Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Similar documents
Review of the literature on the comparison

What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates?

Lecture notes 10. Monetary policy: nominal anchor for the system

The Lack of an Empirical Rationale for a Revival of Discretionary Fiscal Policy. John B. Taylor Stanford University

Comments on Jeffrey Frankel, Commodity Prices and Monetary Policy by Lars Svensson

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning

The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting

BANK OF CANADA RENEWAL OF BACKGROUND INFORMATION THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET. May 2001

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

The Real Business Cycle Model

Please choose the most correct answer. You can choose only ONE answer for every question.

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession

Long-term uncertainty and social security systems

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

Carmen M. Reinhart b. Received 9 February 1998; accepted 7 May 1998

Threshold cointegration and nonlinear adjustment between stock prices and dividends

The estimation of money demand in the Slovak Republic Ing. Viera Kollárová, Ing. Rastislav âársky National Bank of Slovakia

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University

III. 9. IS LM: the basic framework to understand macro policy continued Text, ch 11

Real Business Cycle Theory

Estimating the Impact of Changes in the Federal Funds Target Rate on Market Interest Rates from the 1980s to the Present Day

Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8

The Macroeconometric model for Italy - MeMo-It

Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI

MONETARY POLICY EXPECTATIONS AND BOOM-BUST CYCLES IN THE HOUSING MARKET*

Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research

Traded and non-traded goods

ECO209 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Chapter 14

Price-Level Targeting The Role of Credibility

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

Administered Prices and Inflation Targeting in Thailand Kanin Peerawattanachart

The Goods Market and the Aggregate Expenditures Model

Micro-foundations: Consumption. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Is there a significant connection between commodity prices and exchange rates?

DOES MONEY GRANGER CAUSE INFLATION IN THE EURO AREA?*

2014/2015, week 6 The Ramsey model. Romer, Chapter 2.1 to 2.6

Commentary. Olivier Blanchard. 1. Should We Expect Automatic Stabilizers to Work, That Is, to Stabilize?

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy

Macroeconomics. Introduction to Economic Fluctuations. Zoltán Bartha, PhD Associate Professor. Andrea S. Gubik, PhD Associate Professor

), is described there by a function of the following form: U (c t. )= c t. where c t

What Operating Procedures Should Be Adopted to Maintain Price Stability? Practical Issues

Do core inflation measures help forecast inflation? Out-of-sample evidence from French data

Part II Money and Public Finance Lecture 7 Selected Issues from a Positive Perspective

Suggested Solutions to Assignment 7 (OPTIONAL)

Macro Notes: Introduction to the Short Run

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

Monetary Policy Frameworks

September 21, 2016 Bank of Japan

An Estimate of the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Growth* First draft May 1; revised June 6, 2000

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Risk Shocks and Economic Fluctuations. Summary of work by Christiano, Motto and Rostagno

Master of Arts in Economics. Approved: Roger N. Waud, Chairman. Thomas J. Lutton. Richard P. Theroux. January 2002 Falls Church, Virginia

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies

Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound

MONEY, PRICES AND THE EXCHANGE RATE: EVIDENCE FROM FOUR OECD COUNTRIES

Yale ICF Working Paper No First Draft: February 21, 1992 This Draft: June 29, Safety First Portfolio Insurance

Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information

VII. Short-Run Economic Fluctuations

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Can P* Be a Basis for Core Inflation in the Philippines?

Volume Author/Editor: Kenneth Singleton, editor. Volume URL:

Investment 3.1 INTRODUCTION. Fixed investment

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

Are we there yet? Adjustment paths in response to Tariff shocks: a CGE Analysis.

