacted via email at jesse.blocher@owen.vanderbilt.edu, peter.haslag@owen.vanderbilt.edu and Chi_Zhang1@uml.edu. 1

Short Traders and Short Investors ABSTRACT We now know a great deal about short sellers. For example, they are informed and correct overpricing. However, the literature measures short selling as both a constraint and through trading activity (volume or trades). With a novel measure of short selling activity, we show that short-selling constraints and activity capture two distinct groups of short sellers. The first group ( short traders ) consists of unconstrained traders with a short horizon and lower risk tolerance. The second group ( short investors ) has a longer horizon and higher risk tolerance. While both types of short sellers are informed, they incorporate different types of information. Short traders trade in a matter of days to include short lived information (i.e. events) while short investors include more long-lived information (i.e. firm fundamentals). Keywords: Securities Lending, Short Selling, Limits to Arbitrage, Anomalies JEL: G12, G14, G23 Current version: December 4, 2017 2

There is a large literature, dating back to Miller (1977), that has shown how short selling constraints predict negative stock returns (e.g., Asquith and Meulbroek (1996), Asquith, Pathak, and Ritter (2005), Nagel (2005), Boehme, Danielsen, and Sorescu (2006)). The framework is simple: given a distribution of investors with varying beliefs, short constraints inhibit the most pessimistic investors from participating in financial markets, and therefore, on average, the stock is overpriced compared to the unconstrained alternative. Miller (1977) showed this graphically, and Blocher, Reed, and Van Wesep (2013) showed it in a more rigorous supply and demand framework. Moreover, Blocher and Zhang (2017) have recently shown that short constraints are quite persistent, lasting on average 9 months. There is also a literature showing that short selling activity, defined as trades or trading volume labeled as short sales, predicts negative returns (e.g., Diether, Lee, and Werner (2009), Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang (2008)). Christophe, Ferri, and Angel (2004) identified short selling activity prior to earnings announcements is closely linked to post-announcement returns. Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010) find increased abnormal short activity prior to analyst downgrades and that this activity is related to post-downgrade returns. Engelberg, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2012) investigate short trade volume around news events. While clearly related, the precise relationship between these two literatures has not been investigated. Indeed, some suggest that the only difference between these two literatures is time scale (monthly vs daily). This may be true: tautologically, substantial cumulative short selling activity (i.e. trades) is a necessary condition for a short selling constraint to bind. Thus, the negative returns documented in both of these literatures could be due to two measured effects (short selling constraints and short selling trades/volume), both of which proxy for the same underlying phenomenon (negative information/beliefs among a segment of investors). This we consider to be our null hypothesis. Our alternative hypothesis is that the two measurements (activity and constraints) are capturing two different behaviors. The literature which measures short selling constraints with stock loan fees often sets the threshold for a constraint measure at the 90 th percentile (e.g. Blocher, Reed, and Van Wesep (2013)). This means that borrowing shares of a constrained stock is very expensive. At such high fees, basic economics dictates that few transactions should take place, therefore short selling activity should be low when a stock is short constrained. This is the very definition of the word constrained. Our alternative hypothesis then states that short selling 3

activity should only effectively generate stock price reductions when short selling is unconstrained. Additionally, when a stock is short constrained, there is little short selling activity and so there is no relationship between short activity and stock returns. In summary, our alternative hypothesis is that the two measurements of short selling identify separate and distinct behavior. The primary obstacle to investigating the interaction of short selling constraints and short selling activity has been data availability. Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang (2008), Christophe, Ferri, and Angel (2004), Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010) all use proprietary data. Diether, Lee, and Werner (2009) and Engelberg, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2012) use trade data from Regulation SHO, but this data is only available from January 2005 June 2007. Since short selling constraints are measured at a monthly frequency, the short time period for Regulation SHO limits the sample to 30 observations per firm for short selling constraints, making statistical inference difficult. We overcome this obstacle by developing a novel measure of short selling activity. With the daily stock loan demand data from Markit, we compute a measure of short selling activity as the daily change in shares demanded for stock loans, scaled by shares outstanding. Our measure is a net short selling activity measure, since daily demand is an aggregation of new stock loans and closed loans. This netting effect contrasts with short selling activity measures in the literature, which simply identify short trades and cannot identify covering trades. Delineating between net shorting-selling and net covering activity should strengthen the economic intuition of our tests. To validate our new measure, we show that it replicates both main results in Diether, Lee, and Werner (2009). We find strong evidence that results for short selling constraints and results for short selling activity are two independent effects. We divide our sample into three varying groups of constraint: persistently constrained (or constrained), transiently constrained (or transient), and unconstrained following Blocher and Zhang (2017). Short activity predicts negative returns at short horizons only in the unconstrained group. In the constrained group, there is no detectable short selling activity. Among transient stocks, in most cases there are also no results regarding a relationship between short selling activity and returns. In addition to clarifying the results due to the differing measures, we provide evidence that the two measures of short selling are capturing two separate groups of market participants. 4

