Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Similar documents
Exchange. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory. Boston College. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory (BC) Exchange 1 / 23

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

The Robinson Crusoe model; the Edgeworth Box in Consumption and Factor allocation

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Economics 11: Solutions to Practice Final

3. The Deadweight Loss of Taxation

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Introductory Economics of Taxation. Lecture 1: The definition of taxes, types of taxes and tax rules, types of progressivity of taxes

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

2. Equlibrium and Efficiency

Advanced Microeconomics

Optimal tax and transfer policy

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

Microeconomics IV. First Semster, Course

ECON MACROECONOMIC THEORY Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 5 - Closed Economy Model Towson University 1 / 47

Chapter Thirty. Production

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Lecture 7. The consumer s problem(s) Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2018 Last updated: April 28, 2018

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. August 2010

Econ205 Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Chapter 1

The objectives of the producer

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

ECON 340/ Zenginobuz Fall 2011 STUDY QUESTIONS FOR THE FINAL. x y z w u A u B

A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Microeconomics Review in a Two Good World

The Static Model. Consumer Assumptions on the preferences: Consumer. A description of the Model Economy

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

ECON 200 EXERCISES. (b) Appeal to any propositions you wish to confirm that the production set is convex.

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Lecture 15 - General Equilibrium with Production

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Tools of normative analysis

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM. Wanna Download D. Salvatore, International Economics for free? Gr8, visit now jblogger2016.wordpress.com

Solutions to Problem Set 1

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization. Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Economics 4315/7315: Public Economics

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

ECON Micro Foundations

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

Bureaucratic Efficiency and Democratic Choice

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Market Design. Econ University of Notre Dame

Chapter 12 GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Econ 892 Taxation Sept 13, Introduction. First Welfare Theorem (illustration by the Edgeworth Box)

Welfare Economics. Jan Abrell Centre for Energy Policy and Economics (CEPE) D-MTEC, ETH Zurich. Welfare Economics

1 Excess burden of taxation

p 1 _ x 1 (p 1 _, p 2, I ) x 1 X 1 X 2

Intermediate public economics 5 Externalities Hiroaki Sakamoto

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Economics 230a, Fall 2017 Lecture Note 6: Basic Tax Incidence

1 Dynamic programming

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

1 Two Period Production Economy

On Diamond-Dybvig (1983): A model of liquidity provision

GE in production economies

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

PhD Qualifier Examination

Chapter II: Labour Market Policy

ARE 202: Welfare: Tools and Applications Spring Lecture notes 03 Applications of Revealed Preferences

U(x 1, x 2 ) = 2 ln x 1 + x 2

Lecture 1: A Robinson Crusoe Economy

Optimal Progressivity

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

PRODUCTION COSTS. Econ 311 Microeconomics 1 Lecture Material Prepared by Dr. Emmanuel Codjoe

Intro to Economic analysis

Macro (8701) & Micro (8703) option

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Exogenous variables are determined outside a macroeconomic model. Figure 5.1 A Model Takes Exogenous Variables and Determines Endogenous Variables

A. Introduction to choice under uncertainty 2. B. Risk aversion 11. C. Favorable gambles 15. D. Measures of risk aversion 20. E.

Intermediate Macroeconomics

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

Time, Uncertainty, and Incomplete Markets

ASHORTCOURSEIN INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS WITH CALCULUS. allan

Economics 313: Intermediate Microeconomics II. Sample Final Examination. Version 1. Instructor: Dr. Donna Feir

Assignment 5 Advanced Microeconomics

A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Answers to June 11, 2012 Microeconomics Prelim

Transcription:

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics Laurent Simula ENS Lyon 1 / 54

Roadmap Introduction Pareto Optimality General Equilibrium The Two Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Taxation and individuals 2 / 54

Objectives of this Chapter Make sure that we all agree on the basic general equilibrium, i.e., on its definition and its welfare properties. What is meant by an efficient economic outcome. Under which conditions the process through which prices are determined leads to an efficient outcome. Whether efficiency and equity are compatible or if there is a trade-off between more efficiency and more equity. Refresh and/or introduce a number of basic results and concepts from (public) economics. 3 / 54

