Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Similar documents
Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation

Altruism. Fang Yang. State University of New York at Albany. March Abstract

Australian. Homeownership: Sang-Wook. School of Economics. School of Business ISSN

Means-tested Age Pension and Homeownership: Is There a Link?

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Policy Reforms, Housing, and Wealth Inequality

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role

Household Saving, Financial Constraints, and the Current Account Balance in China

Welfare Analysis of Progressive Expenditure Taxation in Japan

The Budgetary and Welfare Effects of. Tax-Deferred Retirement Saving Accounts

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

Household Finance in China

Reforming the Social Security Earnings Cap: The Role of Endogenous Human Capital

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

A simple wealth model

The Macroeconomics of Universal Health Insurance Vouchers

Journal of Housing Economics

Social Security, Life Insurance and Annuities for Families

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings FESAMES 2009

Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy

Accounting for the Heterogeneity in Retirement. Wealth

Renting Vs Buying a Home: A Matter Of Wealth Accumulation or of Geographic Stability?

Wealth Inequality, Family Background, and Estate Taxation

Consumption Along the Life Cycle: How Different Is Housing?

Home Production and Social Security Reform

Entrepreneurship, Frictions and Wealth

Balance Sheet Recessions

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital

Social Security Reform in a Dynastic Life-Cycle Model with Endogenous Fertility

Saving During Retirement

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Discussion of Fertility, Social Mobility and Long-Run Inequality

Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk

The Implications of a Greying Japan for Public Policy.

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

How Well Does the Australian Aged Pension Provide Social Insurance?

Revisiting Tax on Top Income

Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives

Directory. The Value of Life and the Rise in Health Spending p.1/34

Prof. J. Sachs May 26, 2016 FIRST DRAFT COMMENTS WELCOME PLEASE QUOTE ONLY WITH PERMISSION

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GENDER, MARRIAGE, AND LIFE EXPECTANCY. Margherita Borella Mariacristina De Nardi Fang Yang

Social Security Reform in a Dynastic Life-Cycle Model with Endogenous Fertility

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WEALTH INEQUALITY, FAMILY BACKGROUND, AND ESTATE TAXATION. Mariacristina De Nardi Fang Yang

Health Insurance Reform: The impact of a Medicare Buy-In

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives

Financing National Health Insurance: Challenge of Fast Population Aging

Adverse Selection in the Annuity Market and the Role for Social Security

Income Differences and Health Care Expenditures over the Life Cycle

Intergenerational Policy and the Measurement of the Tax Incidence of Unfunded Liabilities

Retirement, Saving, Benefit Claiming and Solvency Under A Partial System of Voluntary Personal Accounts

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Efficient Bailouts? Javier Bianchi. Wisconsin & NYU

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Can Removing the Tax Cap Save Social Security?

Optimal portfolio choice with health-contingent income products: The value of life care annuities

The Impact of Personal Bankruptcy Law on Entrepreneurship

Public Pension Reform in Japan

Policy Uncertainty and the Cost of Delaying Reform: A case of aging Japan

Old, Sick Alone, and Poor: A Welfare Analysis of Old-Age Social Insurance Programs

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach. QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21

Accounting for non-annuitization

Health Care Reform or Labor Market Reform? A Quantitative Analysis of the Affordable Care Act

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011

DIFFERENTIAL MORTALITY, UNCERTAIN MEDICAL EXPENSES, AND THE SAVING OF ELDERLY SINGLES

Final Exam Solutions

Movements on the Price of Houses

The Effects of Financing Rules in Pay-As-You-Go Pension Systems on the Life and the Business Cycle

Deflation, Credit Collapse and Great Depressions. Enrique G. Mendoza

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Financing National Health Insurance: Challenge of Fast Population Aging

Intervivos Transfers and Bequests in three OECD Countries 1.

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

The Japanese saving rate between 1960 and 2000: productivity, policy changes, and demographics

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Fiscal Cost of Demographic Transition in Japan

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Life Cycle Responses to Health Insurance Status

Elimination of Social Security in a Dynastic Framework

ARTICLE IN PRESS. JID:YREDY AID:433 /FLA [m3g; v 1.49; Prn:17/07/2008; 9:53] P.1 (1-21) Review of Economic Dynamics ( )

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

1 Dynamic programming

Age, Luck, and Inheritance

Retirement Saving, Annuity Markets, and Lifecycle Modeling. James Poterba 10 July 2008

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings

Transcription:

Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales March 2009

Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several studies analyzing the size and the effect of parental transfers to children, both intervivos transfers to younger children, and bequests. Borrowing constraints may induce the parents to transfer resources to constrained children (who tend to be younger) rather than leaving it for later bequests.