In particular, these participants differ in their information set and risk tolerance, and so we call them short traders and short investors. We will characterize them more fully, but to start with, short investors buy and hold short positions in short constrained stocks, while short traders take short term positions in unconstrained stocks, following the two short selling measures just described. To study short sellers differing information sets, we study analyst downgrades and earnings announcements in an event study framework. First, consider downgrades. We find that short sellers only trade ahead of analyst downgrades among unconstrained stocks. Among constrained stocks, we find no evidence of short selling activity. Yet, simultaneously, the largest negative event returns are among constrained stocks, 50% higher than the other groups (-3.6% vs -2.2%, daily). This is consistent with informed short sellers, but with two different meanings of informed. Short investors, who have short positions in constrained stocks, have taken their position long before the downgrade and therefore likely formed their negative viewpoint using the firm s fundamentals (e.g. Dechow et al. (2001)). In this case, the downgrade is simply the analyst (and perhaps other stock owners) catching up to what the short investor already knew prior to the event. In contrast, we find that short traders trade on short-term information in unconstrained stocks ahead of analyst downgrades. This is consistent with Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010), who claim that trading ahead of analyst downgrades is a kind of leakage where analysts tip off traders who then trade just ahead of the event. Thus, short investors and short traders are operating with two different information sets and two different groups of stocks, but both profit off of analyst downgrades. Second, we look at negative earnings surprises. We find that among short constrained stocks there is no statistically significant negative event return. The negative return reaction to lower than expected earnings exists solely among unconstrained stocks. This is consistent with short investors establishing their position ahead of time and the stock adjusting slowly. This is evidence that short investors are informed: they have anticipated the lower than expected earnings such that when announced, there is no additional price change. Consistent with other results, we find no statistically significant short selling activity within ten days around negative earnings surprises among constrained stocks, rather we find weak evidence of covering transactions after the announcement. Short traders, in contrast, sell short just after the negative earnings announcement to capture the well-documented post-earnings-announcement drift. They 5

only do this among unconstrained stocks. This is informed trading, exploiting a known phenomenon, but it is not informed in the same way as short investors. Short investors and short traders also differ with regard to risk tolerance. We measure the riskiness of both the stock (volatility) and lending fees (short selling risk as in Engelberg, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2017)). What we find is striking. Short investors have a much higher tolerance for both volatility and short selling risk. In contrast, short traders only make very low risk trades with regard to both volatility and short selling risk. In a multivariate setting, we find that past stock volatility and short selling risk both predict short selling constraints but not activity. This implies that short investors who short sell a stock they have borrowed at a very high fee are bearing a substantial amount of risk, both in the movement of the stock price as well as the lending fee. Short traders who short sell unconstrained stocks (and pay very low fees), are taking much lower risk, measured both as volatility and as short selling risk. Furthermore, we briefly consider the duration of these positions. We do not offer additional tests of this, yet the logical argument follows directly from each measure s definition and the existing literature. Short traders horizon is typically 1-5 days and predicts returns over a similarly short horizon, whereas short investors time horizons are nine months on average, and predict returns over the same, longer horizon (Blocher and Zhang (2017)). To summarize, these results around information and risk indicates two different sets of short sellers. On the one hand, short investors gather fundamental information about firms, and are willing to pay high fees and maintain a riskier position over extended periods of time. These short sellers are identified with measures of short selling constraints. On the other hand, short traders identify shorter duration deviations in stock price or trade around events such as downgrades and earnings announcements. They pay lower fees, have shorter holding periods, and are only informed about short-run movements in stock prices. Finally, we look at stock price efficiency through the lens of the delay measure (Hou and Moskowitz (2005)). In accordance with Boehmer and Wu (2013), we find that only short traders are associated with less delay (i.e. more price efficiency). We find the opposite among constrained stocks. This stands to reason given that the delay measure is a weekly measure and the predictability of returns of up to six months among persistently constrained stocks is already documented in the literature (Blocher and Zhang (2017)). Diamond and Verrecchia (1987) provide theoretical reasons why these persistently constrained stocks held by short investors 6