Taking All Market Interations into Account Consider a setting in which: Prices are parameters for the individual decision-takers (consumers and producers). Hence, demand and supply functions depend on: the price of the commodity we consider; but also on the other prices in the economy. How prices are determined by the interaction of the decisions of individuals? Focus on the own price effect partial equilibrium viewpoint: interactions between the markets are neglected; single marker considered in isolation. Taking all interactions into account general equilibrium viewpoint. 4 / 54

Competitive General Equilibrium Our analysis will sometimes focus on the general equilibrium under the assumptions of perfect competition: Many buyers and many sellers. Economic agents are thus price takers. Homogeneous products. All products exchanged on a given market, have comparable features. No-entry/exit barriers. It is easy to enter or exit as a business in a perfectly competitive market. Hence, if there is a market on which firms make strictly positive profits in the short-run, new firms will enter the market. New firms will continue to enter the market up to the point where profits are equal to zero. Consequently, in the long run, firms do not make positive profits. Perfect information. All information relevant to the consumer s/producer s decision is available at no cost. 5 / 54

Why Is Perfect Competition Interesting? All distinguishing characteristics of competitive markets are (usually) not satisfied at the same time. General equilibrium under imperfect competition: market powers; asymmetric information; externalities; public goods. However perfect competition is worth studying because: benchmark to which the equilibrium under imperfect competition can be compared; attractive features. Might (to some extent) be regarded as a situation we would like to achieve. 6 / 54

Roadmap Introduction Pareto Optimality Definition Pareto Optimality in a Pure Exchange Economy Introducing Production General Equilibrium The Two Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Taxation and individuals 7 / 54

Pareto Criterion Definition Consider two allocations a 1 and a 2 of economic resources. Then, the allocation a 1 is Pareto-preferred to the allocation a 2 if and only if no one is worse off under a 1 than a 2. Consider an economy with two individuals with the same preferences u (x 1, x 2 ) = x 1 x 2. Now, consider the allocations ( x A 1, xa 2, xb 1, ) xb 2 defined by X 1 = (1, 1, 2, 2), X 2 = (1, 2, 1, 2) and X 3 = (1.5, 1.5, 2, 2). What can we say according to the Pareto criterion? X 3 Pareto-preferred to X 2. Incomplete ranking. Utility A B X 1 1 4 X 2 2 2 X 3 2.25 4 8 / 54

Pareto Optimality/Efficiency Definition A Pareto efficient allocation is an allocation of economic resources which is Pareto-preferred to all other feasible allocations. This implies that: There is no way to make all agents better off. In other words, it is not possible to increase the welfare of an individual without decreasing that of another individual. item In the above example, X 3 is the unique Pareto optimal allocation (in the set consisting of X 1, X 2 and X 3 ). 9 / 54

Pure Exchange Economy: Basic Setting All economic agents are consumers. 2 agents (A and B) + 2 goods (1 and 2) + utilities u A ( x A 1, ) xa 2 and u B ( x B 1, ) xb 2. Quantities consumed: ( x A 1, ) ( xa 2 for A and x B 1, x B ) 2 for B. Initial endowments: A has ( ω1 A, ) ωa 2 of goods 1 and 2 respectively; B has ( ω1 B, ) ωb 2. Economy represented in an Edgeworth box of size X 1 X 2 = ( ω1 A + ) ( ωb 1 ω A 2 + ω2 B ). 10 / 54

Characterization of Pareto Optimum Allocations (1.) What are the allocations of resources corresponding to Pareto optima? Solution to: Problem Find a 4-uplet ( x A 1, xa 2, xb 1, ) xb 2 which maximises u A ( x A 1, ) xa 2 subject to the constraint that person B s utility is above a threshold u B, i.e. u B ( x B 1, x B ) 2 ub, and to the resource constraints x A 1 + x B 1 ω A 1 + ω B 1 = X 1, x A 2 + x B 2 ω A 2 + ω B 2 = X 2. 11 / 54

Underlying assumptions (1.) We will asssume that the utility functions are of class C 2, increasing in each argument and quasiconcave. Let i be person i s preference relations, defined for the choice set X. We define: completeness: (x, y) X 2, x i y or y i x. transitivity: (x, y, z) X 3, x i y and y i z implies x i z. continuity: if x = lim n x n, y = lim n y n and x n i y n for every n, then x i y. monotonicity: (x, y) X 2, x > y = x i y. convexity: (x, y) X 2, {y X : y i x} is convex. 12 / 54

