A Non-Normal Principal Components Model for Security Returns

Similar documents
Chapter 6 Simple Correlation and

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

Enhancing the Practical Usefulness of a Markowitz Optimal Portfolio by Controlling a Market Factor in Correlation between Stocks

Market Risk Analysis Volume I

Some Characteristics of Data

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

Fitting financial time series returns distributions: a mixture normality approach

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

The mathematical model of portfolio optimal size (Tehran exchange market)

The Fallacy of Large Numbers and A Defense of Diversified Active Managers

Long Run Stock Returns after Corporate Events Revisited. Hendrik Bessembinder. W.P. Carey School of Business. Arizona State University.

starting on 5/1/1953 up until 2/1/2017.

University of California Berkeley

IDIOSYNCRATIC RISK AND AUSTRALIAN EQUITY RETURNS

The Fallacy of Large Numbers

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

Simple Descriptive Statistics

Exploring Data and Graphics

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 109 ( 2014 ) Yigit Bora Senyigit *, Yusuf Ag

APPLYING MULTIVARIATE

Moments and Measures of Skewness and Kurtosis

Chapter 3. Descriptive Measures. Copyright 2016, 2012, 2008 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 3, Slide 1

STATISTICAL ANALYSIS OF HIGH FREQUENCY FINANCIAL TIME SERIES: INDIVIDUAL AND COLLECTIVE STOCK DYNAMICS

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region*

Numerical Descriptions of Data

Some estimates of the height of the podium

Traditional Optimization is Not Optimal for Leverage-Averse Investors

DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION

Contents Part I Descriptive Statistics 1 Introduction and Framework Population, Sample, and Observations Variables Quali

Chapter 4. The Normal Distribution

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

ROM Simulation with Exact Means, Covariances, and Multivariate Skewness

Multifactor rules-based portfolios portfolios

ARCH Models and Financial Applications

Does Portfolio Theory Work During Financial Crises?

Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds. Kevin C.H. Chiang*

Appendix A (Pornprasertmanit & Little, in press) Mathematical Proof

Basic Procedure for Histograms

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright

Introduction to Computational Finance and Financial Econometrics Descriptive Statistics

Risk and Return. Nicole Höhling, Introduction. Definitions. Types of risk and beta

Modeling Volatility Risk in Equity Options: a Cross-sectional approach

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 2 Summer 1997 AN ANALYSIS OF VALUE LINE S ABILITY TO FORECAST LONG-RUN RETURNS

2 Exploring Univariate Data

Testing Capital Asset Pricing Model on KSE Stocks Salman Ahmed Shaikh

Tuomo Lampinen Silicon Cloud Technologies LLC

Generalized Dynamic Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering the Market Volatility Shocks

The Impact of Macroeconomic Uncertainty on Commercial Bank Lending Behavior in Barbados. Ryan Bynoe. Draft. Abstract

1 Describing Distributions with numbers

Volatility Lessons Eugene F. Fama a and Kenneth R. French b, Stock returns are volatile. For July 1963 to December 2016 (henceforth ) the

Lecture 6: Non Normal Distributions

Portfolio Construction Research by

Liquidity skewness premium

Maximization of utility and portfolio selection models

Math 227 Elementary Statistics. Bluman 5 th edition

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

STAT 157 HW1 Solutions

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Global Journal of Finance and Banking Issues Vol. 5. No Manu Sharma & Rajnish Aggarwal PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS OF HEDGE FUND INDICES

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Table of Contents. New to the Second Edition... Chapter 1: Introduction : Social Research...

Applied Macro Finance

Concentration and Stock Returns: Australian Evidence

Understanding and Controlling High Factor Exposures of Robust Portfolios

The Response of Asset Prices to Unconventional Monetary Policy

Module Tag PSY_P2_M 7. PAPER No.2: QUANTITATIVE METHODS MODULE No.7: NORMAL DISTRIBUTION

STAT 113 Variability

Applied Macro Finance

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

Minimizing Timing Luck with Portfolio Tranching The Difference Between Hired and Fired

Equilibrium Asset Pricing: With Non-Gaussian Factors and Exponential Utilities

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Mechanics of minimum variance investment approach

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

ELEMENTS OF MATRIX MATHEMATICS

DETERMINANTS OF IMPLIED VOLATILITY MOVEMENTS IN INDIVIDUAL EQUITY OPTIONS CHRISTOPHER G. ANGELO. Presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School of

Frequency Distribution and Summary Statistics

Chapter 3. Numerical Descriptive Measures. Copyright 2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. Chapter 3, Slide 1