should also achieve price efficiency. It may be that we need a price efficiency measure that operates on longer time scale to capture it, a task we leave to future research. Overall, our results are intuitive. The literature investigating short selling activity (trades, volume, etc.) has always used a pooled sample. Therefore, it stands to reason that the documented effects exist primarily among unconstrained stocks, which make up the vast majority of observations in any given panel data set (at any frequency). In contrast, the literature on short selling constraints has always focused on the tail of the distribution, either directly (Asquith, Pathak, and Ritter (2005)) or indirectly by using indicator variables to identify expensive stocks (Blocher, Reed, and Van Wesep (2013)). Either approach to measuring constraints ends up investigating just 10% of the sample. One can, in simple terms, quantify our contribution as showing definitively that these two samples have minimal overlap, and that the market participants identified by each measure have distinct information sets and risk tolerances. II. Hypothesis Development, Data, and Measurements We have briefly delineated our hypotheses in the introduction, but here we develop them more fully. Next, we describe our data set and then detail how we measure short selling activity and short selling constraints. A. Hypothesis Development It is true that some amount of short selling volume must precede the existence of a short selling constraint (as measured by high stock loan prices). However, this alone does not justify a hypothesis that short selling volume and short selling constraints are both measuring the same underlying phenomenon. The timing does not align for them to be measuring the same thing at a monthly frequency. The results in the literature (e.g., Diether, Lee, and Werner (2009)) use relatively high frequency measures of short selling volume (e.g., five days) and measure returns over an equally short period. Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang (2008), however, predict returns for 20 trading days with five days of trading volume. If short volume only predicts returns for the subsequent 20 trading days, and short selling constraints, measured monthly, predict the subsequent month s return, then the only way for these to be measuring the same effect is if they happen at the same time. 7

Therefore, the two measures of short selling must align in time if they are capturing the same underlying phenomena. There must be some measurable short trading volume happening while a stock is constrained as typically measured. Thus, we state our first hypothesis: H1: Short selling activity and short selling constraints measure the same underlying process. The equal and opposite hypothesis is simply that short selling activity and short selling constraints measure two separate and independent effects. While the hypothesis is stated clearly, we must be more precise about what it means to be independent. Two separate processes, if truly independent, should overlap approximately 50% of the time by randomness. Our hypothesis is more clear if we draw on the very definition of constraints, which means that an activity is inhibited: Short selling activity is statistically zero when a stock is short constrained: H2: Short selling activity results exist only in unconstrained stocks This hypothesis is consistent with the scenario described previously, where short selling volume is high in the lead up to a stock becoming short constrained. However, once a stock is constrained, short selling volume (activity) declines significantly and is no longer predictive. Indeed, if we find evidence for H1, we should reconsider the name of the set of results investigating so-called constraints. Hypothesis H2 can be tested in two specific ways. First, we should find that short selling activity impacts stock returns or incorporates information only when the stock is unconstrained. Second, we should find that short selling activity is no longer predictive when the stock is short constrained. As a corollary, we should be able to show that short activity has an impact in the full sample, which would further calibrate our measure to literature, and should be possible since the unconstrained stocks make up most of the sample. B. Data The timeframe for this study is June 2006 to December 2015, with a daily frequency. We begin with the ordinary common shares (SHRCD of 10 or 11) of all firms in the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP), and focus on stocks traded only on the NASDAQ and NYSE. We compute market capitalization groups using the NYSE breakpoints from Ken French s website. We compute the market-to-book ratio as in Daniel and Titman (2006), with market values taken from CRSP as of the end of December in the firm s fiscal year. 8