Underlying assumptions (2.) Under Completeness + Transitivity + Continuity There exists a continuous utility function u : X R which represents person i s preferences. Under Completeness + Transitivity + Continuity + Monotonicity + Convexity There exists a utility function u : X R of class C 2, increasing in each of its argument and quasiconcave which represents person i s preferences. 13 / 54

Characterization of Pareto Optimum Allocations (2.) Under these assumptions, the individual utility maximization problem has (at least) a solution. Strict convexity of preference relation (i.e., strict quasiconcavity of utility function) ensures uniqueness of the solution Individual budget constraints are binding, implying that the overall resource constraints are binding. Monotonicity of person A s preferences implies that the utility constraint u B ( x B 1, ) xb 2 ub is binding. 14 / 54

Characterization of Pareto Optimum Allocations (3.) Under the above-mentionned assumptions, looking for a PO allocation is equivalent to solving: Problem (Equivalent Formulation for PO) Find a 4-uplet ( x A 1, xa 2, xb 1, ) ( xb 2 = x A 1, x A 2, X 1 x A 1, X 2 x A ) 2 which maximises u A ( x A 1, ) xa 2 subject to the constraint u B ( X 1 x A 1, X 2 x A ) 2 = ub. For any allocation solution to this Problem, it is impossible to increase the utility of person A without decreasing the utility of person B below u B. When we consider all possible values for the threshold u B, from 0 case in which all goods are given to person A to u B (X 1, X 2 ) case in which all goods are given to person B, we describe all Pareto efficient allocation in the Edgeworth box. 15 / 54

Characterization of Pareto Optimum Allocations (4.) Lagrangian: L = u A ( x A 1, ) [ xa 2 + λ u B ( X 1 x A 1, X 2 x A ) ] 2 ub. First-order conditions for a maximum: L ( = 0 ua x A 1, ) ( xa 2 λ ub X 1 x A 1, X 2 x A ) 2 = 0, x A 1 L x A 2 x A 1 x B 1 ( (1) = 0 ua x A 1, ) ( xa 2 λ ub X 1 x A 1, X 2 x A ) 2 = 0. x A 2 Eliminating λ, one gets: u A (x A 1,xA 2 ) x A 2 u A (x A 1,xA 2 ) x A 1 = u B (x B 1,xB 2 ) x B 2 u B (x B 1,xB 2 ) x B 1 x A 2 (2) MRS12 A ( x A 1, x A ) ( 2 = MRS B 12 x B 1, x B ) 2 At interior Pareto optimal allocations, the marginal rates of substitution of all individuals are equal. 16 / 54

Pareto Set, Efficiency and Social Justice? Person B s Good 1 O B Person B s Good 2 M 4 X2 M 2 M 3 Person A s Good 2 M 1 E O A X1 Person A s Good 1 17 / 54

Pareto Optimum with Production For simplicity, we will first look at a Robinson Crusoe economy: a consumer (representative consumer) (who thus owns the firm) two goods (labelled 1 and 2) produced in quantities x 1 and x 2 using the limited amount of resources available in the economy. Production Possibility Set (PPS): all combinations (x 1, x 2 ) which can be produced given available resources. Production Possibility Frontier (PPF): all technically efficient allocations. 18 / 54

PPS and PPF x2 P E U 3 G U 2 U 1 0 P Figure: Production Possibility Set (Pink Area including the Red Frontier) 19 / 54

Pareto Optimum Allocation with Production Marginal Rate of Transformation: The (opposite of the) slope of the PPF at a given (x 1, x 2 )-combination is called marginal rate of transformation of good 1 for good 2. Given individual preferences, best possible outcome at E, which is a Pareto optimum. There, the MRT is equal to the MRS. By extension, Theorem In a Pareto optimum allocation with production: (i) the marginal rates of substitution in consumption are identical for all consumers; (ii) the marginal rate of transformation in production is identical for all products; (iii) The marginal rates of substitution in consumption are equal to the marginal rates of transformation in production, such that production processes match consumer wants. 20 / 54

