A Utility Function Explanation of the Empirical Behavior of Income Relative to International Reserves for Selected Economies

Similar documents
IMPACTS OF THE THREE TRILEMMA POLICIES ON INFLATION, GROWTH AND VOLATILITY FOR TEN SELECTED ASIAN AND PACIFIC COUNTRIES.

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

Discussion of Michael Klein s Capital Controls: Gates and Walls Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, September 2012

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. International Trade, Crowding Out, and Market Structure: Cournot Approach. James P.

On the Determinants of Exchange Rate Misalignments

Commodity price movements and monetary policy in Asia

Effectiveness of macroprudential and capital flow measures in Asia and the Pacific 1

Global Imbalances and Latin America: A Comment on Eichengreen and Park

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

ADB Economics Working Paper Series. Competition, Labor Intensity, and Specialization: Structural Changes in Postcrisis Asia

* + p t. i t. = r t. + a(p t

The Theory of Economic Growth

The Theory of Economic Growth

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: The Case of Oil Price Rise and Italy

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

A SIMULTANEOUS-EQUATION MODEL OF THE DETERMINANTS OF THE THAI BAHT/U.S. DOLLAR EXCHANGE RATE

Long-run Stability of Demand for Money in China with Consideration of Bilateral Currency Substitution

Exchange Rate Regimes and Trade Deficit A case of Pakistan

Is Currency Depreciation Expansionary? The Case of South Korea

Stock Prices, Foreign Exchange Reserves, and Interest Rates in Emerging and Developing Economies in Asia

Appendix: Analysis of Exchange Rates Pursuant to the Act

ECON 3010 Intermediate Macroeconomics Chapter 6

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Journal of Asian Economics xxx (2005) xxx xxx. Risk properties of AMU denominated Asian bonds. Junko Shimizu, Eiji Ogawa *

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

EU-ASEAN cooperation - key trade and investment statistics

An Empirical Analysis on the Relationship between Health Care Expenditures and Economic Growth in the European Union Countries

The Trilemma: Insights and Limitations

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Macroeconomics II. Growth. Recent phenomenon Great diversity of growth experiences across countries. Why do some countries grow and others not?

CRS Report for Congress

ABSTRACT. Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Policy with Income-sensitive Capital Flows. J.O.N. Perkins, University of Melbourne

When and How to Delegate? A Life Cycle Analysis of Financial Advice

J Ö N K Ö P I N G I N T E R N A T I O N A L B U S I N E S S S C H O O L JÖNKÖPING UNIVERSITY. A study of the Asian Financial Crisis

IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Policy cooperation, incomplete markets and risk sharing

CCBS Chief Economists Workshop May How Distinct are Financial Cycles from Business Cycles in Asia?

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Recent developments in the euro area suggest. What caused current account imbalances in euro area periphery countries?

Asian Economic and Financial Review MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION AND BANK LENDING IN SOUTH KOREA AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. Yu Hsing

National Income & Business Cycles

Asian Economic and Financial Review BANK CONCENTRATION AND ENTERPRISE BORROWING COST RISK: EVIDENCE FROM ASIAN MARKETS

Chapter 6. The Open Economy

The Evolving Role of Trade in Asia: Opening a New Chapter. Fall 2018 REO Background Paper

Volume 35, Issue 1. Yu Hsing Southeastern Louisiana University

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Chapter 5. Partial Equilibrium Analysis of Import Quota Liberalization: The Case of Textile Industry. ISHIDO Hikari. Introduction

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

Comments on Corporate leverage in emerging Asia

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

Are we there yet? Adjustment paths in response to Tariff shocks: a CGE Analysis.

Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis Fed, IGIER, CEPR and NBER October 2012

The Need for a Coordinated Industrial Strategy to Boost Pakistani Exports: Lessons from Asia

ME II, Prof. Dr. T. Wollmershäuser. Chapter 12 Saving, Capital Accumulation, and Output

E cient Minimum Wages

Growth and Ideas. Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017

Chapter 2 China s National Balance Sheet: Preparation and Analysis

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

Comment: Growing with Capital Controls like China

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Index. exchange rates, 104 5, net inflows, 100, 115, Bretton Woods system, 96 7 business cycles, 57

Suggested answers to Problem Set 5

ASIA EX JAPAN: NEITHER BOOM NOR DOOM

The International Business Academy in Conjunction with. International Journal of Business & Management Research. IJBMR ISSN

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: Oil Price Rise and Italy

What Will Happen When Foreigners Stop Lending to the United States?

Is Higher Volatility Associated with Lower Growth? Intranational Evidence from South Korea

Global Business Economics. Mark Crosby SEMBA International Economics

Regional Monetary Cooperation in East Asia against Asymmetric Responses to the US Dollar Depreciation 1)

Composition of Foreign Capital Inflows and Growth in India: An Empirical Analysis.

ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS OF THE AUSTRALIAN PROPERTY SECTOR USING INPUT-OUTPUT TABLES. YU SONG and CHUNLU LIU Deakin University

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Capital Flow Volatility and Contagion: A Focus on Asia

The Effect of Economic Policy Uncertainty in the US on the Stock Market Performance in Canada and Mexico

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

International Finance

Major Themes in International Economics + Review of Microeconomic Concepts

Yen and Yuan. The Impact of Exchange Rate Fluctuations on the Asian Economies. C. H. Kwan RIETI

ADB Economics Working Paper Series. Poverty Impact of the Economic Slowdown in Developing Asia: Some Scenarios

Answers to Questions: Chapter 7

The outbreak of the 2008 financial crisis led to a. Rue de la Banque No 53 December 2017

Introduction to Economics. MACROECONOMICS Chapter 6 International Economics

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

The Macroprudential Role of International Reserves

The Factors that affect shares Return in Amman Stock Market. Laith Akram Muflih AL Qudah

Asian Monetary Coordination and Global Imbalances

POST-CRISIS GLOBAL REBALANCING CONFERENCE ON GLOBALIZATION AND THE LAW OF THE SEA WASHINGTON DC, DEC 1-3, Barry Bosworth

Working Paper 2/2014 DRIVERS OF RESERVES ACCUMULATION IN THE SOUTH EAST ASIAN COUNTRIES. Min B. Shrestha 1 and Theresia A. Wansi 2.

Using the Relation between GINI Coefficient and Social Benefits as a Measure of the Optimality of Tax Policy

Asia-Pacific Trade Briefs: Hong Kong, China

Asian Regional Policy Coordination

What Are Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates?

Changing Trends and Investor Bases of Asian Bond Markets Sabyasachi Mitra, Asian Development Bank S. Ghon Rhee, University of Hawaii

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

Can global economic conditions explain low New Zealand inflation?

Global Imbalances and Structural Change in the United States

Why Corporate Governance is Important in APEC Economies

POLICY BRIEF. Resurgent Capital Flows to Developing Countries: Policies to Improve Their Impact

6 The Open Economy. This chapter:

Transcription:

Journal of Business & Economic Policy Vol. 5, No. 4, December 2018 doi:10.30845/jbep.v5n4p5 A Utility Function Explanation of the Empirical Behavior of Income Relative to International Reserves for Selected Economies Pook Carson Associate Professor Department of Business Management Salt Lake Community College USA James P. Gander Professor Emeritus Department of Economics University of Utah USA Abstract The purpose of this paper is to explore an economy-wide utility model to explain the empirical behavior of national income relative to international reserves for selected economies. The empirical behavior is taken as the observed optimal outcome from a macroeconomic general equilibrium model which is not specified here but presumed to exist based on the general literature covering the topic. The model uses an economy-wide preference (utility) function as its objective function of two variables, national income and international reserves. The empirical data consist of the ratio of income to reserves for a selected number of mature and developing economies over the time period 1970 to 2011. For mature economies, the ratio is trending upwards, while for the developing economies, the ratio is trending downwards. It is this phenomenon that we attempt to explain in terms of the relative strength of the utilities for income versus reserves. The policy implications are discussed briefly within the context of the existing literature on international reserves. JEL classification: C61; F3; F4 Keywords: Utility Function, Income, Reserves, Empirical Ratios 1. Introduction The purpose of this paper is to develop an a priori utility explanation of the actual empirical behavior of national income, Y(t), relative to the behavior of a nation s international reserves, R(t). The explanation will attempt to differentiate between the behavior of the income-reserve ratio, Y(t)/R(t), over time (in other words its dynamic behavior) for developing economies versus mature (or developed) economies. The essence of the utility explanation is an economy-wide utility function of the type U(Y(t), R(t)) which is shaped by cultural preferences, the details of which will be forthcoming. The utility explanation is presumed to operate within the context of an unspecified general macroeconomic optimization model which, in effect, would account for the empirical behavior of Y(t) and R(t) that we examine. We do not develop such a model here, for doing so would take us beyond the theme (or purpose) of the paper (see, for work on optimal reserve modeling, Alfaro and Kanczuk, 2009; Bar-Ilan, Marion, and Perry, 2007; and Costinot, Lorenzoni, and Werning, 2011). Our explanation, in effect, is an ex post reason for the observed empirical behavior of the income-reserve ratio. This explanation has value for it attempts to get at the utility foundation of income/reserves behavior and why it differs among economies. This value hopefully will add to our understanding of the recent surge in international reserves (see, for a discussion, Vujanovic, 2011). Much of the literature on the income-reserve ratio focuses on the need for self-insurance, but not particularly on the country-specific differences in Y/R ratios. Our model is designed to shed some light on these differences. 38

ISSN 2375-0766 (Print), 2375-0774 (Online) Center for Promoting Ideas, USA www.jbepnet.com The literature is very large and very current. Much of it is from the NBER, the OECD, and the IMF. It is concerned with reserves as self-insurance against sudden capital outflows, with the optimal level of reserves recognizing adjustment costs to sudden stop capital inflows (for example, when exports suddenly drop relative to imports), the opportunity cost (social cost) of holding reserves, the empirical determinants of reserves, the economic development role of reserves (the so-called Mercantilist effect), the policy issues related to imperfections in the current behavior of the IMF, the use of international reserves in managing a country s international debt, and probability models design to handle the optimal level of reserves under uncertainty. This is quite an array of topics, but it is not the purpose of this paper to survey this vast literature. For examples of surveys, see, Calvo, Izquierdo, and Loo-Kung (2012), Obstfeld, Shambaugh, and Taylor (2008, 2010), Moghadam (2010), and Vujanovic (2011). For an excellent set of references, see Jeanne (2007) and his model for determining the optimal level of reserves. In the next section, we develop the utility function model. Then, in the following section, we undertake an empirical examination of the Y/R ratios for several developing and mature economies covering the time period 1970 to 2011. By choice, South East Asian countries are used to represent developing economies and the mature economies are represented by the major traders in South East Asia (the USA, Germany, and Japan). The last section has a summary and conclusions. 2. The Utility Function Model The stock of international reserves, R(t), has four components: gold, special drawing rights, the IMF member s deposit, and foreign exchange holdings by the country s monetary authority. To simplify our explanation, we treat R(t) as homogenous financial capital and use it in aggregate form. The stock of reserves is essentially generated by a nation s exports of goods and services relative to its imports (in other words, by the current account in the balance of international payments). The surplus on the current account can have several different uses (as the above literature topics suggest), such as adding to a country s loanable funds supply via the banking system, or purchasing foreign bonds (like China does), or adding to its reserve account holdings within its own central bank or the IMF, or reducing its international debt. While these different uses have different implications with respect to a country s income (GDP), pursing these implications is beyond the scope of our paper, for we use aggregate reserves to focus on the utility explanation of the behavior of income and reserves and take its multiple uses as given. The utility function is given by U=U(Y(t), R(t)) and, as indicated earlier, it includes the country s flow variable, Y(t), and its asset variable, R(t). The use of Y or C (consumption) in an economy s U(.) is common. Our inclusion of an asset R in U(.) is an important design feature. The presumption is that the R (and its various unspecified uses) also creates utility much like Y does with its various unspecified components. Other assets may also create utility, but their inclusion would complicate the model and would go beyond the focus of the paper. Standard properties for U(Y(t), R(t)) are assumed. Let i index Y and j index R, so that the partial derivatives U i >0, U j >0, U ii <0, U jj <0, and U ij =U ji >0, given continuity. The utility function is assumed to be homogeneous to the first degree (for example, U = Y a R b, where coefficients a + b =1 and a>0 and b>0). These properties will be useful when examining the empirical behavior of the income/reserve ratios. 3. Empirical Analysis Country data on income and reserves are taken from the IMF. The reserves are in current US dollars. The income data are in the national currency which was converted to US dollars by the authors using year-end exchange rates contained in the data set. Both variables are in nominal values, but since a ratio Y/R is used, no real value conversion is needed. The countries selected are in two groups, developing economies in South-East Asia (Indonesia, South Korea, Thailand, Singapore, Malaysia, the Philippines, and China the order follows the order in the Figure 1) and mature economies that are the major trading partners with these economies (Japan, Germany, and the USA in Figure 2). 39