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang

Discussion of Risks to Price Stability, The Zero Lower Bound, and Forward Guidance: A Real-Time Assessment

MONITORING JOBS AND INFLATION

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Commentary: Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old

Monetary policy and models

Fiscal Consolidation Strategy: An Update for the Budget Reform Proposal of March 2013

Canadian Inflation, Unemployment, and Business Cycle

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

ECF2331 Final Revision

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

PROSPECTS FOR THE UNITED STATES ECONOMY

Volatility Clustering of Fine Wine Prices assuming Different Distributions

At the European Council in Copenhagen in December

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

WHAT DOES THE HOUSE PRICE-TO-

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching with Time-Varying Volatilities

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ARE GOVERNMENT SPENDING MULTIPLIERS GREATER DURING PERIODS OF SLACK? EVIDENCE FROM 20TH CENTURY HISTORICAL DATA

ACTIVE FISCAL, PASSIVE MONEY EQUILIBRIUM IN A PURELY BACKWARD-LOOKING MODEL

Transcription:

Discussion Benoît Carmichael The two studies presented in the first session of the conference take quite different approaches to the question of price indexes. On the one hand, Coulombe s study develops the idea that the general level of prices is indeed a relevant intertemporal price under a monetary regime where the general price level is stationary. The author illustrates this viewpoint by analysing the behaviour of real interest rate expectations during the gold-standard era in Great Britain. In doing this, Coulombe suggests a new solution to Gibson s paradox. On the other hand, Crawford, Fillion, and Laflèche, using the latest econometric techniques, set out to determine whether inflation, as measured by the consumer price index (CPI), is a satisfactory way of identifying the underlying trend of inflation in Canada. Their study also attempts to quantify the degree of bias in the CPI as a measure of the cost of living. In this discussion I do not compare and contrast the results of these two studies. The two approaches are very different, making any comparison risky. The primary objective of Coulombe s study is to reassess to what extent the general price level can convey useful information to economic agents in their intertemporal decisions, beyond what is already revealed by the interest rate. According to conventional interpretation, the real interest rate is the only intertemporal price that is relevant for allocating consumption over time. Once this is known, the general price level does not offer any additional information that would help individuals make better choices. Coulombe s study seeks to show that this result is in fact valid only in an economy where the general price level is integrated of order one. Let me review his argument briefly: 77

78 Discussion: Carmichael An individual who maximizes his utility will allocate his consumption over periods t and t + 1 to equalize the marginal rate of intertemporal substitution (MRIS) at the anticipated real interest rate: MRIS t logu ( t ) logu ( t+1 ) r t π at+1,. This is measured by the deviation between the nominal interest rate, r t, and the expected inflation rate, π at+1, = ( p at+1, p t ). Coulombe analyses the implications of this condition for the behaviour of the expected real interest rate under two different monetary regimes. In the one case, the monetary authority seeks to keep the inflation rate constant at its trend value π, while in the other case, monetary policy is aimed instead at keeping the general price level on a deterministic path, growing at rate π. The two regimes differ in a crucial way. Under the first monetary regime, any shocks to the general price level persist indefinitely; under the second, they are eventually completely eliminated by the central bank, since the level of prices will always return to the long-term trend. With the first monetary regime, the expected inflation rate is always equal to the trend inflation rate. There is no possible gap, therefore, between conditional and non-conditional expectations about the inflation rate. It is rational for an individual always to expect inflation to remain at its trend value. For this reason, the current price level gives no information about the intertemporal value of goods and services. Conversely, under the second monetary regime, the price level always returns to its long-term trend. The conditional expectation for the inflation rate that is, the rational expectation for π t+1 is not generally equal to the trend inflation rate. In fact, in Coulombe s example, the expected inflation rate, π at+1,, is equal to the trend inflation rate, from which we must subtract a factor that flows from the short-term dynamics of the inflation rate. This short-term factor, which is equal to α( pt µt ), depends on the deviation of the price level, p t, from its long-term trend, µ t. In an economy where the price level is constant over the long term, the Euler condition ( 2 ) becomes simply C t+1 MRIS t = ln ---------- = r C t + α( p t p 0 ). t In this case, the individual will assess his subjective real interest rate directly on the basis of information conveyed by the nominal interest rate and the general price level. Coulombe interprets this result as an indication that the general price level is in fact a relative intertemporal price that conveys information that is useful for decision-making. Perhaps the most significant result of this study is to show that the Summers effect is not valid in an economy where the price level is stationary. In effect, as can readily be seen from the above equation, the subjective real interest rate can become

