ECON 581. Introduction to Arrow-Debreu Pricing and Complete Markets. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Similar documents
Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Slides III - Complete Markets

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982

On Diamond-Dybvig (1983): A model of liquidity provision

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

14.05 Lecture Notes. Labor Supply

Solutions to Problem Set 1

1 Dynamic programming

Solutions for Homework #5

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Arrow Debreu Equilibrium. October 31, 2015

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 3

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Consumption and Saving

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Lecture 2: Stochastic Discount Factor

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Attitudes Toward Risk. Joseph Tao-yi Wang 2013/10/16. (Lecture 11, Micro Theory I)

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

ECON 200 EXERCISES. (b) Appeal to any propositions you wish to confirm that the production set is convex.

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

Macro 1: Exchange Economies

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

ECON 815. Uncertainty and Asset Prices

The endowment of the island is given by. e b = 2, e c = 2c 2.

Time, Uncertainty, and Incomplete Markets

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 7: Moral Hazard. Patrick Legros

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Money Demand. ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

Lecture 2: The Neoclassical Growth Model

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Answers to June 11, 2012 Microeconomics Prelim

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. A Neo-Classical Benchmark Economy. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

Consumption-Savings Decisions and Credit Markets

The Robinson Crusoe model; the Edgeworth Box in Consumption and Factor allocation

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Intro to Economic analysis

Lecture Notes: November 29, 2012 TIME AND UNCERTAINTY: FUTURES MARKETS

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 8: Insurance Markets

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

X ln( +1 ) +1 [0 ] Γ( )

Financial Economics: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing in General Equilibrium c

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

1 Mar Review. Consumer s problem is. V (z, K, a; G, q z ) = max. subject to. c+ X q z. w(z, K) = zf 2 (K, H(K)) (4) K 0 = G(z, K) (5)

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

Financial Economics: Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

ECON 581. Decision making under risk. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

The text book to this class is available at

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Uncertainty in Equilibrium

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

20. Financial Integration, Financial Development, and Global Imbalances

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

One-Period Valuation Theory

Advanced Microeconomics

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Outline 1 Technology 2 Cost minimization 3 Profit maximization 4 The firm supply Comparative statics 5 Multiproduct firms P. Piacquadio (p.g.piacquadi

Cash-in-Advance Model

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification

UCLA Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory

ECON MACROECONOMIC THEORY Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 5 - Closed Economy Model Towson University 1 / 47

Transcription:

ECON 58. Introduction to Arrow-Debreu Pricing and Complete Markets Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko / 28

Arrow-Debreu economy General equilibrium, exchange economy Static (all trades done at period 0) but multi-period No restrictions on preferences 2 / 28

Basic setting Two dates: 0, and. This set-up, however, is fully generalizable to multiple periods. S possible states of nature at date, indexed by s =, 2,..., S with the corresponding probabilities π(s). One perishable (=non storable) consumption good I agents, indexed i =,..., I, with preferences u i 0(c i 0) + β i S s= π(s)u i (c i (s)) Agent i s endowment is described by the vector {y i 0, (yi (s)) s=,2,...,s} 3 / 28

Traded securities Arrow-Debreu securities (AD) (contingent claims): security for state s date priced at time 0 at q 0 (s) promises delivery of one unit of commodity tomorrow (at date ) if state s is realized and nothing otherwise Thus, individual i s consumption in state s will equal her holdings of AD securities for state s, date 4 / 28

Agent s problem. Competitive equilibrium setting max u i 0(c i 0) + β i c i 0,ci (),...,ci (S) s.t. S π(s)u i (c i (s)) s= (P) S S c i 0 + q(s)c 0 i (s) y0 i + q(s)y 0 (s) i s= s= c i 0, c i (),..., c i (S) 0 5 / 28

Definition of the equilibrium Equilibrium is a set of contingent claim prices such that: q 0 (), q 0 (2),..., q 0 (S) at those prices c i 0, ci (),..., ci (S) solve problem (P) for all i s, and 2 I c i 0 = i= I y0, i i= I c i (s) = i= I y(s), i for each s =, 2,..., S. i= 6 / 28