Motivation Since Becker (1974), several studies analyzing the size and the effect of parental transfers to children, both intervivos transfers to younger children, and bequests. Borrowing constraints may induce the parents to transfer resources to constrained children (who tend to be younger) rather than leaving it for later bequests. The topic is important and deserves our attention.

Motivation Since Becker (1974), several studies analyzing the size and the effect of parental transfers to children, both intervivos transfers to younger children, and bequests. Borrowing constraints may induce the parents to transfer resources to constrained children (who tend to be younger) rather than leaving it for later bequests. The topic is important and deserves our attention.... by an anonymous referee who rejected the paper

Question We analyse intergenerational transfer of wealth over the lifecycle in the US vs. Korea using a standard lifecycle model with different transfer motives Explore the aggregate, distributional, and welfare impact of borrowing constraint The role of borrowing constraint in accounting for cross-country differences in wealth accumulation & timing of transfer Document counter-factual policy experiments in the light of borrowing constraint

Outline Some empirical evidence (rough data, no estimation) Benchmark lifecycle model with different transfer motives - bequest vs. intervivos transfer Simulation results Policy experiments

Age-Wealth Profiles in US vs. Korea 12 10 US (PSID 2001) Korea (KLIPS 1999 2005) Average Income = 1 8 6 4 2 0 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 Age Figure 2.1 Age-profile of Wealth Accumulation (US vs Korea)

Aggregate Intervivos Transfer Table: Aggregate Intervivos Transfer - US, Korea Author Source Percentage TR TR Y Altonji et al. PSID 23% $1810 5.2% (1997) (1988) (received) McGarry HRS 29% $3013 7.5% (1999) (1992) (gave) Kim et al. KLIPS 21% $3273 15.8% (2004) (2002) (received)

Age-Transfer Distribution Table: Age-Transfer Distribution - US, Korea Age Groups -29 30-34 35-39 40-44 45-49 Fraction of households receiving transfers US 29.5% 22.6% 19.1% 16.5% 11.8% Korea 26.6% 28.6% 27.3% 19.1% 13.7% Transfer as a fraction of average household income US 4.3% 5.6% 6.5% 6.7% 4.8% Korea 5.2% 14.7% 9.9% 6.2% 9.2% Transfer as a fraction of average cohort income US 5.6% 5.2% 5.2% 5.2% 3.5% Korea 13.3% 14.0% 8.3% 5.5% 7.7%

Evidence of Borrowing Constraint? Table: Mortgage-GDP ratio and Loan-to-value ratios - US, Korea Year 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Outstanding Mortgage-to-GDP Ratio US 53% 52% 54% 56% 55% Korea 10% 11% 12% 12% 13% Loan-to-value ratio US 78% 80% 80% 78% 79% Korea 25% 26% 28% 28% 33%

Summarizing... Age-wealth profile shows that 1 wealth peaks earlier and decumulates faster after the peak in Korea than in the United States 2 younger Korean households hold more wealth than the corresponding cohorts in the United States, while for older households, the relation is reversed.

Summarizing... Age-transfer profile shows that 1 on average, more households in Korea receive positive parental transfers than in the United States 2 the relative importance of transfer income is larger for Korean households, especially in the younger cohorts aged less than 35. The degree of credit constraint in Korea is larger as evidenced from the size of the mortgage market and the down-payment requirements.

Main features Quantitative general equilibrium lifecycle model One-sided altruism (parent children) warm-glow bequest motive during retirement (parents aged 70-85 vs. children aged 40-55) altruistic intervivos transfer prior to retirement (parents aged 55-70 vs. children aged 25-40) Uninsurable labor income, uncertain lifetime (mortality risk)

Demographics & Technology 1 period in the model corresponds to 5 years. Agents enter working life at 25(j = 1), retire at 65(j = 9), live at most until 80(J = 12). Retired agents face mortality risk, upon death agents leave bequest, equally re-distributed to agents (aged 40-55) s j : exogenously given survival probability at age j + 1 conditional on being alive at age j. Final goods produced can be consumed (C), invested (I ) or spent by government (G).

