Derivative Securities

Similar documents
******************************* The multi-period binomial model generalizes the single-period binomial model we considered in Section 2.

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

************************

Derivative Securities Section 9 Fall 2004 Notes by Robert V. Kohn, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences.

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

1 The continuous time limit

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Homework Assignments

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

Naked & Covered Positions

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Hedging. MATH 472 Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

The Black-Scholes Equation

The Greek Letters Based on Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright John C. Hull 2012

Lecture 9: Practicalities in Using Black-Scholes. Sunday, September 23, 12

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

King s College London

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

P&L Attribution and Risk Management

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Barrier options. In options only come into being if S t reaches B for some 0 t T, at which point they become an ordinary option.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Financial Risk Management

P-7. Table of Contents. Module 1: Introductory Derivatives

OPTIONS & GREEKS. Study notes. An option results in the right (but not the obligation) to buy or sell an asset, at a predetermined

Simulation Wrap-up, Statistics COS 323

The Black-Scholes Model

S u =$55. S u =S (1+u) S=$50. S d =$48.5. S d =S (1+d) C u = $5 = Max{55-50,0} $1.06. C u = Max{Su-X,0} (1+r) (1+r) $1.06. C d = $0 = Max{48.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Spring 2018 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3

Evaluating the Black-Scholes option pricing model using hedging simulations

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

King s College London

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

1 Parameterization of Binomial Models and Derivation of the Black-Scholes PDE.

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Rho and Delta. Paul Hollingsworth January 29, Introduction 1. 2 Zero coupon bond 1. 3 FX forward 2. 5 Rho (ρ) 4. 7 Time bucketing 6

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 7th Edition, Copyright John C. Hull

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II. Derivatives and Risk Management By Rajiv Srivastava. Copyright Oxford University Press

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

B. Combinations. 1. Synthetic Call (Put-Call Parity). 2. Writing a Covered Call. 3. Straddle, Strangle. 4. Spreads (Bull, Bear, Butterfly).

Chapter 17. Options and Corporate Finance. Key Concepts and Skills

Solutions of Exercises on Black Scholes model and pricing financial derivatives MQF: ACTU. 468 S you can also use d 2 = d 1 σ T

The Black-Scholes Model

1. In this exercise, we can easily employ the equations (13.66) (13.70), (13.79) (13.80) and

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

MATH 476/567 ACTUARIAL RISK THEORY FALL 2016 PROFESSOR WANG. Homework 3 Solution

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

Financial Markets & Risk

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

CHAPTER 9. Solutions. Exercise The payoff diagrams will look as in the figure below.

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk

Options Markets: Introduction

Pricing Options with Binomial Trees

Chapter 14 Exotic Options: I

Math 239 Homework 1 solutions

In this lecture we will solve the final-value problem derived in the previous lecture 4, V (1) + rs = rv (t < T )

Financial Derivatives Section 5

The Black-Scholes Model

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

1. 2 marks each True/False: briefly explain (no formal proofs/derivations are required for full mark).

Two Types of Options

Appendix A Financial Calculations

non linear Payoffs Markus K. Brunnermeier

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Derivatives Options on Bonds and Interest Rates. Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

Homework Set 6 Solutions

Lecture 4: Barrier Options

Transcription:

Derivative Securities he Black-Scholes formula and its applications. his Section deduces the Black- Scholes formula for a European call or put, as a consequence of risk-neutral valuation in the continuous time limit. hen we discuss the Delta, Gamma, Vega, and Rho of a portfolio, and their significance for hedging. Our treatment is closest to Jarrow and urnbull, however Hull s treatment of this material is also excellent. Hedging is a very important topic, and these notes don t do justice to it; see e.g. chapter 4 of Hull s 5th edition for further, more practical discussion. We assume throughout these notes that the underlying asset pays no dividend and has no carrying cost. (We ll remove these assumptions later in the semester. Briefly: if the underlying asset pays a continuous dividend, e.g. if it is the value of a broad stock index, or a foreign exchange rate, the continuous-time risk neutral process is like what we found in the no-dividend case but with r replaced by r q where q is the dividend rate.) ******************* he Black-Scholes formula for a European call or put. he upshot of Section 4 is this: the value at time t of a European option with payoff f(s ) is V (f) = e r( t) E RN f(s ). Here E RN f(s ) is the expected value of the price at maturity with respect to a special probability distribution the risk-neutral one. his distribution is determined by the property that s = s t exp (r 2 σ2 )( t) + σ tz where s t is the spot price at time t and Z is Gaussian with mean 0 and variance. Equivalently: logs /s t is Gaussian with mean (r 2 σ2 )( t) and variance σ 2 ( t). his formula can be evaluated for any payoff f by numerical integration. But for special payoffs including the put and the call we can get explicit expressions in terms of the cumulative distribution function N(x) = x e u2 /2 du. (N(x) is the probability that a Gaussian random variable with mean 0 and variance has value x.) he explicit formulas have advantages over numerical integration: besides being easy to evaluate, they permit us to see quite directly how the value and the hedge portfolio depend on strike price, spot price, risk-free rate, and volatility. It s sufficient, of course, to consider t = 0. Let cs 0, ; K = value at time 0 of a European call with strike K and maturity, if the spot price is s 0 ; ps 0, ; K = value at time 0 of a European put with strike K and maturity, if the spot price is s 0.

