Appendix C Border Adjustments under the National Retail Sales Tax or Corporate Activity Tax

Similar documents
ILLUSTRATIVE MOCK EXAMPLES

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

T h e l e g a l i t y o f t h e p r o p o s e d U. S. b o r d e r a d j u s t m e n t t a x " u n d e r W T O l a w

TECHNICAL COOPERATION HANDBOOK ON NOTIFICATION REQUIREMENTS AGREEMENT ON SUBSIDIES AND COUNTERVAILING MEASURES. Revised August 2013

Article 2. National Treatment and Quantitative Restrictions

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

Anti-dumping and Subsidy Issues in Agricultural Trade. Presentation by G. Tereposky Thomas & Partners CATPRN Workshop 6 March 2005

WTO ANALYTICAL INDEX Anti-Dumping Agreement Article 5 (Jurisprudence)

Order Code RS20746 Updated April 24, 2007 Export Tax Benefits and the WTO: The Extraterritorial Income Exclusion and Foreign Sales Corporations Summar

NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

The agreement of principal relevance in the WTO context is the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing measures (the "SCM Agreement").

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

Elements of a Trade and Climate Code

APPLICATION AND INTERPRETATION OF ARTICLE 24 (NON-DISCRIMINATION) Public discussion draft. 3 May 2007

'Brazil Cotton' Makes Trade Retaliation Operational

PROTOCOL ON THE ACCESSION OF THE PEOPLE'S REPUBLIC OF ClDNA. Preamble

Indonesia Measures Concerning the Importation of Chicken Meat and Chicken Products WT/DS484

CHAPTER TWO NATIONAL TREATMENT AND MARKET ACCESS FOR GOODS

Why the Ryan-Brady Tax Proposal Will Be Found to Be Inconsistent with WTO Law

International Competitiveness: An Economic Analysis of VAT Border Tax Adjustments

Recent cases on the application of Taiwan sourcing rules

The General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS): objectives, coverage and disciplines

United States Subsidies on Upland Cotton. Recourse to Article 21.5 of the DSU by Brazil. Third Participant s Submission of Australia

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

Article 9. Export Subsidy Commitments. 1. The following export subsidies are subject to reduction commitments under this Agreement:

CRS Report for Congress

Agreement on Trade in Services (TISA) Tuesday, 2 December 2014 Geneva. Round: 1-5 December 2014

UNITED STATES FINAL DUMPING DETERMINATION ON SOFTWOOD LUMBER FROM CANADA. Recourse to Article 21.5 of the DSU by Canada (AB )

CANADA. Chapter 8. Quantitative Restrictions 1) EXPORT RESTRICTIONS ON LOGS

THIRD PARTY SUBMISSION OF NEW ZEALAND

National Interest Analysis

WT/DS472/R WT/DS497/R

NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 15 May 1996 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques

WTO ANALYTICAL INDEX SCM Agreement Article 3 (Jurisprudence)

Summary Report Responses to the public consultation on the special scheme for small enterprises under the VAT Directive

Lao People s Democratic Republic Peace Independence Democracy Unity Prosperity

Paper by. Matthew R. Nicely, Partner, Thompson Hine LLP

AMF s answer in relation to the European Commission s call for evidence regarding private placement regimes in the EU

Leasing taxation Estonia

( ) Page: 1/10 FREE TRADE AGREEMENT BETWEEN MEXICO AND PANAMA (GOODS AND SERVICES) QUESTIONS AND REPLIES

In the World Trade Organization CANADA MEASURES RELATING TO THE FEED-IN TARIFF PROGRAM (DS426)

Value added tax in Lao PDR: Agenda for the future

Currency Manipulation: The IMF and WTO

ANNEX D REQUEST FOR THE ESTABLISHMENT OF A PANEL

PART I CHAPTER 1 MOST-FAVOURED-NATION TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

UNITED STATES FINAL DUMPING DETERMINATION ON SOFTWOOD LUMBER FROM CANADA. Recourse to Article 21.5 of the DSU by Canada (WT/DS264)

Chapter 2 The General Agreement on Trade in Services

WTO ANALYTICAL INDEX SCM Agreement Article 1 (Jurisprudence)

International Tax Sweden Highlights 2018

EU Commission Publishes New Regulations and Guidelines on the Application of EU Competition Law to Certain Categories of Commercial Contracts