Journal of Business & Economic Policy Vol. 5, No. 4, December 2018 doi:10.30845/jbep.v5n4p5 40

ISSN 2375-0766 (Print), 2375-0774 (Online) Center for Promoting Ideas, USA www.jbepnet.com Figure 1 shows the time path of the Y/R ratio for the developing economies. While there exists volatility in the seven time series, since around 1982-1985 the trend is decidedly downward due to the fact that R is growing faster than Y. To give a sense of the magnitudes of the ratios observed, by order of the appearances in Figure 1, the ratios of Y/R range (from early periods to later) from about 55 to 5, 56 to 3, 24 to 2, 2 to 1, 9 to 2, 45 to 3, and 107 to 2 for China. This downward trend in the Y/R ratios is consistent with what others have observed (for example, Jeanne (2007) using the inverse, R/Y, shows an upward trend for emerging markets). On the other hand, for the mature economies in Figure 2, with the exception of Japan, the trend is decidedly upwards. For Japan, the time series trend is downwards. The ratios range (from the early to the later period) from 59 to 5 for Japan, 11 to 72 for Germany and 72 to 190 for the USA. These empirical results for mature countries are consistent with those shown by Vujanovic (2011). 41

Journal of Business & Economic Policy Vol. 5, No. 4, December 2018 doi:10.30845/jbep.v5n4p5 What is the economic explanation in terms of the utility function of these results? If b>a, this will result in a falling Y/R ratio over time. To see this, we use the two marginals of the utility function, MU(Y) and MU(R), to obtain stylistically, (b/a)(y*/r*)=k, where k is some given constant and Y*(t) and R*(t) are the optimal time paths. If b=a, then, with Y* and R* growing at the same rate, the ratio remains constant at k. With b>a, say, 2/3 and 1/3 respectively, then (b/a)=2 and the ratio Y*/R*<k, implying R* is growing faster than Y*, so the ratio Y/R is falling over time (the developing economy case). Alternatively, with b<a, the ratio Y*/R*>k, implying Y* is growing faster than R*, so the ratio Y/R is rising over time (the developed economy ex-japan case). For the developing economies, the results mean that they put relatively greater utility (welfare) value on reserves compared to national income. In terms of our model, conceptually, from the previous specification of U=Y a R b, if b>a, then R(t) is relatively more efficient (the elasticity with respect to U(.) is b) in generating utility compared to Y(t). So, while both Y and R can be increasing over time (albeit, at different rates), the ratio Y/R will be falling over time. It appears that such is the case for the developing economies. The opposite is the case for the mature economies ex-japan. The idea that countries hold more reserves relative to income because reserves are more efficient in producing utility still leaves open the question: Why are reserves relatively more efficient (relatively more satisfying) for developing economies? Alfaro and Kanczuk (2006) argue in their stochastic model that the optimal policy is to hold no reserves. Others, for example, Calvo, Izquierdo, and Loo-Kung (2012) and Jeanne (2007) take the position that reserves are needed to finance imports as insurance against a sudden fall in exports. There is some evidence for the insurance explanation in the data, since the Y/R ratio for the developing economies is lower than that for the developed countries. The developing economies are thus holding more insurance relative to income (Y) than the developed economies. Presumably, the developing economies benefit from such insurance to a greater extent than the developed economies. But the problem is that the developing nations are holding vastly more reserves over time, as their economies are growing. If their need for insurance were driven by their (small) size, we would expect this need to