Competitive equilibrium and Pareto optimality illustrated Agents Endowments Preferences t=0 t= s= s=2 Agent 0 2 2 c 0 + 0.9 [ 3 ln(c ()) + 2 3 ln(c (2))] Agent 2 5 4 6 2 c2 0 + 0.9 [ 3 ln(c2 ()) + 2 3 ln(c2 (2))] 7 / 28

Maximization problems Agent : max {c 0,c (),c (2)} 0 2 [ + }{{} 0.9 3 ln(c ()) + 2 ] 3 ln(c (2)) =β 0 + q() 0 + 2 q(2) 0 c () q() 0 c (2) q(2) 0 }{{} =c 0 Agent 2: max {c 2 0,c2 (),c2 (2)} 0 2 [ + }{{} 0.9 3 ln(c2 ()) + 2 ] 3 ln(c2 (2)) =β 2 5 + 4 q() 0 + 6 q(2) 0 c 2 () q() 0 c 2 (2) q(2) 0 }{{} =c 2 0 8 / 28

Optimum Optimality conditions: c Agent : () : q 0() 2 = 0.9 c (2) : q 0(2) 2 = 0.9 2 c 2 Agent 2: () : q 0() 2 = 0.9 c 2 (2) : q 0(2) 2 = 0.9 2 Feasibility conditions: 3 c () 3 c (2) 3 c 2 () 3 c 2 (2) c () + c 2 () = 5 c (2) + c 2 (2) = 8 c () = c 2 () = 2.5 c (2) = c 2 (2) = 4. 9 / 28

Prices of AD securities Optimality conditions can be expressed as q 0 (s) = 0.9 π(s) /2 c i (s), s, i =, 2, or That is, q 0 (s) = β π(s) u i 0 c i 0 u i c i (s), s, i =, 2. today s price of the tomorrow s good if state s is realized price of the today s good = MUi (s) MU i 0 q 0 () = 2 0.9 3 q 0 (2) = 2 0.9 2 3 c c = 2 0.9 () 3 2.5 = 0.24 2 = 2 0.9 (2) 3 4 = 0.30 0 / 28

Notes on AD prices Prices reflect probabilities, and marginal rates of substitution and therefore relative scarcities of the goods (total quantities of goods differ in different states) If date marginal utilities were constant (linear, risk neutral preferences), the goods endowments wouldn t influence the AD prices, which would be then exactly proportional to the state probabilities / 28

Post-trade equilibrium consumptions t=0 t= utility s= s=2 Agent 9.04 2.5 4 5.62 Agent 2 5.96 2.5 4 4.09 Total 5 5 8 c 0 = 0 + 0.24 + 2 0.3 2.5 0.24 4 0.3 = 9.04 c 2 0 = 5 + 4 0.24 + 6 0.3 2.5 0.24 4 0.3 = 5.96 2 / 28

Is the equilibrium Pareto optimal? (If yes, it is impossible to rearrange the allocation of consumptions so that the utility of one agent is higher without reducing the utility of the other agent.) 3 / 28

Pareto problem max u (c 0, c (), c (2)) + λu 2 (c 2 0, c 2 (), c 2 (2)) {c 0,c (),c (2)} 0 s.t. c 0 + c 2 0 = 5 c () + c 2 () = 5 c (2) + c 2 (2) = 8 c 0, c (), c (2), c 2 0, c 2 (), c 2 (2) 0 FOCs: u 0 u 2 0 = u () u 2 () = u (2) = λ. (2) u 2 4 / 28

In terms of our example, the first 3 equalities are /2 0.9 /2 = 0.9 3 c () 3 c 2 () = 0.9 2 3 c (2) 0.9 2 3 c 2 (2) In our example, competitive equilibrium corresponds to the Pareto optimum with equal weighting of the two agents utilities, λ =. 5 / 28