Intergenerational Transfers INTERGENERATIONAL TRANSFERS Parents Work Retire j = 7, 8, 9 j = 10,11,12 Bequest Children Intervivos transfer j = 1, 2, 3 j = 4, 5, 6 Work Work

Preferences CRRA utility function U(c j ) = c1 σ j 1 σ Warm-glow bequest motive, De Nardi (2004). ϕ(q) = ϕ 1 [ 1 + q ϕ 2 ] 1 σ Intervivos transfer motivated by altruism parents care about children s utility with discount factor γ < 1.

Labor Productivity Exogenous age-efficiency profile ɛ j + stochastic productivity shocks y j (Markov process) First period productivity shock is inherited from parents according to a transition function Q yh. Afterwards, producvitity evolves according to transition function Q y. Total productivity given by ɛ j y j, wage rate given by ω.

Market Arrangements Working agents can borrow upto some fraction of current period labor income. Agents in the early stages of lifecycle (j = 1, 2, 3) can also partially collaterialize parental assets. a j+1 κ 1 ωɛ j y j I j=1,2,3 κ 2 a 1 j+6 j = 1,..., 9 Retired households cannot borrow. a j+1 0 j = 10,..., 12

Government Re-distribution of bequest to children in periods j = 4, 5, 6. j=10,11,12 T = q m (dx) (1) m (dx) j=4,5,6 Social security benefit b m (dx) = τ ss j=10,11,12 j=1,...,9 Constant government expenditure from tax revenues. ωɛy m (dx) (2) τ c C + τ k rk = G (3)

Household Recursive Problem : Retired Parents (j = 10, 11, 12) V (j, a) = max c,a [ U(c) + sβv (j + 1, a ) + (1 s)ϕ(q) ] (4) subject to (1 + τ c )c + a (1 + r(1 τ k ))a + b c 0 q = a 0

Household Recursive Problem : Children ( j = 4, 5, 6) V ( j, ã, ỹ) = max c,ã [ U( c) + βev ( j + 1, ã, ỹ ) ] (5) subject to (1 + τ c ) c + ã (1 τ ss )ωɛỹ + (1 + r(1 τ k ))ã + T c 0 ã κ 1 ωɛỹ

Household Recursive Problem : Parents at (j = 7, 8, 9) V (j, a, y, ã, ỹ) = max c,a,tr U(c) + γu( c) + I j=7,8βev (j + 1, a, y, ã, ỹ ) +I j=9 βv (j + 1, a ) subject to (6) (1 + τ c )c + tr + a (1 τ ss )ωɛy + (1 + r(1 τ k ))a c 0 a κ 1 ωɛy

Household Recursive Problem : Children at ( j = 1, 2, 3) V ( j, a, y, ã, ỹ) = max c,ã U( c) + I j=1,2 βev ( j + 1, a, y, ã, ỹ ) +I j=3 βev ( j + 1, ã, ỹ ) subject to (7) (1 + τ c ) c + ã (1 τ ss )ωɛỹ + (1 + r(1 τ k ))ã + tr c 0 ã κ 1 ωɛỹ κ 2 a

Stationary Equilibrium government policy arrangements {T, G, τ SS, τ c, τ k } prices {r, w} value functions V (x) allotions c(x), a (x), tr(x) time-invariant distribution of agents, m (x), over the state variables x = {j, a, y, ã, ỹ} aggregate quantities {Y, C, K, L}

Stationary Equilibrium the functions V (x), c(x), a (x), tr(x) solve the dynamic maximization problem of the households. factor prices are equal to their marginal products: r = F K (K, L) δ (8) w = F L (K, L) (9) the government policy satisfies (1), (2), (3). m is the invariant distribution of households over the state variables for this economy. all markets clear.

Common Parameter Definition and Values Table: Common Parameter Definition and Values Parameters Definition Values σ Risk-aversion coefficient 1.5 α Capital income share 0.237 δ Depreciation rate 0.042 φ 1 Bequest parameter -9.5 φ 2 Bequest parameter 11.6 b Replacement ratio 0.4 τ c Consumption tax rate 0.05 ρ Persistence of income process 0.85

Country-specific Parameter Definition and Values Table: Country-Specific Parameter Definition and Values Parameters US Korea κ 1 0.75 0.25 κ 2 0.0 0.0 σy 2 0.30 0.07 τ ss 9.0% 12.4% τ k 50.2% 13.0%