Washington University Fall Economics 487

Applying Independent Component Analysis to Factor Model in Finance

Fundamentals of Statistics

STATISTICAL DISTRIBUTIONS AND THE CALCULATOR

Risk Control of Mean-Reversion Time in Statistical Arbitrage,

Global Currency Hedging

appstats5.notebook September 07, 2016 Chapter 5

Quantitative Measure. February Axioma Research Team

Image analysis of malign melanoma: Waveles and svd

(High Dividend) Maximum Upside Volatility Indices. Financial Index Engineering for Structured Products

THE PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIVERSITY SCHREYER HONORS COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE

Chapter 15: Sampling distributions

One COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. Performance PART

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

Hitotsubashi ICS-FS Working Paper Series. A method for risk parity/budgeting portfolio based on Gram-Schmidt orthonormalization

I. Return Calculations (20 pts, 4 points each)

Stochastic Portfolio Theory Optimization and the Origin of Rule-Based Investing.

Subject CS1 Actuarial Statistics 1 Core Principles. Syllabus. for the 2019 exams. 1 June 2018

The Fundamental Law of Mismanagement

Transcription:

A Non-Normal Principal Components Model for Security Returns Sander Gerber Babak Javid Harry Markowitz Paul Sargen David Starer February 21, 219 Abstract We introduce a principal components model for securities returns. The components are non-normal, exhibiting significant skewness and kurtosis. The model can explain a large proportion of the variance of the securities returns with only one or two components. Third and higher-order components individually contribute so little that they can be considered to be noise terms. 1 Introduction In this paper, we propose a non-normal principal component model of the stock market. We create the model from a statistical study of a broad cross-section of approximately 5, US equities daily for 2 years. In our analysis, we find that only a small number of components can explain a significant amount of the variance of the securities return. Generally, third and higher-order components (essentially, the idiosyncratic terms) individually contribute so little to the variance that they can be considered to be noise terms. Importantly, we find that neither the significant components nor the idiosyncratic terms are normally distributed. Both sets exhibit significant skewness and kurtosis. Therefore, traditional models based on normal distributions are not fully descriptive of security returns. They can neither represent the extreme movements and comovements that security returns often exhibit, nor the low-level economically insignificant noise that security returns also often exhibit. However, these characteristics can be represented by the model presented in this paper. The finding of non-normality implies that meaningful security analysis requires statistical measures (1) that are insensitive to extreme moves, (2) that are also not influenced by small movements that may be noise, but (3) that still capture information in movements when such movements are meaningful. In Gerber et al. [219], we introduced the Gerber statistic (GS), which is a robust measure of correlation that satisfies all three of these requirements. 1

Precursors Portfolio construction [Markowitz, 1952, 1959] relies heavily on the availability of the matrix of covariances between securities returns. Often the sample covariance matrix is used as an estimate for the actual covariance matrix. But as early as Sharpe [1963], it has been known that a single factor approximation of this matrix leads to portfolios that outperform those constructed from the sample covariance matrix. Factor models originated with Spearman [194], who showed that one can reduce the dimension of a model by expressing the model variables as linear combinations of underlying common factors plus random idiosyncratic terms. Quantitative analysts have embraced this methodology, and factor models for security returns now abound. These models range from the early single factor model of Sharpe [1963], through the three and more factor models of Fama and French [1992, 1993], past the multifactor model of Rosenberg and Maranthe [1976], to modern models using tens or even hundreds of quantitative and categorical explanatory variables. This diversity in models is possible because of an important property of factor analysis: The factors and the factor loadings are not unique. That is, the factors can be rotated using any orthonormal matrix and the model remains identical. Therefore, in the abstract, any model can be expressed as a rotated version of any other model. Nevertheless, despite the numerous studies of these factors, we are unaware of research focused on the statistical distributions of the factors themselves. As described by Cont [21], a study by Laloux et al. [2] showed that principal components, apart from the ones corresponding to the largest few eigenvalues, do not seem to contain any information: in fact, their marginal distribution closely resembles the spectral distribution of a positive symmetric matrix with random entries whose distribution is the most random possible i.e., entropy maximizing. These results strongly question the validity of the use of the sample covariance matrix as an input for portfolio optimization... and support the rationale behind factor models... where the correlations between a large number of assets are represented through a small number of factors. We will use such a low-order principal component model, but will examine in more detail the statistics of the principal components. 2 Theory Our objective is to examine the characteristics of securities returns through the lens of a factor model. The structure of the model follows the general form r tj = K f tk x jk + ε tj (1) k=1 where x jk is the exposure of security j to a component k, f tk is the return of component k for time period t, and ε tj is an idiosyncratic or noise term. The f tk terms can be considered to be the drivers of the securities returns. With obvious notation, Equation (1) in matrix form is R = F X + E (2) 2