Our primary securities lending dataset is for the North American equity loan market from Markit (formerly Data Explorers), which includes data from 125 large custodians and 32 prime brokers in the securities lending industry. The data coverage is quite large, accounting for about 80% of U.S. equities, and 85% of the securities lending market. This dataset provides detailed information on each stock s demand, supply, and lending fees in the equity lending market. The Markit dataset also contains two important borrowing cost variables. The first is borrowing cost variable is the Daily Cost to Borrow Score (DCBS). The DCBS is a 1-10 integer categorization that describes how expensive a stock is to borrow, with 1 being the cheapest and 10 being the most expensive. The scores are computed by Markit for each stock-day and are based on actual lending fees that they receive from securities dealers but are not allowed to re-distribute. The second is indicative lending fees, which we use to compute short selling risk. We compute two risk measures. The first is volatility, which is compute daily for the trailing 252 days, and then annualized. The second is the short selling risk measure of Engelberg, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2017), which is also computed daily from 252 day trailing data. Rather than use the predicted value from their regression, however, we use the simple unconditional measure of risk based on historical loan fee variance. Engelberg, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2017) show in their appendix that it is more parsimonious and leads to the same inference. Our analyst downgrades data comes from Institutional Brokers Estimate System (I/B/E/S), using the I/B/E/S Recommendations Detail File over the period July 2006 to September 2016. Following Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010) and Mikhail, Walther, and Willis (2004), we restrict our sample based on the following criteria. First, during the sample period, the stock price has to be at least $5 on the downgrade date. Second, there are no other downgrades in the preceding week and no quarterly earnings announcement in the preceding or following week. Third, we exclude downgrades that transitioning from Strong Buy to Buy. Fourth, we only include the downgrades that the time difference between current recommendation and prior recommendation is within 365 days. Finally, we require non-missing information of share price, total shares outstanding, volume, and stock return during our sample period. We also require non-missing information of SPECIAL and PERSIST. In case a downgrade occurs on a non-trading day, the next closest trading day will be coded as though it were the downgrade day. Summary statistics for our dataset are in Table I. Short selling has a slightly negative mean implying that we observe slightly more net covering of short positions over our sample. 9

Approximately five percent of the firm days are persistently constrained. That is, these firms have experienced higher fees to borrow the stock over the last forty-two trading days. Alternatively, General Collateral represents around 71% of the sample. The remainder, Transient, represents stocks that have had at least one day in which it was expensive to borrow the stock and makes up about 16% of the sample. C. Measures of Activity and Constraints We measure daily short selling activity as the change in daily short interest, divided by shares outstanding. We sometimes present results (for robustness) of changes in short interest divided by daily share volume (or Short Share), but our primary variable of interest is scaled by shares outstanding. Both scaling variables (shares outstanding and daily volume) have been used in the short selling literature, yet we have a slight preference for shares outstanding because it is more stable over the relevant time frames, and so variation comes primarily from the changes in daily short interest, not overall trading volume. Because our measure is a net measure, we can also capture net covering activity (i.e. changes where short interest is decreasing on net). Therefore, to sharpen our analysis we sometimes report results where we have set all negatives (i.e. net covering activity) to zero. This way, a reported coefficient must be due to increasing or decreasing net short selling activity, and is in no way related to covering. For econometric reasons, we include the mirror-image variable that includes only net covering observations with net short selling activity zeroed out. As a final robustness test, we measure abnormal short selling activity as a level of activity exceeding two standard deviations computed over the firm s trailing two months average. We measure short constraint following the PERSIST measure of Blocher and Zhang (2017), but at a daily level. Starting with daily data, we create an indicator for days where stock lending fees were high, DCBS > 1. We then take a moving average of the indicator over the last 42 trading days. 1 If the moving average is exactly equal to one then this implies that the stock has been persistently expensive to borrow and we therefore label it as CONST for constrained. To contrast our constrained variable, we classify stocks as being unconstrained (UNCONST), or general collateral ( GC ), when the trailing moving average equals zero. We drop all stock- 1 For the majority of our tests we will utilize forty two trading days which amounts to two months. This helps us maintain a consistent definition as Blocher and Zhang (2017). 10

month observations where more than 50% of DCBS observations are missing, and in practice this filter eliminates few observations, since DCBS is populated quite consistently. All days with the trailing moving average between 0 and 1 we label as Transient (TRANS), since they are transiently or temporarily short constrained. We start with a simple calibration exercise since our measure of short activity, in particular, is novel. 2 What we show is that cumulative short activity predicts short selling constraints, as just defined. Recall that the constraint measure is based on loan fees, and high loan fees certainly inhibit short selling, and almost certainly result from high demand. Separately, our measure is based on changes in daily short interest, or loans demanded, so the link between the two need not be mechanical. Rather, we are clearly showing that our measure is not picking up noise or some other unobserved variable. The calibration is in Table II. Using each of the three methods to measure short selling activity we find a positive and significant relationship between activity and constraints. The empirical regression asks how activity today predicts becoming constrained in the next two months in a linear probability model with a dependent variable taking the value of one if the stock is constrained forty-two trading days ahead. Because our definition of constraint relies on a high lending fee for the previous forty-two trading days, we use the indicator forty-two days in the future to avoid conflating the two. Hence, we run the following regression Persist i,t+42 = β 1 Short Activity i,t + δ Controls i,t + τ t + θ i + ε i,t+42 for stock i on day t. We include controls for stock characteristics capturing liquidity, trading, and return moments, as well as firm and day fixed effects. Moreover, we double cluster standard errors along the firm and day dimensions. We find that regardless of how we measure short activity, more activity leads to a greater likelihood of becoming constrained. In an economic sense, we see that a one standard deviation increase in shorting activity leads to a 0.20% increase in the likelihood of becoming constrained. Recall that the unconditional probability of becoming persistently constrained is about five percent, so this is a relative increase of around 5.8%. Furthermore, we see that times of greater trading activity and slightly higher volatility are 2 In addition, we also replicate Diether, Lee, and Werner (2009) from July 2006 to June 2007, which is the one year that Reg SHO and our sample overlap. We show that our measure broadly replicates their findings, when moved to the later period. Their original measurement period was January December 2005. Results available upon request. 11