Roadmap Introduction Pareto Optimality General Equilibrium Definition Efficiency The Two Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Taxation and individuals 21 / 54

General Equilibrium Definition A general equilibrium is an equilibrium with the following features: 1. every consumer maximises his utility in his budget set; 2. every firm maximize its profits; 3. demand equals supply on every market. Condition (3.) is called the market clearing condition. 22 / 54

Competitive Equilibrium and Pareto Efficiency: Example x2 Efficient prices C C* G Initial prices E F C U 2 U 3 C* 0 Figure: Equilibrium and Efficiency: An Example 23 / 54

Roadmap Introduction Pareto Optimality General Equilibrium The Two Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Pareto Optimality of the Competitive Equilibrium Decentralization of a Pareto Optimum Taxation and individuals 24 / 54

Pareto Efficiency of Any Competitive General Equilibrium First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics Any general competitive equilibrium is Pareto efficient. Competitive markets tend toward the efficient allocation of resources. Supports a case for non-intervention in ideal conditions and in ideal conditions only: let the markets do the work and the outcome will be Pareto efficient. Pareto efficiency is not necessarily the same thing as desirability. There can be many possible Pareto efficient allocations of resources and not all of them may be equally desirable by society. The conditions of perfect competition are often not satisfied. Because the competitive equilibrium appears as normatively attractive (because it is a Pareto optimum), should governments policies aim at implementing the conditions of perfect competition when they are not satisfied in practice? 25 / 54

Decentralization of a Pareto Optimal Allocation as a General Equilibrium Any general competitive equilibrium is Pareto efficient. Yet, there can be many possible Pareto efficient allocations of resources and not all of them may be equally desirable by society. Is it possible for the policymaker to choose a desirable allocation, implement an appropriate economic policy, then let the markets freely work and finally obtain the desired allocation? The answer is: yes, under certain conditions. 26 / 54

Decentralization of a Pareto Optimal Allocation: Illustration Person B s Good 1 O B BC2 Person B s Good 2 M 4 X2 A M 2 M 3 M 1 B O A X1 Person A s Good 1 Figure: Decentralization of An Allocation as a General Equilibrium 27 / 54

Decentralization of a Pareto Optimal Allocation Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics When individual preferences and production possibility sets are convex, any Pareto optimum allocation can be obtained as a general equilibrium once appropriate lump-sum transfers have taken place. 28 / 54

Choice of the socially desirable allocation? Use of a Paretian social welfare function. Assume individual utilities are u ( x i 1, 2) xi for i = 1,..., N. We can define a social welfare function as W ( u ( x 1 1, x 2 ( 2),..., u x N 1, x N )) 2, non-decreasing in every individual utility u ( x i 1, xi 2). Examples of social welfare functions: Pure Utilitarianism: W ( u ( ( )) x 1 1, x2) 2,..., u x N 1, x N N 2 = i=1 u ( ) x i 1, x i 2. Weighted Utilitarianism: W ( u ( ( )) x 1 1, x2) 2,..., u x N 1, x N N 2 = i=1 G ( u ( )) x i 1, x i 2 with G concave (aversion to inequality). Rawlsian Maximin: W ( u ( ( )) { ( )} x 1 1, x2) 2,..., u x N 1, x N 2 = mini=1,...,n u x i 1, x i 2. Are lump-sum transfers feasible? 29 / 54

Roadmap Introduction Pareto Optimality General Equilibrium The Two Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Taxation and individuals 30 / 54

Taxation and individuals Throughout the Lectures, we derive key results in public economics by using highly simplified mathematical models of the economy Generally, we will focus on the simplest possible models that still bring home the key message Some key characteristics of these economic models include: Firms are fully rational and maximize profits Individuals are fully rational and maximize utility Markets are perfectly competitive Under these assumptions, we derive the following results below: 1. Equivalence between employee s and employer s income taxes 2. Equivalence between income tax and uniform commodity tax 3. Utility equivalence between different tax instruments 4. Income and substitution effects of the income tax 31 / 54

