Department of Economics Queen s University. ECON239: Development Economics Professor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis

Similar documents
Problems in Rural Credit Markets

Write your identification number on each paper and cover sheet (the number stated in the upper right hand corner on your exam cover).

Credit Market Problems in Developing Countries

Problem Set # Public Economics

The New Growth Theories - Week 6

SOLUTIONS TO MIDTERM EXAMINATION

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

Notes on classical growth theory (optional read)

Practice Questions Chapters 9 to 11

About 80% of the countries have GDP per capita below the average income per head

SAMPLE EXAM QUESTIONS FOR FALL 2018 ECON3310 MIDTERM 2

QUESTIONNAIRE A I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (2 points each)

Econ 277A: Economic Development I. Final Exam (06 May 2012)

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Population Economics Field Exam September 2010

Department of Economics Queen s University. ECON835: Development Economics Instructor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis

QUESTIONNAIRE A I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (4 points each)

Chapter 4. Economic Growth

QUESTIONNAIRE A I. MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS (3 points each)

Simple e ciency-wage model

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

Statistical Evidence and Inference

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Limited Attention and Income Distribution

Econ 102: Lecture Notes #7. Human Capital. John Knowles University of Pennsylvania. October 6th, 2004

SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 5

ECON Micro Foundations

Review Seminar. Section A

Chapter 6: Long-Run Economic Growth

ECON 256: Poverty, Growth & Inequality. Jack Rossbach

Introduction to economic growth (2)

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

The Solow Growth Model

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

Part 1: Short answer, 60 points possible Part 2: Analytical problems, 40 points possible

3. Which of the following assertions CLEARLY DOES NOT correspond to what you learned in this course?

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

ECO 4933 Topics in Theory

Chapters 1 & 2 - MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA

The Role of Physical Capital

Chapter 7. Economic Growth I: Capital Accumulation and Population Growth (The Very Long Run) CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I. slide 0

1 Chapter 1: Economic growth

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 7 of the text.

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D

INTRODUCTION TO MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA. The Variables of Interest to Macroeconomists

Costs. Lecture 5. August Reading: Perlo Chapter 7 1 / 63

Optimal Monetary Policy

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

). In Ch. 9, when we add technological progress, k is capital per effective worker (k = K

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth

CHAPTER SEVEN - Eight. Economic Growth

The Economics of State Capacity. Weak States and Strong States. Ely Lectures. Johns Hopkins University. April 14th-18th 2008.

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

Queen s University Department of Economics ECON 222 Macroeconomic Theory I Fall Term Section 001 Midterm Examination 31 October 2012

Population Economics Field Exam Spring This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator.

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems I (Solutions)

5. If capital lasts an average of 25 years, the depreciation rate is percent per year. A) 25 B) 5 C) 4 D) 2.5

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

E-322 Muhammad Rahman CHAPTER-6

ECON 3560/5040 Week 3

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

EC 205 Macroeconomics I

Growth Growth Accounting The Solow Model Golden Rule. Growth. Joydeep Bhattacharya. Iowa State. February 16, Growth

E cient Minimum Wages

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010

Finance Macroeconomic Analysis Midterm #1 Summer 2013

Chapters 1 & 2 - MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA

Optimal Progressivity

Monetary Policy: Rules versus discretion..

Econ 302 Assignment 2 Answer Key

The Facts of Economic Growth and the Introdution to the Solow Model

Components of Economic Growth

Class Notes. Intermediate Macroeconomics. Li Gan. Lecture 7: Economic Growth. It is amazing how much we have achieved.

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

An endogenous growth model with human capital and learning

5.1 Introduction. The Solow Growth Model. Additions / differences with the model: Chapter 5. In this chapter, we learn:

004: Macroeconomic Theory

Remember the dynamic equation for capital stock _K = F (K; T L) C K C = _ K + K = I

Development Economics Lecture Notes 2

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics

Credit Market Problems in Developing Countries

Macroeconomic Measurements, Part II: GDP and Real GDP CHAPTER

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, UNIVERSITY OF VICTORIA

SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS

Optimal Taxation : (c) Optimal Income Taxation

3. TFU: A zero rate of increase in the Consumer Price Index is an appropriate target for monetary policy.

QUEEN S UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ARTS AND SCIENCE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

LEC 2: Exogenous (Neoclassical) growth model

QUEEN S UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ARTS AND SCIENCE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Economics 222 A&B Macroeconomic Theory I. Final Examination 20 April 2009

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

Practice final posted. Final for senior June 1 5pm. Final for all non seniors posted June 5 5pm due June 9 at noon

Econ Review Set 3 - Answers

Department of Economics Queen s University ECON 239: Development Economics Assignment # 3 Due Date: Wednesday, November 26, :30 am (in class)

Multivariate Statistics Lecture Notes. Stephen Ansolabehere

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Midterm 1. The market value of all final goods and services produced in a particular location over some period of time.