United States Anti-Dumping and Countervailing Measures on Large Residential Washers from Korea (AB , DS464)

Tax and Superannuation Laws Amendment (2016 Measures No. 1) Bill 2016 No., 2016

Chapter 16 Indirect Taxation

Mechanisms for the Effective Collection of VAT/GST WHERE THE SUPPLIER IS NOT LOCATED IN THE JURISDICTION OF TAXATION

Applying IFRS. A closer look at IFRS accounting for the effects of the US Tax Cuts and Jobs Act. January 2018

RESEARCH Paper. The Most Favoured-Nation provision in the EC/EAC Economic Partnership Agreement and its implications: Agriculture and Development

The Uruguay Round and the Liberalization of

Re: USCIB Comments on HM Treasury s position paper on Corporate Tax and the Digital Economy

CANADA. The U.S.-Canada Free Trade Agreement and the North American Free Trade Agreement

Draft Chapter 6 Measurement Issues Associated with Quasi-transit Trade and Similar Phenomena 1

How to Methodically Research WTO Law

The Estey Centre Journal of. International Law. and Trade Policy

NATIONAL TREATMENT AND MARKET ACCESS FOR GOODS. Section A: Scope and coverage. Article. Scope. Article. Objective

In the World Trade Organization CANADA MEASURES RELATING TO THE FEED-IN TARIFF PROGRAM (DS426)

MANAGING INTERNATIONAL TAX ISSUES

April 30, Re: USCIB Comment Letter on the OECD discussion draft on BEPS Action 3: Strengthening CFC Rules. Dear Mr. Pross, General Comments

An Analysis of "Buy America" Provisions In ADF Group Inc. v. United States under Chapter 11 of the NAFTA. Rahna Epting, IELP Law Clerk August 25, 2005

VALUE ADDED TAX COMMITTEE (ARTICLE 398 OF DIRECTIVE 2006/112/EC) WORKING PAPER NO 903 REV

Netherlands 13 th Directive (86/560/EEC) VAT refunds

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

ARGENTINA MEASURES AFFECTING THE

IRELAND GLOBAL GUIDE TO M&A TAX: 2017 EDITION

DATE: 2/24/2017. TO: All Employees & Contractors FROM: Tod Carpenter, President and CEO SUBJECT: Global Trade Compliance Policy Statement

Land Rich Duty 1. Peter Allen and Katrina Parkyn, Allens Arthur Robinson

Taxation of cross-border mergers and acquisitions

Foreign Investments in German Real Estate

What In-House Counsel Needs to Know about Trade Compliance

1 Three major Problems for Software Product Companies. 2 Removing Confusion on Goods and Service tax for Software Products in Indirect tax regime

Article 20. Other Requirements

international law of contemporary media session 7: the law of the world trade organization (part 2)

Then one-cap subtitle follows, comparisons both in 36-point Arial bold

Comparison and Assessment of the Tax Treatment of Foreign Source Income in Canada, Australia, France, Germany and the United States

Article XXVIII. Definitions

Agreement on Trade-Related Investment Measures

A Handbook on the WTO Customs Valuation Agreement

Austria. Clemens Philipp Schindler and Martina Gatterer. Schindler Attorneys

UK Trade in Goods Statistics Methodology Statement. Overview of Asymmetries 1. WHO SHOULD READ THIS? 2. INTRODUCTION

POSSIBLE UPDATE OF THE EXTRACTIVE INDUSTRIES HANDBOOK

Climate Policy and Carbon Tariffs: Some New Wine Mixed with Old Wine in New Green bottles?

Overview of the Consumption Tax System in Japan - May Yasutaka Nishikori Nishimura & Asahi. 1 Historical Background

General National Treatment Obligation: Article III:4 of the GATT 1994

Introduction to the GATS

Article 2. Specificity

Economics 340 International Economics Prof. Alan Deardorff First Midterm Exam. Form 0. February 19, 2018

Canadian Tax Foundation. Fifty-Eighth Annual Conference November 26 - November 28, 2006 The Westin Harbour Castle Hotel, Toronto

EU-Mexico Free Trade Agreement EU TEXTUAL PROPOSAL. Chapter on Trade in Goods. Article X.1. Scope. Article X.2

NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

The European Commission Is Attempting a Radical Change to How Digital Transactions Are Taxed Throughout the EU

Transcription:

3 Appendix C Border Adjustments under the National Retail Sales Tax or Corporate Activity Tax Administrative Issues From an administrative standpoint, it is easy to exempt exports of goods and services from either the NRST or CAT. For the NRST, exemption happens naturally because the point of tax collection is a retail sales transaction within US territory. For CAT, exemption requires the exporting firm to claim a deduction for its export revenue, and to back up the deduction with a customs declaration and evidence of payment from the foreign purchaser. However, from an administrative standpoint, tax collection at the border on imports of goods and services presents challenges under both the NRST and CAT. Under both systems, it would be almost impossible to collect taxes on sales of digital services, such as videos, music, or software, from foreign businesses to domestic consumers. Foreign sellers are not a plausible tax collection point for a US retail sales tax. Moreover, in the absence of a novel tax accord between the United States and the European Union (as well as numerous other countries), foreign business firms would not be liable to pay CAT to the US Treasury on business-to-consumer sales. Sales of digital services from foreign to domestic businesses would be susceptible to tax under CAT by denying the US firm a deduction for the foreign purchase. Under the NRST, such sales would be taxed when a US firm made a retail sale of a product that included the foreign digital service. Merchandise imports present different tax collection challenges under the NRST and CAT. Under the NRST, imported merchandise would not 91

be subject to tax unless the buyer was a household consumer. To collect the tax on consumers returning tourists, household imports via UPS or FedEx, and direct household purchases of autos and furniture made abroad customs authorities would need to distinguish between household and business imports. The administrative challenge would be to identify and weed out dummy business firms that were fronts for household purchasers to avoid paying the NRST. Apart from that challenge, it is worth noting that the NRST would tax imports of capital equipment, if at all, only over the period of time that capital services show up in the price of retail goods. In some instances, the services of imported capital would never appear in the price of products subject to the NRST for example, public services such as roads and hospitals. WTO Aspects Graetz (2002b, paragraph 25) contends that export exemptions are not permitted for the subtraction-method VAT under the WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (SCM). The SCM is part of the GATT, and thus applies to trade in goods but not services. Graetz argues that a subtraction-method VAT, as an entity tax, does not qualify as an indirect tax under the SCM. Hence, exemption of exports from a subtraction-method VAT would amount to a prohibited export subsidy. Annex I of the SCM provides an Illustrative List of measures that are and are not considered prohibited export subsidies (SCM, Article 3.1(a)). Item (e) of the Annex lists as a prohibited export subsidy: (e) The full or partial exemption, remission, or deferral specifically related to exports, of direct taxes or social welfare charges paid or payable by industrial or commercial enterprises. By implication and history, the full or partial remission of indirect taxes is not a prohibited export subsidy, nor indeed any other type of subsidy. 1 In footnote 58 of the SCM, direct and indirect taxes are defined as follows: For the purpose of the Agreement: The term direct taxes shall mean taxes on wages, profits, interests, rents, royalties and all other forms of income, and taxes on the ownership of real property.... 1. WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures, footnote 5 to Article 3.1(a) makes this clear: Measures referred to in Annex I as not constituting export subsidies shall not be prohibited under this or any other provision of this Agreement. 92 REFORMING THE US CORPORATE TAX

The term indirect taxes shall mean sales, excise, turnover, value added, franchise, stamp, transfer, inventory and equipment taxes, border taxes and all taxes other than direct taxes and import charges.... This definition makes no distinction between credit-invoice and subtraction-method VAT systems, although both versions were well known by 1994, the year of the Uruguay Round SCM agreement. Furthermore, the footnote enunciates a restrictive definition of direct taxes. A plain reading of the SCM Illustrative List places subtraction-method VAT systems in the indirect tax category, eligible for border adjustment. Graetz s core assertion is that, by virtue of the fact that the subtractionmethod VAT is administered as an entity tax, it becomes a direct tax rather than an indirect tax. We would be amazed if, in the course of litigation, the WTO Appellate Body could be persuaded by this argument, since it turns on administrative form rather than economic substance. However, if the WTO Appellate Body did conclude that a subtraction-method VAT is a direct tax, the United States, Japan, and other subtraction-method VAT countries should insist that the SCM Code be amended. A related WTO legal question is whether a border tax can be imposed on imported merchandise in lieu of a subtraction-method VAT. The specific question is whether collecting the in-lieu-of tax on imports at the same rate as the subtraction-method VAT would violate the national treatment requirement of GATT Article III. GATT Article III, paragraph 4 reads: The products of the territory of any contracting party imported into the territory of any other contracting party shall be accorded treatment no less favorable than that accorded like products of national origin in respect to all laws, regulations and requirements affecting their internal sale, offering for sale, purchase, transportation, distribution or use.... The threshold question is whether a subtraction-method VAT may properly be considered a tax on products again highlighting the administrative differences between a credit-invoice VAT and a subtraction-method VAT. Some commentators (such as Graetz 2002b) might argue that because the credit-invoice VAT is applied transaction by transaction, it is a tax on individual products; meanwhile, since the subtraction-method VAT is a tax on the whole entity, it cannot be attributed to individual products. This argument again elevates form over substance. Each subtraction-method VAT payer is perfectly capable, just as credit-invoice VAT payers are, of producing an invoice showing purchasers how much tax was collected through the whole chain of production, simply by multiplying the tax-inclusive rate by the tax-inclusive price. The only difference is that for a subtraction-method VAT firm, there is no trail of invoices going back to the farm or mine. We feel confident that the Appellate Body would not cite this difference to rule that the subtraction-method VAT is not a product tax. APPENDIX C 93