Parameters to match given set of targets Table: Parameters to match given set of targets Parameters Definition US Korea β Discount factor 0.982 0.943 γ Pure altruism parameter 0.155 0.385

US Table: Summary Statistics of Benchmark Simulation - US Variable Benchmark Data Capital output ratio 3.187 3.173 Transfer-to-bequest ratio 0.27 0.28 Average Wealth 25-40 0.50 0.87 40-55 4.95 3.95 55-70 9.51 8.94 70-85 7.13 8.13

US Table: Summary Statistics of Benchmark Simulation - US Variable Benchmark Data Average flow of bequest (% of GDP) 1.6% 2.6% Transfer to 25-30 (% of GDP) 0.54% 4.3% Transfer to 30-35 (% of GDP) 1.94% 5.6% Transfer to 35-40 (% of GDP) 2.66% 6.5% Gini (wealth) 0.75 0.78

Korea Table: Summary Statistics of Benchmark Simulation - Korea Variable Benchmark Data Capital output ratio 2.455 2.448 Transfer-to-bequest ratio 0.904 0.91 Average Wealth 25-40 0.70 2.74 40-55 4.68 5.33 55-70 8.21 5.97 70-85 4.32 4.32

Korea Table: Summary Statistics of Benchmark Simulation - Korea Variable Benchmark Data Average flow of bequest (% of GDP) 1.2% 1.9% Transfer to 25-30 (% of GDP) 1.97% 5.2% Transfer to 30-35 (% of GDP) 3.17% 14.7% Transfer to 35-40 (% of GDP) 3.70% 9.9% Gini (wealth) 0.63 0.66

Table: Tightening Borrowing Constraint - US Parameter (κ 1 = 0.75) (κ 1 = 0.25) Capital output ratio 3.187 3.206 Transfer-to-bequest ratio 0.27 0.31 Average Wealth 25-40 100.0 138.2 40-55 100.0 104.6 55-70 100.0 99.4 70-85 100.0 98.0 T 100.0 96.2 tr 1 100.0 184.9 tr 2 100.0 105.7 tr 3 100.0 97.4 Welfare 100.0 99.3 Gini 0.75 0.706

Table: Relaxing Borrowing Constraint - Korea Parameter (κ 1 = 0.25) (κ 1 = 0.75) Capital output ratio 2.455 2.445 Transfer-to-bequest ratio 0.91 0.934 Average Wealth 25-40 100.0 85.8 40-55 100.0 98.5 55-70 100.0 102.0 70-85 100.0 104.7 T 100.0 105.9 tr 1 100.0 91.9 tr 2 100.0 108.1 tr 3 100.0 119.9 Welfare 100.0 99.8 Gini 0.63 0.663

Table: Parental Asset Collateralization - US Parameter (κ 2 = 0) (κ 2 = 0.25) Capital output ratio 3.187 3.126 Transfer-to-bequest ratio 0.27 0.262 Average Wealth 25-40 100.0 93.4 40-55 100.0 97.6 55-70 100.0 97.5 70-85 100.0 98.3 T 100.0 97.4 tr 1 100.0 82.8 tr 2 100.0 93.7 tr 3 100.0 97.4 Welfare 100.0 100.1 Gini 0.75 0.753

Table: Parental Asset Collateralization - Korea Parameter (κ 2 = 0) (κ 2 = 0.25) Capital output ratio 2.455 2.448 Transfer-to-bequest ratio 0.91 0.929 Average Wealth 25-40 100.0 90.6 40-55 100.0 99.5 55-70 100.0 101.0 70-85 100.0 101.8 T 100.0 102.2 tr 1 100.0 76.0 tr 2 100.0 108.7 tr 3 100.0 117.3 Welfare 100.0 99.9 Gini 0.63 0.644

Conclusion Life-cycle model with intergenerational linkages to study wealth transfers between parents and children. While the parents are of working age, the utility of the children s consumption enters the utility of the parents. When parents die, they leave bequests, and have an (exogenous) warm-glow utility from leaving a bequest. Higher borrowing constraints (that prevent children from borrowing to smooth their consumption) tend to generate larger transfers early in life (relative to bequests). This matches the empirical evidence from Korea (a stricter constraints country) and the US. We also look how transfers are impacted by allowing children to use parental wealth as a collateral to borrow.

Extensions Better calibration of Korean data Incorporate two-sided altruism (children supporting elderly parents) Incorporate human capital investment decision (and its interaction with intervivos transfer)