he explicit formulas are: cs 0, ; K = s 0 N(d ) Ke r N(d 2 ) ps 0, ; K = Ke r N( d 2 ) s 0 N( d ) in which d = d 2 = σ σ log(s 0 /K) + (r + 2 σ2 ) log(s 0 /K) + (r 2 σ2 ) = d σ. o derive these formulas we use the following result. (he calculation at the end of Section 4 was a special case.) Lemma: Suppose X is Gaussian with mean µ and variance σ 2. hen for any real numbers a and k, E e ax restricted to X k = e aµ+ 2 a2 σ 2 N(d) with d = ( k + µ + aσ 2 )/σ. Proof: he left hand side is defined by E e ax restricted to X k = (x µ) σ e ax 2 exp k 2σ 2 dx. Complete the square: hus ax E e ax X k = e aµ+ 2 a2 σ 2 (x µ)2 2σ 2 = aµ + 2 a2 σ 2 x (µ + aσ2 ) 2 2σ 2. σ k x (µ + aσ 2 ) 2 exp 2σ 2 dx. If we set u = x (µ + aσ 2 )/σ and κ = k (µ + aσ 2 )/σ this becomes e aµ+ 2 a2 σ 2 e u2 /2 du = e aµ+ 2 a2 σ 2 N(κ) where d = κ = ( k + µ + aσ 2 )/σ. κ = e aµ+ 2 a2 σ 2 N(d) We apply this to the European call. Our task is to evaluate e r (s 0 e x (x r σ K) + σ 2 exp /2 ) 2 2σ 2 dx. 2

he integrand is nonzero when s 0 e x > K, i.e. when x > log(k/s 0 ). Applying the Lemma with a = and k = log(k/s 0 ) we get e r s 0 e x (x r σ k σ 2 exp /2 ) 2 2σ 2 dx = s 0 N(d ); applying the Lemma again with a = 0 we get e r K (x r σ k σ 2 exp /2 ) 2 2σ 2 dx = Ke r N(d 2 ); combining these results gives the formula for cs 0, ; K. he formula for the value of a European put can be obtained similarly. Or easier we can derive it from the formula for a call, using put-call parity: ps 0, ; K = cs 0, ; K + Ke r s 0 = Ke r N(d 2 ) s 0 N(d ) = Ke r N( d 2 ) s 0 N( d ). For options with maturity and strike price K, the value at any time t is naturally cs t, t; K for a call, ps t, t; K for a put. ********************* Hedging. We know how to hedge in the discrete-time, multiperiod binomial tree setting: the payoff is replicated by a portfolio consisting of = (0, s 0 ) units of stock and a (long or short) bond, chosen to have the same value as the derivative claim. At time δt the stock price changes to s δt and the value of the hedge portfolio changes by (s δt s 0 ). he new value of the hedge portfolio is also the new value of the option, so (0, s 0 ) = change in value of option from time 0 to δt change in value of stock from time 0 to δt. he replication strategy requires a self-financing trade at every time step, adjusting the amount of stock in the portfolio to match the new value of. In the real world prices are not confined to a binomial tree, and there are no well-defined time steps. We cannot trade continuously. So while we can pass to the continuous time limit for the value of the option, we must still trade at discrete times in our attempts to replicate it. Suppose, for simplicity, we trade at equally spaced times with interval δt. What to use for the initial hedge ratio? Not being clairvoyant we don t know the value of the stock at 3