Transcription:

Department of Economics Queen s University ECON239: Development Economics Professor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis Midterm Exam Answer Key Monday, October 25, 2010 Section A (50 percent): Discuss the validity of THREE (3) of the following statements. In your answer de ne or explain as precisely as possible any terms or concepts which are underlined, with particular reference to the context in which they are being used. You should aim to make each answer no longer than a single side (two sides if double-spaced), and you should include diagrams and/or real-world examples where appropriate. All questions have equal value. A1. Suppose there are two goods produced in the world: DVDs, which are traded internationally, and hair cuts, which are not. Assume that transport costs are negligible. The following table shows information on the consumption and prices of DVDs and hair cuts in the USA and China: DVDs Hair Cuts Price of DVDs Price of Hair Cuts Country Consumed Consumed in Local Currency in Local Currency USA 9 4 2 4 China 3 4 10 10 The value of the purchasing power parity exchange rate depends on whether a US or a world wide basket of goods is used to compute it. The PPP rate is usually de ned as the number of units of a country s currency required to purchase the same quantity of goods and services in the local (developing country) market as $1 would buy in the US (2 marks). Formally, we can calculate this as (1 mark) PPP exchange rate for China = Cost of representative basket of goods and services in US Cost of same basket of goods and services in China Using the US basket of goods: To buy the US basket (9 DVDs and 4 haircuts) in the US would cost (9 2) + (4 4) = 34 US$ To buy the US basket (9 DVDs and 4 haircuts) in China would cost (9 10) + (4 10) = 130 RMB 1

So the PPP exchange rate (using the US basket) is (3 marks) PPP US = 130 34 = 3:82 Using the world basket of goods (12 DVDs and 8 haircuts): To buy the world basket in the US would cost In China this basket would cost would cost (12 2) + (8 4) = 56 US$ (12 10) + (8 10) = 200 RMB So the PPP exchange rate (using the World basket) is (3 marks) PPP W orld = 200 56 = 3:57 (Note that for this calculation it does not matter whether we use the whole world basket or half the world basket (6 DVDs and 4 haircuts), as long as we use something proportional to the world basket.) Obviously, the two approaches yield di erent results and would (1 mark) also yield di erent degrees of income disparity (using only the Chinese basket would give a third ratio). There is no correct method for computing PPP rates in this example, so the best we can do is consider the range of values that we get. Most PPP estimates use a basket that corresponds to US consumption patterns (but discard luxury items ). A2. The head count ratio is a better target measure of poverty than the poverty gap index because it is likely to lead to less of a bias in poverty reduction policies towards individuals who are already close to the poverty line. The headcount ratio is simply the fraction of a given population that is below some well-de ned poverty line (2 marks). Given that the resources of policy makers are limited, the fact that it is cheaper to shift those just below the poverty line up to it, than it is to shift up those well below it, will imply a bigger bang for the buck in targeting the not so poor (2 marks). This potential bias illustrates the importance of thinking carefully about formulating target measures for policy. An alternative target measure that avoids this bias is the poverty gap index which measures the depth of poverty: the amount of income needed to raise those below the poverty line up to it (3 marks). This is often expressed as a percentage of total economywide income the poverty gap ratio. If this were the target measure then policies that increase the incomes of the very poor would have an equal impact on the measure as those that increase the incomes of the not-so poor (2 marks). This is not to say that measures like the poverty gap ratio are immune from their own problems. For example, a country with high average income may have a low PGR (implying high inequality), even though the depth of poverty is the same as a relatively poor country (1 mark). 2