associated with an increased likelihood of becoming constrained. On the whole, it appears that that our intuition that constraints are preceded by large amounts of activity is accurate. III. Short Activity versus Short Constraints In this first results section, we focus on the two primary measures of short selling in the literature: activity (i.e. short volume or trades) and constraints (i.e. high cost to short). We measure activity as the change in daily short interest divided by shares outstanding. We measure constraint as a persistent constraint: a stock has been expensive-to-borrow for the trailing fortytwo trading day moving window. Our approach is to follow the pattern set by Diether, Lee, and Werner (2009), in which we test whether high returns lead to short selling activity, and then whether short selling activity predicts negative returns. Our additional contribution is to split this analysis based short selling constraints leading into the test. This is a test of our two hypotheses. If we find results only where the stock is short constrained, then we conclude that H1 is correct: both measures identify the same underlying phenomena. If we only find results among unconstrained stocks, then we conclude that H2 is correct: constraints and activity measure two independent (and separate) phenomena. As initial evidence, we present a simple frequency table in Table III. The first item to note is that 79.9% of the sample is in the unconstrained category, which is consistent with past literature. 19.3% of the sample we have categorized as High Short Activity, but 14.6% is in the unconstrained category. Only 1.1% is both High Short Activity and Constrained. This previews our results that the two measures are separate phenomena. A. Returns predicting short selling Next we turn to a multivariate setting. Here, we investigate whether high short selling activity follows positive returns among constrained or unconstrained stocks. The first set of results are in Table IV, where we test whether past returns predict short selling activity. In this table, we use our simple measure of Short Activity, which is the change in daily short interest, divided by shares outstanding. However, here we winsorize this measure at zero, meaning that every negative number is set to zero. The reason for doing so is that we want to isolate our measure only to identifying net short selling activity. Negative changes in daily short interest 12

indicate net covering activity, which adds noise or possibly a spurious correlation. We are not interested in predicting net covering activity in this specification. The primary variable of interest is Past Return [-5,-1], which is the cumulative raw return over the five days previous to day t. It is positive and significant in every specification except (7). This final specification is the subsample of only constrained stocks (CONST). There, the coefficient is just 0.031, and the t-statistic is 0.13. This compares to the unconstrained sample, which has a coefficient of 0.925 and a t-statistic of 13.49. There is also some expected ordering when we investigate some different subsamples. We take the unconstrained sample, and further subsample it to include only stock-days where the firm stays unconstrained (subset STAY). This is to ensure that we are not including short selling activity that is leading to a constraint, as we identified in Table II. This analysis is model (4), and the result is essentially identical to model (3) across all variables. Model (5) picks up the remainder of the sample that starts unconstrained but changes (CHANGE) to be more constrained. We still find an effect of activity here, but both economic and statistical significance is diminished. Finally, in model (6), we analyze only transiently constrained stocks (TRANS), which are the middle group, neither constrained nor unconstrained. The coefficient here is also positive and significant, but less economically and statistically so than the unconstrained specification in Model (3). Model (1) and (2) are baseline specifications using the entire sample, which give a positive and significant coefficient on Past Return, consistent with Diether, Lee, and Werner (2009). To further test our hypotheses, we turn to Table V. This table shows results for the same specifications as above, but changes the dependent variable. We start with the same short activity measure: change in daily short interest divided by shares outstanding. Here, we define Abnormal Short Activity as an indicator variable where Short Activity exceeds two standard deviations measured over the past two months, with a daily moving window. This is, by definition, an asymmetric measure, so there is no need to exclude net covering activity as with the previous measure. Table V largely corroborates Table IV. The biggest difference is that there is no longer any result in the CHANGE or TRANS samples. Said differently, Table V shows that past positive returns predict abnormal short activity only among stocks that are unconstrained. If that stock begins moving toward a constraint (CHANGE, model 5) or is transiently expensive-to- 13