As mentioned earlier, we propose that US firms that are not CATregistered be required to pay a tax on merchandise imports in lieu of CAT (our preferred version of a subtraction-method VAT). A national treatment problem might arise if the importing US firm is a pass-through entity. This firm might claim that it is not subject to CAT, directly or indirectly, when it buys the equivalent good from a domestic pass-through entity. Therefore, it should not have to pay the in-lieu-of tax on imports. This argument would have merit in those rare instances where the alternative domestic supplier was indeed a pass-through entity, and where that supplier also purchased all its inputs from pass-through entities. Provided the eligibility test for taxation as a pass-through entity is sufficiently narrow, only a small amount of intermediate inputs made in the United States would be sold by these entities. In most cases, the alternative domestic supplier would directly or indirectly pay CAT. Hence, there is no real difference in the great majority of transactions: imports would pay the in-lieu-of tax; domestic suppliers would pay CAT. If the WTO Appellate Body nevertheless ruled that imports by passthrough entities should be exempt from the in-lieu-of tax, a gaping revenue hole would be created. Such a ruling would lead nearly all importers selling consumer goods to conduct their purchases from foreign suppliers by using pass-through entities. We are very doubtful that the WTO Appellate Body would open this loophole. If it did, the United States would have to sharply narrow the CAT exemption for pass-through entities. A special question arises for household imports under CAT. In a few cases, households might argue that the alternative domestic supplier was a pass-through entity, such as a small jewelry or leather goods firm. However, it is worth noting that US imports of low-value shipments (under $1,250 each, predominantly purchases by returning tourists) were only $14 billion in 2003. If the WTO rules against the United States on this point, the revenue loss from exempting low-value imports by returning tourists would not be great. The hypothetical argument for exemption from the in-lieu-of tax is stronger when it comes to legal, accounting, and consulting services provided by foreign firms. Article XVII of the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) requires national treatment with respect to imported services that are scheduled by a WTO member. Within the United States, these services are often supplied by pass-through entities, notably partnerships and limited-liability corporations. As we have envisaged CAT, it would not attempt to tax imports of such services per se, but only when purchased by a US firm subject to CAT. Hence, under our plan, there would be no conflict with the GATS national treatment standard for business-to-business sales of such services. Imported business services, like domestic business services supplied by a pass-through entity, would not qualify as a deduction from the CAT base. However, when foreign firms supplied these services directly to domestic households, 94 REFORMING THE US CORPORATE TAX

those purchases would escape the CAT net (the same as purchases from domestic service firms). Summary While potential loopholes exist, both the NRST and CAT are broadly adjustable at the border, in contrast to the corporate income tax. Both regimes would fully exempt exports, and both would assess business tax on nearly all imports of goods and business services. Under both regimes, some imports would escape taxation, but this quantity appears to be small. As with any tax system, loopholes would be enlarged over time. Periodic reviews and amendments would thus be required. Moreover, in the context of broader trade negotiations on a bilateral or regional basis, such as the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), the United States and its partners might agree, on a reciprocal basis, to eliminate their border adjustments on imports from one another. This is an intriguing possibility, but a topic beyond the scope of the present monograph. APPENDIX C 95