A3. The Harrod-Domar model provides a useful approximation of the likely impacts of foreign aid on an economy s growth rate. (4 marks) The Harrod Domar model is a formal theory that o ers a simple formula stating at what rate an economy must save, s, in order to attain a per capita income growth rate of g, given a population growth rate, n, a rate of physical depreciation,, and a capital income ratio, : s = (n + g + ): Foreign aid can then be thought of as an attempt to ll the gap between this target savings rate and the actual savings rate of the economy. If the actual level of domestic saving is S D and aggregate income is Y; the aid needed to achieve the target above is assumed to be given by A = sy S D = (n + g + )Y S D In principle, then the Harrod-Domar model does provide a guide of the impact of foreign aid on investment and, in turn, on an economy s growth rate. In practice (as discussed by Easterly), however, this model has done a very poor job of predicting the e ects of foreign aid on growth. Firstly, the impact of aid on investment in many countries has been small much of the aid has been consumed in one way or another, rather than invested in growth promoting activities. The assumption that aid will be simply added to domestic saving in order to raise investment, rather than substituted, ignores important incentives and institutional factors that have been important (2 marks). Secondly, the statistical relationship between investment and growth over shorter periods has also been rather weak (1 mark). In addition, to these practical problems, several key assumptions of the model are inconsistent with observed facts. In particular, the model implicitly assumes that there are constant returns the capital, and that there is surplus labour available (2 marks). As Easterly argues, neither assumption holds water, at least in the long run. A vivid example of this is the case of Zambia (1 mark). A4. Potential settler mortality rates from the period of colonization by European powers are useful in assessing the impact of cross country institutional di erences on economic performance, because they are an exogenous source of variation in political and legal institutions. Cross country institutional di erences refers to di erences in the humanly devised constraints that structure incentives in economic transactions. These can include aspects of the political system (e.g. degree of democracy, constraints on executive power, etc.), the extent and e ectiveness of the legal system in supporting and enforcing contracts, elements of the socio-economic infrastructure (e.g. land rights, social insurance systems, etc.). There are a number of indices (based on scores and rankings applied by various organization) available that purport to measure institutional quality across countries, and these are typically highly correlated with per capita income (2 marks). However, it is generally di cult to assess the direction of causation between these two measures is it that better institutions lead to higher income per capita, or do richer 3

countries have better institutions simply because they can a ord them? Ideally, in order to determine the causal role of institutions, we need an exogenous source of variation some measurable factor that is an important determinant of the variation in institutional quality, but which is clearly not itself determined by the level of per capita income of a country. (2 marks) The article by Acemoglu, et al. (2001) represents an attempt to measure the impact of di erences in institutional quality by using potential settler mortality rates as an exogenous source of variation in legal and political institutions. Their argument is that where settler mortality rates were low, European powers moved in and colonized those countries and brought their institutions with them, whereas where mortality rates were high they tended to extract (human and natural) resources at arms length rather than settle there. In these extractive situations, they set up institutions (e.g. political power structures) that were designed to ease extraction of resources, rather than to protect the economic and political rights of citizens. (4 marks) They argue that these high and low quality institutions persist today in many countries. Acemoglu et al. argue that as much as 75% of the variation in current income per capita of these ex colonies can be accounted for by the di erences in institutional quality that resulted from di erences in settler mortality rates (1 mark). Note that the mortality rates faced by settlers were not the same as those faced by indigenous peoples who had developed some immunity to the local diseases over time. Therefore, it is not the case that countries with high rates of disease are just poorer. (1 mark) A5. The evidence that sharecropping results in low productivity suggests that people in the rural sector of many developing countries are not rational. The tenancy arrangement of sharecropping has been common in various countries of the world for centuries, although it is less prevalent now than in the past. It refers to the practice where tenants pay landowners a speci ed share of their output instead of, or in addition to a xed rental payment (2 marks). In economics, rationality consists of two assumptions: (1) that individuals act in their own self interest and (2) that they can gure out the consequences of their own and other people s actions (2 marks). The evidence suggests that sharecropping tenancy relationships lead to lower productivity than xed rental agreements, because they o er low incentives for e ort and investment. Given that sharecropping is so persistent, one might think that this implies that people in the rural sector are not acting rationally. However, most economists think it is more likely that the institution of share-cropping serves an important purpose in terms of sharing risk. Proponents of the Chicago school of thought argue that landlords and tenants can agree on the e cient level of e ort, but then adopt a sharecropping arrangement to minimize the transactions cost associated with risk bearing. However, this view is inconsistent with the low productivity if sharecropping and ignores the di culty of monitoring efort. According to the new institutional school, sharecropping is best viewed as the result of a trade o between risk and incentives. To see this, suppose that the landlord is risk neutral, but Tenant is risk averse. In this case, according to the Chicago school view we would expect to see a wage contract. However, suppose that the Landlord cannot 4