borrow (TRANS, model 6) there is no result. As before, there remains no result among constrained stocks, seen again in model 7. Overall, we have strong evidence that returns only predict short selling activity among unconstrained stocks. The prediction is never present among constrained stocks. Depending on the precise measurement of short activity, there may be some predictive ability among stocks that are transiently constrained or transitioning to constrained, but the evidence here is not consistent. B. Short selling predicting returns Next, we investigate the well-documented result that short activity predicts negative returns. This also follows Diether, Lee, and Werner (2009), as well as Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang (2008). As before, our innovation is to further split the sample into constrained, transient, and unconstrained, as well as our adjusted samples of STAY and CHANGE where we subsample unconstrained based on whether the stock remains that way or not. The primary results are in Table VI. In this table, we have a slightly different measure of short activity: we normalize by daily volume instead of shares outstanding. This more closely follows the literature and provides a stronger result. Again, we compute the Abnormal version of this measure, which sets an indicator when short activity (redefined with daily volume) exceeds two standard deviations over the rolling moving average of the past two month s activity. The dependent variable is the cumulative raw return from day 0 to day 2. The primary explanatory variable of interest is Abnormal Short Activity, as described above. Models (1) and (2) show the main result present in the literature in the pooled sample. Abnormal short selling activity predicts negative returns. In model (3), we subsample to include only unconstrained stocks (UNCONST) and find virtually identical results, though with slightly more economic and statistical significance. In the STAY sample, where stocks are unconstrained and remain that way, we also find very similar results to the pooled sample (model 2). The CHANGE sample, where stocks are unconstrained but do not remain so (model 5), there is now no statistical significance. This continues in model 6 (transient) and model 7 (constrained). In model 7, where stocks are constrained, the coefficient is positive, though close to zero and statistically insignificant. Table VII repeats this analysis, but uses our preferred definition of short activity, change in daily short interest divided by shares outstanding. Again, we use the abnormal version of this measure, setting an indicator when it exceeds one standard deviation measured over a trailing, 14

moving annual window. The results are directionally similar to those in Table VI, but somewhat reduced in both economic and statistical significance. In this panel, the only coefficient that is statistically significant is the one in the unconstrained subsample. Neither the pooled sample (models 1 and 2) nor any sample with any kind of constraint yields a negative and significant result. While it would be preferable that results be more similar to Table VI, these results at least corroborate hypothesis H2, that short selling activity only predicts negative returns among unconstrained stocks. 3 IV. Short Traders versus Short Investors Having established that the two measures of short selling in the literature (activity and constraints) are identifying two different phenomena, we now attempt to better characterize the differences. For example, we know that short sellers are informed, but this is a broad term. Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang (2008) show that short sellers are primarily institutional investors, a group typically seen as sophisticated. Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010) and Christophe, Ferri, and Angel (2004) show that short sellers anticipate analyst downgrades and earnings announcements, respectively. Dechow et al. (2001) show that high short interest is associated with firms having weak fundamentals (e.g. book-to-market). These are all ways of describing short sellers as informed, but are they describing the same groups of short sellers? We begin to address this question here. 4 Similarly, it is clear that short selling is risky (e.g., Engelberg, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2017)). However, Engelberg, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2017) focus primarily on longer holding periods and their results use a monthly frequency. This strongly implies that they are only analyzing short sellers who end up constrained, not those measured with short selling activity measures. Taken together, this would imply that the benefits to information gathering (e.g. in Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang (2008), etc.) do not pair with the risks faced by short sellers in Engelberg, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2017), but this relationship is as of yet untested. 3 In unreported results, we also perform this analysis using our short activity measure, without using the abnormal indicator. We get directionally similar results, but none are statistically significant. The t-statistic on Short Activity in the unconstrained sample is -1.69, which almost meets the 10% level of significance. 4 Engelberg, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2012) test whether shorts are informed about news events, but we do not test this event. 15