Incomplete markets=less AD securities than states Assume that only state- date- AD security is available. Agent : max {c 0,c ()} 0 2 0 + q() 0 c () q() 0 }{{} =c 0 [ + }{{} 0.9 3 ln(c ()) + 2 ] 3 ln(2) =β Agent 2 : max {c 2 0,c2 ()} 0 2 5 + 4 q() 0 c 2 () q() 0 }{{} =c 2 0 [ + }{{} 0.9 3 ln(c2 ()) + 2 ] 3 ln(6) =β 2 6 / 28

Post-trade allocation FOCs and the feasibility condition imply c () = c2 () = ( + 4)/2 = 2.5. t=0 t= utility s= s=2 Agent 9.64 2.5 2 5.5<5.62 Agent 2 5.36 2.5 6 4.03<4.09 Total 5 5 8 The market with AD securities for each state, called complete market, is Pareto superior to the incomplete market. 7 / 28

Risk sharing. New endowment matrix Agents Endowments Preferences t=0 t= s= s=2 Agent 4 5 2 c 0 + 0.9 [ 2 ln(c ()) + 2 ln(c (2))] Agent 2 4 5 2 c2 0 + 0.9 [ 2 ln(c2 ()) + 2 ln(c2 (2))] 8 / 28

Table : No trade Agents Utilities Expected utility in period t= s= s=2 Agent ln() ln(5) 2 ln() + 2 ln(5)=0.8047 Agent 2 ln(5) ln() 2 ln(5) + 2 ln()=0.8047 9 / 28

Table 2: Trade under complete markets Agents Utilities Expected utility in period t= s= s=2 Agent ln(3) ln(3) 2 ln(3) + 2 ln(3)=.099 Agent 2 ln(3) ln(3) 2 ln(3) + 2 ln(3)=.099 Both agents are perfectly insured=no variation in tomorrow s consumption regardless of the realized state of nature. This happens because the aggregate endowment in state and 2 is the same (=6), that is there s no aggregate risk. 20 / 28

Notes on Pareto optimal allocations λ = u 0 u 2 0 = u () u 2 () = u (2) u 2 (2) u () u (2) = u2 () u 2 (2) If one of the two agents is fully insured no variation in her date consumption (MRS=) the other must be as well 2 / 28

Notes on Pareto optimal allocations λ = u 0 u 2 0 = u () u 2 () = u (2) u 2 (2) u () u (2) = u2 () u 2 (2) If one of the two agents is fully insured no variation in her date consumption (MRS=) the other must be as well More generally, if the MRS are to differ from, given that they must be equal between the agents, the low consumption-high MU state must be the same for both agents and similarly for the high consumption-low MU state. Impossible when there s no aggregate risk, hence individuals are perfectly insured in the absence of aggregate risk. 2 / 28

Notes on Pareto optimal allocations λ = u 0 u 2 0 = u () u 2 () = u (2) u 2 (2) u () u (2) = u2 () u 2 (2) If one of the two agents is fully insured no variation in her date consumption (MRS=) the other must be as well More generally, if the MRS are to differ from, given that they must be equal between the agents, the low consumption-high MU state must be the same for both agents and similarly for the high consumption-low MU state. Impossible when there s no aggregate risk, hence individuals are perfectly insured in the absence of aggregate risk. If there is aggregate risk, however, the above reasoning also implies that, at a Pareto optimum, it is shared proportionately among agents with same risk tolerance. 2 / 28

Notes on Pareto optimal allocations λ = u 0 u 2 0 = u () u 2 () = u (2) u 2 (2) u () u (2) = u2 () u 2 (2) If one of the two agents is fully insured no variation in her date consumption (MRS=) the other must be as well More generally, if the MRS are to differ from, given that they must be equal between the agents, the low consumption-high MU state must be the same for both agents and similarly for the high consumption-low MU state. Impossible when there s no aggregate risk, hence individuals are perfectly insured in the absence of aggregate risk. If there is aggregate risk, however, the above reasoning also implies that, at a Pareto optimum, it is shared proportionately among agents with same risk tolerance. If agents are differentially risk averse, in a Pareto optimal allocation the less risk averse will typically provide some insurance services to the more risk averse. 2 / 28