directly monitor the e ort of the Tenant, and he cannot infer e ort due to the risk in production described above (e ort here is a hidden action ). The incentive constrained or second best e cient value of the output share is the one where the marginal gains (due to reduced e ciency losses) and marginal cost (due to greater risk) of increasing it any further are just equalized. Note that this must generally give a share of output to the tenant which is less than one, so that this outcome is not as productive as a xed rental contract. However, its the best outcome possible given the informational constraint (6 marks). Section B (50 percent): Answer ONE (1) of the following Long Questions. B1. Consider the following version of the Solow growth model. Suppose the relationship between output per worker, y, and capital per worker, k, at any point in time is represented by y = f(k); where the function f() is increase in k and concave. Suppose also that there is no technological change, population growth is n, the savings rate is s and the rate of depreciation of capital is. (a) Explain why the model economy is in a steady state when the capital stock per worker satis es sf(k) = (n + )k: Illustrate this situation on a diagram. Investment per worker (n+δ)k sf(k) k* k Figure 1: The Solow Model: Steady State 5

The right hand side of this equation is the economy s break even level of investment where new investment is high enough to just o set the negative e ects of depreciation and population growth on the capital stock per worker. The equation states that the capital stock per work is such that the actual investment per worker is just equal to this break even level, so that the capital stock per worker does not change over time. Once the economy has reached this situation, there is no tendency for the capital stock per worker to change over time, so that the economy is in steady state. (b) Suppose there are two such economies (A and B). The two economies have identical values of n and and face the same production relationship, f(). However, country A has a higher savings rate than B: s A > s B. Explain using a diagram what this implies for the relative steady state levels of capital and output per worker in each country. As illustrated in Figure, the steady-state capital stock per worker in economy A exceeds that in country B: ka > k B. Investment per worker (n+δ)k s A f(k) s B f(k) k* B k A * k (c) (Suppose that, in addition to having a higher savings rate, economy A starts out with a higher capital stock per worker than country B. Which economy grows fastest? Explain with the aid of a diagram. In general, this is ambiguous. Suppose country B starts out at k 0. Then the increase in its capital stock per worker is given by the vertical distance between its savings function and the break even investment line. If country A starts out at k 1 (a little above k 0 ) then clearly this increment to its capital stock is much larger and it will grow fastest. However, if country A starts out at k 2 (closer to its own steady state), then this increment is small and country B will grow fastest. (d) Suppose that, in addition to having a higher savings rate, economy A also has a higher population growth rate than economy B: n A > n B. Is it possible that both 6

Investment per worker (n+δ)k s A f(k) s B f(k) k 0 k 1 k* B k 2 k A * k economies have the same steady state output per worker? Explain. Yes, it is possible. Figure illustrates a situation where the positive a ect of a higher savings rate on Country A is exactly o set by the negative a ect of higher population growth. Investment per worker (n A +δ)k (n B +δ)k s A f(k) s B f(k) k* k (e) If = 0:1, s A = 0:3, s B = 0:2, n A = 0:05 and n B = 0:02, which economy has the highest steady state output per worker? Explain using a diagram of the production function. The steady state output capital ratio is given by For country A this is given by Y K = f(k) = n + k s 0:05 + 0:1 = 0:5 0:3 7

and for country B it is given by 0:02 + 0:1 = 0:6 0:2 As illustrated in Figure, due to diminishing returns, a lower output capital ratio is associated with higher output per worker. Therefore country A has the highest steady state output per worker. Output per Capita Production Function y=f(k) Falling outputcapital ratios Figure 2: Diminishing Returns to Capital per Worker Capital per capita B2. A plot of land is owned by a Landlord but worked by a Tenant. If the Tenant provides e ort L she incurs a cost C(L), which increases at an increasing rate with L. The value of output from the plot is given by the production function y = g(l) + x; where g(l) increases at a decreasing rate with L, and x represents random variations in output due to climatic conditions. The Landlord can observe the output produced by the Tenant, but cannot monitor or infer the amount of e ort she exerts. (a) Using the above information, write down the incomes of the two parties under (1) a wage contract, (2) a rental contract and (3) a sharecropping contract. The Tenant s income is : I t = F + (1 )[g(l) + x] C(L): The Landlord s income is : I l = F + [g(l) + x]: The contract speci es alternative values of F and, before the two parties know what the value of x will be. We can represent three alternative types of contract in this framework: 8