Our goal in this section is to better characterize what we see as two distinct groups of market participants, each measured by one of the two short selling measures. We call the first group short traders, who we claim are measured by short activity, and we call the second group short investors, who we claim are measured by short constraints. A. Short traders and short investors have different information sets To investigate varying information sets, we analyze analyst downgrades as in Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010) and negative earnings announcements as in Christophe, Ferri, and Angel (2004). Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010) find that short sellers anticipate downgrades by trading ahead of them, and test whether this result is due to tipping or instead due to fundamental analysis of publicly available information. They conclude that their result is due to tipping i.e. analysts somehow communicate to other market participants that new information is forthcoming. Christophe, Ferri, and Angel (2004) find that short sellers trade in anticipation of earnings announcements, and that more activity is associated with larger (negative) postannouncement returns. We revisit these two results in light of our finding that short sellers are not a uniform group. Specifically, we split the two samples (Analyst Downgrades and Earnings Announcements) into our three main groupings by short selling constraints: constrained, unconstrained, and transient (neither). Then, we separately investigate both stock returns and short selling activity around the events within each of these categories. The results for analyst downgrades are in Table VIII and Table IX for returns and short activity, respectively. In Table VIII, model 1 shows the return pattern in the pooled sample. There is a small run-up ahead of the event, then a large negative return on the event day itself, then no detectable return post-event. Among constrained stocks, in model 2, we see an event return that is 50% larger than the event return in unconstrained stocks (model 3): -3.61% versus - 2.18%. It is also larger than the event return among transient stocks, seen in model 4 (-2.91%). Table IX shows a similar specification, but this time measuring short selling activity. In models 1-4, it is abnormal short selling activity, and in models 5-8 it is short activity. Both tell a similar story: in model 1 and 5, which are the pooled sample, we see significantly more short selling activity both ahead of the event and then much more on the event day. This combined with the previous table s result is what Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010) found. This pooled 16

result masks some underlying differences, however. Among constrained stocks (models 2 and 6), there is no detectable short selling at all, before or during the event. The only result is after the event, where a negative and significant coefficient indicates net covering activity. This stands to reason if the short seller s negative information has now been revealed publicly and he or she is closing the position at a profit. The Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010) result lives entirely in the unconstrained sample, in models 3 and 7. There is net short selling ahead of the event and greater magnitudes on the event day. This is intuitive since short constrained stocks are, by definition, difficult to short sell. It also has implications for how we view short sellers information. Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010) claimed that they had evidence that their result indicated that there was tipping of some sort happening ahead of analyst downgrades, and this is what it meant for short sellers to be informed ahead of analyst downgrades. We concur, but our results complete the picture. Instead of rejecting the hypothesis of short sellers using publicly available firm fundamentals, our results are consistent with short investors trading on that type of long-lived information and the analyst downgrade revealing it clearly to the public. Dechow et al. (2001) has shown that short sellers do, in fact, use fundamental information to inform their trades. Our results show that constrained stocks have the largest return response, but without any short activity ahead of time. This is consistent with longer-lived negative beliefs about a stock with positions in place before the 21-day symmetric window around analyst downgrades. The analyst downgrade clearly reveals the negative information already obtained (or perhaps processed using publicly available information) by the short investor. We find more evidence of this when we consider negative earnings surprises in Table X and Table XI for returns and activity, respectively. Table X shows that there is no return result for negative earnings surprises among constrained stocks. We measure this using the bottom quintile of earnings surprises using a seasonal random walk model (SUE1), but find very similar results when we further adjust for extraordinary items (SUE2) or when we use analyst expectations (SUE3). We also use the sample where the earnings surprise is negative rather than the bottom quintile (a larger sample) and find the same results. We interpret this result as short investors using fundamental information. They have already established their very costly short position, and have held it for a while. The very fact that the stock is expensive to borrow is itself a signal to owners that they may want to sell 17

(Blocher and Zhang (2017)). Because the stock has adjusted downward ahead of the earnings announcement, even though the surprise is negative, and sometimes large, there is not a statistically significant change in price upon the revelation of this information. In contrast, in all other samples (ALL, UNCONST, TRANS), there is a negative and significant event return. Table XI shows results around short selling activity. Again, we measure activity as changes in short interest divided by shares outstanding and using an indicator for abnormal short activity. Regardless of measure, we find no short activity among constrained stocks around earnings announcements. This is consistent with our other results that these activities are independent. Instead, what we find is that informed short traders short stocks immediately after the negative earnings surprise. This is informed trading due to the well-documented earnings announcement drift phenomena, and is likely profitable though we do not investigate it further. We do not find any short trading ahead of earnings announcements as found in Christophe, Ferri, and Angel (2004). B. Short traders and short investors have different risk tolerances A key differentiating characteristics among market participants is risk aversion. Thus, it is natural to ask if these two groups of investors, short traders and short investors, have different tolerances for risk. Risk in short selling has two dimensions, both important. One is the stock volatility, a standard measure for any investor. However, volatility should loom even larger for short sellers due to the inherent leverage in their position. If the price goes against them (i.e. up), then they will be required to put up more collateral for their stock loan. This is directly analogous to a leveraged long position. The second dimension of risk for short sellers is lending fee variance, or short selling risk, as coined by Engelberg, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2017). This is, very simply, the risk that lending fees, which are set daily, may rise over the course of holding a short position, making it gradually more expensive to hold. Our goal is to measure the riskiness of positions taken by short investors versus short traders. We set up the test from the perspective of a short seller, ex ante, sizing up the risk of a possible short position. Specifically, we test if trailing measure of risk predict short selling constraints (short investor perspective) or higher short selling activity (short trader perspective). 18