Discussion: Carmichael 79 negative, even if there is a minimum floor under the nominal interest rate. If p t drops enough with respect to p 0, the MRIS becomes negative. In this context, it is as if the economy has a relative price as well the general price level for making adjustments. The burden of adjustment no longer falls entirely on the nominal interest rate, as it does in the first monetary regime. This might then allow for smoother adjustments to economic shocks. For this reason, and contrary to Summers conclusion (1991), Coulombe maintains that a monetary regime with stable prices is the better one. Without doubt, this would seem to be the main conclusion of his study, in terms of economic policy. So far, the analysis has been developed entirely within a context of partial equilibrium. The author considers only the perspective of individuals who are maximizing their utility. Despite the encouraging empirical results obtained for the gold-standard period, it is still difficult to assess whether Coulombe s results can stand up to a general-equilibrium analysis. We must remember that the nominal interest rate is treated here as an exogenous variable. It would be interesting to see whether the mechanism that Coulombe describes is operational when all prices and all quantities are determined simultaneously. It is possible to construct a fairly standard model in which, at general equilibrium, nominal interest rate movements will always cancel out those of the factor α( p t µ t ), leaving the real interest rate independent of the general price level. Benassy (1995) offers a good example of such a model. Moreover, in a general-equilibrium context, the stabilizing effect described by the author is easier to visualize when shocks come from the aggregate demand side, since in this case the GDP and the general price level fluctuate in tandem. Intuitively, those who react according to equation ( 2 ) have, as individuals, an interest in reducing (or increasing) their MRIS when they observe a fall (or a rise) in the general price level. This reduction (increase) translates in practice into an increase (reduction) in their current demand for goods and services, C t, at the expense of their future consumption. Thus, in the case of a negative aggregate demand shock, the drop in the general price level will induce individuals to react in a way that will weaken the shock s initial impact. This is the stabilizing effect mentioned by the author. In the case of an aggregate supply shock, the price effect may function in the opposite direction and, as I see it, could thus be destabilizing for the economy. A recession caused by a negative supply shock is accompanied by an increase in the general price level. Under the second monetary regime, this will lead individuals to increase (reduce) their MRIS and therefore to reduce (increase) their demand for goods and services, C t. Such a reaction will reinforce, rather than weaken, the initial depressing effect on output and employment. This brings me to the conclusion that the stabilizing effect described by the author will be dominant only if economic shocks come mainly from the

80 Discussion: Carmichael demand side. Of course, my own analysis, like that of the author, ignores movements in the nominal interest rate. It does, however, illustrate the need to examine the mechanism that Coulombe has identified within a generalequilibrium context. In his conclusion, Coulombe reminds us of the advantages of a regime of price-level stability, and he urges the Bank of Canada to give this option serious consideration. Before choosing such a regime, and thereby imposing the occasional period of deflation, we should look carefully at the costs of moving towards this kind of regime. Unless the new monetary regime could be made instantly credible, the shift towards a regime of pricelevel stability might well impose great economic and social costs on the Canadian economy. Even if our understanding of economic phenomena today is better than it was 50 or 60 years ago, there is still a risk that our generation, like preceding ones, will adjust only slowly to a radical change of regime. If that is the case, then we should proceed with caution. I turn now to the study by Crawford, Fillion, and Laflèche, which gives us a highly detailed analysis of inflation measures based on the Canadian CPI. The study has three primary objectives. First, it seeks to determine whether trend movements in the CPI are consistent with those observed in other price measurements in particular, the implicit GDP deflator and the general level of unit labour costs. Second, the study examines new statistical measurements of the trend inflation rate that are intended to eliminate temporary supply shocks. Finally, the paper summarizes and, more important, quantifies the various biases present in the measure of the Canadian CPI. Overall, the authors have used great care in their study. It provides several new empirical results, particularly with respect to the new measures of trend inflation in Canada, and the measurement biases contained in the CPI. My comments about the study focus on four points. First, the absence of cointegration between the implicit GDP deflator and the general level of unit labour costs is surprising and deserves more attention. During the period examined, services accounted for an increasingly important share of the Canadian economy. It is possible that the difficulties surrounding the measurement of output in these service sectors may lead to major errors in measuring the deflators. If that is the case, they might contaminate the estimated relationships and produce results where there is no cointegration. It is not surprising, then, given the biases in the CPI measurement noted in Section 3 of the paper, to see that the empirical results reject the hypothesis of a unitary cointegration vector between the CPI and other price measures. Second, I wonder whether the authors have overlooked the possible positive correlation between the level of inflation and its variance (see Okun