(1) A wage contract : F < 0 and = 1 the Landlord pays a xed wage, F, to the Tenant in return for a speci ed level of e ort and receives all the output herself. The wage is determined in the labour market. (2) A rental contract : F > 0 and = 0 the Tenant rents the plot from the Landlord for a xed amount F and receives all the output himself. The rent is determined in the land rental market. (3) A sharecropping contract : F =? and 0 < < 1: the two parties divide up the output, with the Tenant getting a share 1 and the Landlord receiving. A xed payment, F, may also be made from one party to the other, the net value of which will depend upon market wages and rental rates. However, this contract is not a pure market contract: factors other than price matter. (b) In each of these contracts describe how the risk is allocated between to two parties. What about the incentives faced by the Tenant to exert e ort? (1) In the wage contract, the Landlord faces all the risk and the Tenant none, but the incentives faced by the Tenant are weak. (2) In the rental contract, the incentives faced by the Tenant are strong, but he now bears all the risk and the Landlord bears none. (3) In the share cropping contract, both parties bear some risk. The smaller the value of, the more risk the Tenant faces and the less is borne by the Landlord. The incentives faced by the Tenant are weaker than under a rental contract but stronger that under the wage contract, and decrease with. Assume that the Landlord is risk neutral, but the Tenant is risk averse. This riskaversion is represented as a cost which increases at an increasing rate with the Tenant s share of output. (c) With the aid of a diagram, explain how the theoretical constrained e cient output share received by the Tenant, 1, and the associated e ort level, L, are determined in a sharecropping contract. Given the parameters of the contract, and F, the Tenant will choose his e ort level so that his private marginal cost equals his private marginal bene t: MC(L) = (1 )MB(L): This is the Tenant s incentive constraint: it tells the Landlord how he will have to increase the output share 1 in order to encourage more e ort. In particular, 1 is an increasing function of the desired e ort level. However, the increase in 1 needed to attain more e ort, also increases the cost of risk faced by the Tenant. The increment in the cost of risk necessary to attain each additional unit of e ort is given by the marginal cost of risk (MCR) curve illustrated in Figure 3. 9

The incentive constrained or second best e cient value of is the one where the gains and losses of decreasing it any further are just equalized,. For any > the increase in productive e ciency resulting from an increase in the share exceeds the increase in the cost imposed due to additional risk. For any < the reduction in productive e ciency resulting from an decrease in the share is less than the decrease in the cost imposed due to additional risk. When =, the reduced production e ciency loss caused by increasing the share, AB, is just equal to the additional welfare cost due to risk, CD. A MC E B (1 α )MP MP L* Labour MCR C D 1 α 1 α Figure 3: Constrained-e cient Sharecropping Contract (d) Using the same diagram as in (c) illustrate the total losses (due to bad incentives and risk) under the sharecropping contract, relative to the full information case. The e ciency (i.e. welfare) losses are represented by the shaded areas in Figure 3. (e) As countries become more developed, sharecropping tends to become less prevalent as a form of tenancy. How can the theory outlined above help to account for this observation? Explain your answer using a diagram. As countries become more developed, we generally see credit markets and insurance markets improve. This implies that farmers are likely to have better access to ways of insuring themselves against risk and so the cost of risk will tend to decline. Also some innovations in agriculture 10

(more resistant crop varieties) may act to reduce risk directly. As illustrated in the lower panel of Figure 4, the implication is that the MCR curve shifts down. Now the original share received by the Tenant, 1 0, is no longer constrained e cient a small reduction in will reduce the e ciency loss by more than the increase in the cost of risk. To nd the new constrained e cient share, just reduce (thereby shifting up the e ective marginal bene t accruing the tenant) until the marginal e ciency loss is just equal to the marginal cost of risk. That is where A 0 B 0 = C 0 D 0. This yields the new constrained-e cient share accruing to the tenant, 1 1, which is now higher. Eventually, as risk is reduced enough we will tend to see xed rental contracts emerge as a form of tenancy ( = 1), rather than sharecropping. A MC A' AB=CD B B' MP A'B'=C'D' (1 α 1 )MP (1 α 0 )MP Labour MCR C C' D D' 1 α 0 1 α 1 1 α Figure 4: E ect of Reduction in Risk due to Crop Insurance Note that another factor which may also improve with development is that agriculture becomes more productive. This will cause the MP curve to shift up and to the right, which will also cause the share received by the tenant to rise. 11