Table XII shows the results. Models 1-3 investigate the risk tolerance of short investors because it uses a leading measure of persistent constraints. Models 4-6 investigate the risk tolerance of short traders, because it uses a leading measure of short activity. The results are striking, though not surprising given what we know already. There is a positive and significant relationship between both volatility and short selling risk and subsequent constraints in models 1-3. Put differently, stocks that are high risk are likely to become constrained. This implies that a short investor considering a position in a stock already somewhat constrained should already know that this is a risky stock and therefore a risky position. Since constraints are often persistent, we add in a lagged constraint indicator, CONST and interact it with our risk measures. The interaction coefficient is positive and significant for short selling risk. This shows that stocks that have been constrained and continue to be constrained are even riskier to short, and that short investors must, therefore, have a very high risk tolerance. The story is almost the opposite among short traders. There is essentially no relationship between short selling risk and future short activity. In model 4, the coefficient is negative and significant, which indicates less risk, but the other models have no significance. Strikingly, the relationship between volatility and future short selling activity is negative and significant. This is understandable if we conceive of short traders as short-term traders engaging in short horizon (less than 5 days) arbitrage trades. A very volatile stock makes short-term arbitrage trades harder to detect and harder to execute profitable. Therefore, higher volatility stocks will generally have less short selling when the investment horizon is short. The volatility swamps the expected return from the short-term trade. C. Price Efficiency: only short traders help? Lastly, we turn to price efficiency. Short sellers are informed, and more informed traders mean more accurate prices. Short sellers correct overpricing, and thus should be associated with more accurate prices. It is now broadly accepted in the literature that short selling is associated with price efficiency. However, which short sellers help price efficiency, traders or investors? Diamond and Verrecchia (1987) show how costly short selling drives out uninformed short sellers. Therefore it is possible that short investors are the driving force behind price efficiency since they pay higher prices and face greater risk to establish short positions. In contrast, a close look at Boehmer and 19

Wu (2013), who study short selling and price efficiency, reveals that their measure of short selling is activity based (short volume from Reg SHO), not constraint-based. Therefore, we expect that short traders also play a role in price efficiency. In contrast, Saffi and Sigurdsson (2011) show that short selling constraints, as measured by low institutional ownership, are associated with worse price efficiency. Our results are in Table XIII investigating short constraints and Table XIV investigating short activity. We measure price efficiency with the weekly Delay 1 measure in Hou and Moskowitz (2005). We find that short constraints are associated with less price efficiency (more delay in incorporating information). This is consistent with the prediction in Blocher and Zhang (2017) and results in Saffi and Sigurdsson (2011). In this case, longer-term short investors are constrained from fully expressing their beliefs through trades, and so the price does not correct as it otherwise should. This is also consistent with Diamond and Verrecchia (1987), who model persistent short sale constraints where prices are efficient, but prices take longer to adjust to negative information in the presence of constraints. This result shows up in the first row of the table, where we have an indicator variable for constraints (CONST). It is positive and significant in all specifications, indicating that constraints are associated with more price delay (less price efficiency). In row 2, we see that transient stocks (TRANS) are similar, but with much smaller economic magnitude. In model (4), we begin to include measures of activity, to see if high activity can mitigate or overcome the effect of constraints, but it does not. Short activity is negative but insignificant. In model 5, we include abnormal short activity, and it does show up as negative and significant, indicating that greater short activity means less delay (more efficiency). However, this is an independent effect, not one that in any way mitigates constraints. When we interact the two, CONST and abnormal short activity, the coefficient is insignificant. This result previews what we find in Table XIV, which focuses on short activity. Once again, Delay is the dependent variable, and now Abnormal Short Activity is in row 1 as the key explanatory variable. In the whole sample (ALL) and in the unconstrained sample (models 1-5), we see that abnormal short activity is associated with less Delay, which is to say greater price efficiency. This is consistent with Boehmer and Wu (2013). However, in models 6-8, we subset to isolate the part of sample experiencing some amount of constraints and the result disappears. It 20