Notes on Pareto optimal allocations λ = u 0 u 2 0 = u () u 2 () = u (2) u 2 (2) u () u (2) = u2 () u 2 (2) If one of the two agents is fully insured no variation in her date consumption (MRS=) the other must be as well More generally, if the MRS are to differ from, given that they must be equal between the agents, the low consumption-high MU state must be the same for both agents and similarly for the high consumption-low MU state. Impossible when there s no aggregate risk, hence individuals are perfectly insured in the absence of aggregate risk. If there is aggregate risk, however, the above reasoning also implies that, at a Pareto optimum, it is shared proportionately among agents with same risk tolerance. If agents are differentially risk averse, in a Pareto optimal allocation the less risk averse will typically provide some insurance services to the more risk averse. More generally, optimal risk sharing dictates that the agent most tolerant of risk bears a disproportionate share of it. 2 / 28

CRRA preferences Let u i 0 and ui (c i (s)) be CRRA, and assume homogeneous time discounting factors: u(c) = c ρ ρ, ρ > 0, ρ u(c) = log c, ρ =. 22 / 28

AD prices with homogeneous CRRA preferences Recall FOCs: q(s)(c 0 i 0) ρ = π(s)β(c i (s)) ρ, s =,..., S, i =,..., I [ ] π(s)β /ρ c i (s) = q 0(s) c i 0, s =,..., S, i =,..., I [ ] π(s)β /ρ c i (s) = q i 0 }{{} (s) c i 0, s =,..., S, i =,..., I i }{{} =ȳ (s) =ȳ 0 ] [ȳ q(s) 0 (s) ρ = π(s)β, s =,..., S, ȳ 0 where ȳ 0 and ȳ (s) are total, economy-wide, endowments at date 0, and date, state s, respectively. 23 / 28

The existence of the representative consumer. CRRA preferences ] [ȳ q(s) 0 (s) ρ = π(s)β, s =,..., S ȳ 0 Notice that the economy with the representative consumer who owns the economy-wide endowments at each date-state will result into the same equilibrium vector of prices and aggregate consumption as a decentralized economy populated by consumers with identical time discount factors and identical CRRA preferences. 24 / 28

Equilibrium consumption levels: CRRA preferences Furthermore, π(s)β(c i (s)) ρ (c i 0 ) ρ = q 0 (s) = π(s)β(cj (s)) ρ (c j 0 ) ρ ci (s) c i 0 = ȳ(s) ȳ 0 ci (s) ȳ (s) = ci 0 ȳ 0 = cj (s) c j 0 c j and (s) ȳ (s) = cj 0 ȳ 0 π(s)β(c i (s)) ρ π(s )β(c i (s )) ρ = q0 (s) q 0 (s ) = π(s)β(cj (s)) ρ π(s )β(c j (s )) ρ ci (s) c i (s ) = q0 (s) q 0 (s ) = ȳ(s) ȳ (s ) = cj (s) c j (s ) ci (s) ȳ (s) = ci (s ) ȳ (s ) and c j (s) ȳ (s) = cj (s ) ȳ (s ) 25 / 28

Summary Any agent i s consumption is a constant share κ i of date total endowment regardless of the state. Any agent i s date 0 consumption share in total output is the same as her date share. Agent i s share in aggregate consumption/wealth is the agent s share of the aggregate wealth on date 0, evaluated at equilibrium Arrow-Debreu prices. 26 / 28

Individual consumption share: CRRA preferences y i 0 + S q(s)y 0 (s) i = c i 0 + s= = κ i ȳ 0 + S q(s)c 0 i (s) s= = κ i [ȳ 0 + S q(s)κ 0 i ȳ (s) s= ] S q(s)ȳ 0 (s) κ i = yi 0 + S s= q0 (s)yi (s) ȳ 0 + S s= q0 (s)ȳ (s) You can further simplify the above expression by plugging in the AD prices. s= 27 / 28

Suggested readings for this lecture Danthine, J. P., Donaldson, J. (2005), Intermediate Financial Theory, Elsevier Academic Press. Chapter 8. 28 / 28