Discussion: Carmichael 81 1971; Pagan, Hall, and Trivedi 1983; and Crawford and Kasumavich 1996, for example). Their Table 5 shows that the volatility of inflation has declined with the drop in the average rate of inflation. The authors do not seem to have tested rigorously for heteroscedasticity of errors in the estimated vector error-correction model (VECM). The standard deviations of the residuals shown in Table 2 will overestimate the variability of shocks during periods of low inflation if there is a positive correlation in the data between the level of inflation and its variance. It is thus possible and even probable that the simulation results in Table 3 overestimate the variability of deviations in the inflation rate over the different time horizons calculated. For the same reason, we might suspect that the excess-deviation frequencies calculated in Table 4 are also overestimated. We must remember that a deviation of 1 per cent is proportionately more significant when the average inflation rate is fluctuating around a level of 2 per cent, as at present, rather than around 10 per cent, as in the late 1970s and early 1980s. Third, it would be interesting to know whether the new measures for Canada s trend inflation are more strongly correlated with aggregate demand shocks, especially with the rate of growth of the money supply, than are the raw data. In the United States, Bryan and Cecchetti (1993) have concluded that growth of the money supply in the past was more strongly correlated with trend inflation measures based on the weighted mean or weighted average of the trimmed distribution than with the overall rate of CPI inflation. What is perhaps even more interesting is that their Grangercausality tests show that lagged monetary growth predicts future trend inflation, even when the forecasting capacity of past inflation is factored in. This would seem to overturn the counterintuitive results of Hoover (1991), which show a correlation in the opposite direction, from inflation to money growth, when inflation is measured with the raw data. Finally, I believe Section 3 of the paper offers an excellent review of the various biases in the CPI as a measure of the cost of living in Canada. The analysis shows that Canadian biases, while less significant than those observed in the United States, are still not negligible at 0.7 per cent per year. We must remember that a bias of that magnitude produces an accumulated deviation of 10 per cent after 14 years. In theory, the idea of setting the inflation target at the total bias value, with the goal of keeping the purchasing power of money constant, is interesting and deserves to be examined seriously. However, before adopting such a policy, we need to assess whether the bias varies in a predictable way over time, for example as a trend, or as a function of the state of the economy.

82 Discussion: Carmichael References Benassy, J-P. 1995. Money and Wage Contracts in an Optimizing Model of the Business Cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 35 (April): 303-15. Bryan, M. F., and S. G. Cecchetti. 1993. Measuring Core Inflation. NBER Working Paper No. 4303. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass. Crawford, A., and M. Kasumavich. 1996. Does Inflation Uncertainty Vary with the Level of Inflation? Working Paper No. 96-9. Bank of Canada, Ottawa. Hoover, K. D. 1991. The Causal Direction Between Money and Prices: An Alternative Approach. Journal of Monetary Economics 27 (June): 381-423. Okun, A. M. 1971. The Mirage of Steady Inflation. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2): 485-98. Pagan, A. R., A. D. Hall, and P. K. Trivedi. 1983. Assessing the Variability of Inflation. Review of Economic Studies 50 (October): 585-96.