time δt, so we can t use the formula given above. Instead we should use its continuous-time limit: (value of option) (0, s 0 ) = (value of stock). here s a subtle point here: if the stock price changes continuously in time, but we only rebalance at discretely chosen times jδt, then we cannot expect to replicate the option perfectly using self-financing trades. Put differently: if we maintain the principle that the value of the hedge portfolio is equal to that of the option at each time jδt, then our trades will no longer be self-financing. We will address this point soon, after developing the continuous-time Black-Scholes theory. We ll show then that (if transaction costs are ignored) the expected cost of replication tends to 0 as δt 0. (In practice transaction costs are not negligible; deciding when, really, to rebalance, taking into account transaction costs, is an important and interesting problem but one beyond the scope of this course.) For the European put and call we can easily get formulas for by differentiating our expressions for c and p: at time from maturity the hedge ratio should be for the call, and = = s 0 cs 0, ; K = N(d ) s 0 ps 0, ; K = N( d ) for the put. he hard way to see this is an application of chain rule: for example, in the case of the call, c = N(d ) + s 0 N (d ) d s 0 s Ke r N (d 2 ) d 2 s. But d 2 = d σ, so d /s = d 2 /s; also N (x) = exp x 2 /2. It follows with some calculation that s 0 N (d ) d s Ke r N (d 2 ) d 2 s = 0, so finally c/s 0 = N(d ) as asserted. here is however an easier way: differentiate the original formula expressing the value as a discounted risk-neutral expectation. Passing the derivative under the integral, for a call with strike K: = e r (s 0 e x (x r σ K) + s 0 σ 2 exp /2 ) 2 2σ 2 dx = e r (s 0 e x K) + (x r σ s 0 σ 2 exp /2 ) 2 2σ 2 dx = e r e x (x r σ log(k/s 0 ) σ 2 exp /2 ) 2 2σ 2 dx = N(d ). 4

******************* Since we have explicit formulas for the value of a put or call, we can differentiate them to learn the dependence on the underlying parameters. Some of these derivatives have names: Definition Call Put Delta = s 0 N(d ) > 0 N( d ) < 0 Gamma = 2 s 2 0 heta = t s 0 σ exp( d2 /2) > 0 s 0 σ exp( d2 /2) > 0 s 0σ 2 exp( d2 /2) rke r N(d 2 ) < 0 s 0σ 2 exp( d2 /2) + rke r N( d 2 ) > < 0 Vega = σ s 0 exp( d 2 /2) > 0 s 0 exp( d 2 /2) > 0 Rho = r Ke r N(d 2 ) > 0 Ke r N( d 2 ) < 0. hese formulas apply at time t = 0; the formulas applicable at any time t are similar, with replaced by t. hese are obviously useful for understanding how the value of the option changes with time, volatility, etc. But more: they are useful for designing improved hedges. For example, suppose a bank sells two types of options on the same underlying asset, with different strike prices and maturities. As usual the bank wants to limit its exposure to changes in the stock price; but suppose in addition it wants to limit its exposure to changes (or errors in specification of) volatility. Let i =, 2 refer to the two types of options, and let n, n 2 be the quantities held of each. (hese are negative if the bank sold the options.) he bank naturally also invests in the underlying stock and in risk-free bonds; let n s and n b be the quantities held of each. hen the value of the bank s initial portfolio is V total = n V + n 2 V 2 + n s s 0 + n b. We already know how the stock and bond holdings should be chosen if the bank plans to replicate (dynamically) the options: they should satisfy and V total = 0 n + n 2 2 + n s = 0. Notice that the latter relation says V total /s 0 = 0: the value of the bank s holdings are insensitive (to first order) to changes in the stock price. If we were dealing in just one option there would be no further freedom: we would have two homogeneous equations in three variables n, n s, n b, restricting their values to a line so that n determines n s and n b. hat s the situation we re familiar with. But if we re dealing in two (independent) options then we have the freedom to impose one additional linear equation. For example we can ask that the portfolio be insensitive (to first order) to changes in σ by imposing the additional condition n Vega + n 2 Vega 2 = 0. 5

hus: by selling the two types of assets in the proper proportions the bank can reduce its exposure to change or misspecification of volatility. If the bank sells three types of options then we have room for yet another condition e.g. we could impose first-order insensitivity to changes in the risk-free rate r. And so on. It is not actually necessary that the bank use the underlying stock as one of its assets. Each option is equivalent to a portfolio consisting of stock and risk-free bond; so a portfolio consisting entirely of options and a bond position will function as a hedge portfolio so long as its total is equal to 0. Replication requires dynamic rebalancing. he bank must change its holdings at each time increment to set the new to 0. In the familiar, one-option setting this was done by adjusting the stock and bond holdings, keeping the option holding fixed. In the present, two-option setting, maintaining the additional condition Vega total = 0 will require the ratio between n and n 2 to be dynamically updated as well, i.e. the bank will have to sell or buy additional options as time proceeds. 6