decline with growth (i.e., for Y/R to increase over time). This is not the case. An alternative explanation is that the higher reserves preferred by developing economies is driven by their reliance on exports, which increase along with income (Y). However, the time series in Figure 1 correspond to a period of growing domestic markets in all of these developing economies, particularly South Korea and China, suggesting limits to this explanation as well. Greater insight can be garnered by examining differences among the developed economies. Holding income constant, Germany s economy is fairly similar to that of the United States; yet Germans have consistently chosen a more conservative level of reserves, resulting in a much lower Y/R ratio. The case of Japan is even more dramatic, with a time-trend that is virtually equivalent (if less volatile) to its Asian neighbors. This trend is so different from the other developed economies that it is unlikely to be explained by variables other than differences in underlying utility. These facts suggest that culture is likely to play a larger role in shaping the utility derived from reserves than recognized in the literature. Differences in financial attitudes and cultural perspectives toward risk taking across economies and regions can dramatically alter the efficiency with which reserves produce utility. 4. Summary and Conclusions The empirical behavior of national income relative to international reserves was modeled by a utility function model. Fairly standard assumptions were used. The changing ratios over time are trending downwards for developing economies and upwards for mature economies, with the notable exception of Japan. These results are difficult to reconcile with common explanations in the literature, but are consistent with a utility model which allows cultural differences in preferences. The model was not intended to address specifically how policy outcomes (such as fiscal and monetary changes) are used to control ratios or why different utility functions exist across different types of economies (mature versus developing). The facts show that they do differ and the model does offer an avenue of explanation for the difference. 42

ISSN 2375-0766 (Print), 2375-0774 (Online) Center for Promoting Ideas, USA www.jbepnet.com 5. References Alfaro, L., Kanczuk, F. (2009). Optimal reserve management and sovereign debt. Journal of International Economics, 77, 23-36. Bar-Ilan, A., Marion, N., Perry, D. (2007). Drift control of international reserves. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 31, 3110-3137. Calvo, G., Izzquierdo, A., Loo-Kung, R. (2012). Optimal holdings of international reserves: Self-insurance against sudden stop. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 18219, July. Costinot, A., Lorenzoni, G., Werning, I. (2011). A theory of capital controls as dynamic terms-of-trade manipulation. National Bureau of Economic Research WorkingPaper 17680, December. Jeanne, O. (2007). International reserves in emerging market countries: Too much of a good thing? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 1-79. Obstfeld, M., Shambaugh, J., Taylor, A. (2008). Financial stability, the trilemma, and international reserves. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 14217, August. Obstfeld, M., Shambaugh, J., Taylor, A. (2010). Financial stability, the trilemma, and international reserves. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(2), 57-95. Moghadam, R. (2010). Reserve accumulation and international monetary stability. International Monetary Fund, prepared by the Strategy, Policy and Review Department, April, 1-35. Vujanovic, P. (2011). Understanding the recent surge in the accumulation of international reserves. OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 866, May, 1-28. 43