Equivalence between employee s and employer s income taxes Assume that the income tax consists of an employee s part t and an employer s part τ Firms hire l units of labor, with constant productivity n per unit = total production equals nl Firms pay wages w and face a payroll tax rate equal to τ = total labor costs equal (1 + τ)wl Profits are thus given by: Π = nl (1 + τ)wl Perfect competition and free entry of firms imply that equilibrium wage rate is given by (1 + τ)w = n. 32 / 54

A representative individual supplies l units of labor for a gross wage rate of w per unit ( ) = earns before-tax income wl = 1 1+τ nl Individual pays income tax rate t and consumes ( after-tax ) income c = consumption equal to c = (1 t)wl = 1 t 1+τ nl Individual utility is C 2, increasing in consumption and decreasing in labor supply: U = u(c, l), with u c > 0, u l < 0. Substitute for consumption c: (( ) ) 1 t U = u nl, l 1 + τ Maximize with respect to labor supply l: ( ) 1 t u l = nu c 1 + τ Marginal costs of supplying labor equals marginal benefits of consuming the resulting income 33 / 54

Notice that both utility and labor supply only depends on the combination 1 t 1+τ, not on t and τ separately = It does not matter whether income taxes are levied through employer taxes (τ > 0, t = 0) or employee taxes (t > 0, τ = 0) or any other combination. = Statements such as We should shift the burden of income taxation from employees to employers are largely nonsense. (Can you think of instances in which this equivalence does not hold?) In the remainder of the Lectures, we typically assume τ = 0 and thus w = n without loss of generality 34 / 54

Equivalence between an income tax and a uniform commodity tax We assume the government levies a proportional income tax t and a uniform commodity tax τ Representative individual with wage w supplies l units of labor: Before-tax income given by wl After-tax income given by (1 t)wl Income is spent on consumption goods c and x, and on a uniform commodity tax τ(c + x) Utility is given by: U = u(c, x, l), u c, u x > 0, u l < 0 Budget constraint is given by: (1 + τ)(c + x) = (1 t)wl 35 / 54

We can rewrite the budget constraint as: ( ) 1 t c = wl x 1 + τ Substitute into the utility function to get: (( ) ) 1 t U = u wl x, x, l 1 + τ Maximize utility with respect to x and l: u x = u c u l = ( 1 t 1 + τ ) wu c First FOC: no marginal benefits of consuming more x by reducing consumption of c Second FOC: marginal costs of supplying more l equals marginal benefits of consuming the resulting income 36 / 54

Notice that both utility and labor supply only depends on the combination 1 t 1+τ, not on t and τ separately = It does not matter whether taxes are levied through a tax on income (t > 0, τ = 0) or through a uniform tax on consumption (τ > 0, t = 0) = Statements such as We should shift the burden of taxation from income to consumption are largely nonsense (Can you think of instances in which this equivalence does not hold?) In the remainder of the Lectures, we typically assume either τ = 0 or t = 0 without loss of generality 37 / 54

Utility equivalence of different tax instruments We assume the government levies a proportional income tax t, a specific commodity tax τ, and a lump-sum tax T Q: Does it matter for utility which tax instrument is used to raise one unit of taxes? Representative individual with wage w supplies l units of labor: Before-tax income given by wl After-tax income given by (1 t)wl T After-tax income is spent on consumption goods c and x, and on a specific commodity tax τ x Utility is given by: U = u(c, x, l), u c, u x > 0, u l < 0 Budget constraint is given by: c = (1 t)wl T (1 + τ)x 38 / 54

Substitute budget constraint into the utility function to get: U = u((1 t)wl T (1 + τ)x, x, l) Still a function of l and x. We want to write utility as a function of tax instruments {t, τ, T } to determine their effects on utility. First-order conditions w.r.t. x and l are again given by: u x = u c u l = ( 1 t 1 + τ ) wu c These conditions imply equilibrium x and l as function of tax instruments: x = x(t, τ, T ) and l = l(t, τ, T ) Substitute back into utility function to get indirect utility the utility gained after the individual optimizes his behavior: v(t, τ, T ) u((1 t)wl T (1 + τ)x, x, l ) 39 / 54

The envelope theorem: because indirect utility is maximized w.r.t. x and l, partial derivatives w.r.t. x and l are zero Taking derivatives w.r.t. {T, t, τ} yields: v T dt = u c dt v t dt = u c wl dt v τ dτ = u c x dτ = The utility effects of raising the lump-sum tax by dt, the income tax by wl dt, or the commodity tax by x dτ are identical = In other words, individuals do not care through which tax instruments an additional unit of taxes is collected! They simply suffer, to an extent equal to their income loss times their marginal utility of consumption u c This result is sometimes referred to as Roy s Identity 40 / 54

Do at home: derive x, l, and v(t, τ, ) T ) for the specific utility function u(c, x, l) = c + ln x. Confirm the utility ( l 1+1/e 1+1/e equivalence of the different tax instruments by taking partial derivatives of the indirect utility w.r.t. {t, τ, T }. 41 / 54

Income and substitution effects of the income tax on labor supply While utility effects of different tax instruments are identical, the behavioral effects are not Indeed, the lump-sum tax T only has an income effect on labor supply; the income tax rate t has both an income effect and a substitution effect Income effect: intuitively, both T and t lower disposable income, thereby decreasing the consumption of commodities and leisure (higher labor supply) Substitution effect: the income tax t also raises the price of commodities in terms of leisure, leading to a substitution effect from commodities to leisure (lower labor supply) [if normal goods ] = the income effect of t on l is positive; the substitution effect is negative; the net effect is ambiguous 42 / 54

Labor supply: income and substitution effects Consumption cc Budget line: cc = 1 tt wwww TT TT Labor supply ll

Labor supply: income and substitution effects Consumption cc Budget line: cc = 1 tt wwww TT Indifference curves TT Labor supply ll

Labor supply: income and substitution effects Consumption cc Budget line: cc = 1 tt wwww TT Indifference curves TT Labor supply ll

Labor supply: income and substitution effects Consumption cc Budget line: cc = 1 tt wwww TT Indifference curves TT Labor supply ll

Labor supply: income and substitution effects Consumption cc cc = 1 tt wwww TT Equilibrium labor supply TT ll Labor supply ll

Labor supply: income and substitution effects Consumption cc cc = 1 tt wwww TT cc = 1 tt wwww TT New equilibrium TT ll ll Labor supply ll

Labor supply: income and substitution effects Consumption cc cc = 1 tt wwww TT Substitution effect cc = 1 tt wwww TT TT ll ll Labor supply ll Income effect

Labor supply: income and substitution effects Consumption cc cc = 1 tt wwww TT Substitution effect cc = 1 tt wwww TT substitution effect dominates income effect TT ll ll Labor supply ll Income effect

Labor supply: income and substitution effects Consumption cc cc = 1 tt wwww TT Substitution effect cc = 1 tt wwww TT Alternative scenario 1: Income effect dominates substitution effect TT ll ll Labor supply ll Income effect

Labor supply: income and substitution effects Consumption cc cc = 1 tt wwww TT Substitution effect cc = 1 tt wwww TT Alternative scenario 2: NO income effect TT ll ll Labor supply ll

Formally, we can use the Slutsky decomposition to decompose the total labor supply response to a change in income taxes dl dt into a substitution effect and an income effect: dl c dt dl dt = dlc dl + wl dt dt is the compensated change in labor supply: it represents the change in labor supply due to the change in the slope of the budget line is the income effect on labor supply: it represents the change in labor supply due to the shift of the budget line wl dl dt Note that only the substitution effect represents the labor supply effect of distorting prices! Q: We have shown that income taxes and lump-sum taxes differ in their labor supply effects. But we have also shown that income taxes and lump-sum taxes have equivalent utility effects. How can we explain this seeming paradox? 53 / 54

The net-of-tax rate elasticity of labor supply / taxable income As the course unfolds, we will often make use of the concept of net-of-tax rate elasticities. For example, the compensated net-of-tax rate elasticity of labor supply can be written as: e dlc 1 t = dlc 1 t d(1 t) l dt l If the net-of-tax rate (1 t) goes up by 1%, labor supply goes up by e% Instead of labor supply l, we will also often talk about taxable income z wl. Notice that the elasticity of taxable income is equal to the elasticity of labor supply: dz 1 t = wdl 1 t = d(1 t) z d(1 t) wl dl 1 t d(1 t) l 54 / 54