The model in Equations (1) and (2) is extremely versatile and includes factor models, smart-beta models, econometric models, time series models, statistical models, and many others as special cases. For example, in the case of a factor model, the components could be financial statement data such as earnings yield, dividend yield, and so on. Here, x jk would represent the financial data itself (centered and scaled to a standard deviation of one across the investment universe) and f tk would represent the return obtained in period t from a one-standard deviation exposure to factor k. The model places no restriction on whether any of the returns should be raw, excess, or active. The model can operate in several modes. For example, with the model in an identification mode, the exposures and security returns are assumed to be known, and the returns to the factors are found by linear or generalized regression. With the model in a prediction or data generating mode, the f tk are assumed to be known, the ε tj are replaced by their expected values of zero, and the security returns r tj are computed as linear combinations of the component returns f tk. We can use the model in the data identification mode to gain a better understanding of market characteristics. For this purpose, we perform principal component analysis on a broad range of stocks to find the statistical distributions of important components. Principal Component Analysis (PCA) [Pearson, 191, Hotelling, 1933] produces a parsimonious summary of data in terms of orthogonal sets of standardized linear combinations of the original data. Consider again the return matrix R whose columns represent different securities and whose rows represent different time intervals. We remove the mean of each column of R to obtain the centered return matrix R c. The sample covariance matrix of the returns is then C = 1 M 1 R c R c, where M is the number of time samples. The singular value decomposition (SVD) [Golub and Van Loan, 213] of R c is R c = W TOT S TOT X TOT where W TOT and X TOT are unitary matrices (i.e., matrices whose inverses equal their conjugate transposes) and S TOT is a diagonal matrix whose elements s k ; k = 1,..., K are the singular values of R c. The singular values are non-negative real numbers. In terms of the singular value decomposition, the sample covariance matrix is C = 1 M 1 X TOTS TOT W TOTW TOT S TOT X TOT = 1 M 1 X TOTS 2 TOTX TOT, which can be rearranged to give ( ) 1 CX TOT = X TOT M 1 S2 TOT. 3

The latter expression is the eigendecomposition of the covariance matrix. Therefore, the singular values are related to the eigenvalues λ k ; k = 1,..., K, of the sample covariance C by the identity λ k = 1 M 1 s2 k. Each eigenvalue is equal to the variance of its respective principal component. Letting W TOT S TOT = F TOT, the centered return matrix R c can be written in the principal component form R c = F TOT X TOT (3) where the matrix F TOT (called the score) has columns that are mutually orthogonal. The matrix X TOT is a rotation matrix called the coefficient or loading matrix. Importantly, each column of F TOT is called a principal component and can be considered to be a time series. The centered return matrix R c, therefore, is a linear combination of mutually orthogonal time series. These principal components are entirely analogous to factor return time series. Equation (3) is an identity; that is, the return matrix on the left hand side is exactly equal to the decomposition on the right hand side. If, however, we consider a small number of principal components (say m components) to describe the data with sufficient accuracy, we can categorize the remaining K m components as noise. Accordingly, we can partition F TOT and X TOT into signal and noise parts as follows: ] R c = [ F SIG F NOISE ] [ X SIG X NOISE = F SIG X SIG + E (4) where E = F NOISE X NOISE is a noise matrix, and can be considered to be the idiosyncratic part of the decomposition. That is, the entry in the t-th row and the j-th column of E is the idiosyncratic return of the j-th security over interval t. Note the direct correspondence between the representations in Equation (4) and (2). Making use of the decomposition of R c into its signal and noise components, and the properties of the unitary matrices, we find that the covariance matrix is C = X SIG Λ SIG X SIG + X NOISE Λ NOISE X NOISE, = C SIG + C NOISE, where Λ SIG and Λ NOISE are diagonal matrices containing the eigenvalues of the signal and noise parts, respectively. Note that Λ SIG is an m m matrix. In particular, if m = 1, it is a scalar. Notice that the noise covariance matrix X NOISE Λ NOISE X NOISE is not diagonal. Therefore, the idiosyncratic terms are not orthogonal, but are mutually correlated. 3 Empirical Results In our empirical tests, we used twenty years of daily returns from approximately 5, US stocks. We truncated the absolute value of returns to 3% to prevent our results being unduly influenced by outliers. We separated the period from the beginning of 1998 to the 4

end of 217 into ten non-overlapping two-year intervals. For each interval we performed 1, repetitions of the following test. In each test, we chose 1 stocks randomly with replacement from the available universe. For each two-year sample of 1 stocks, we formed a centered return matrix R c as described above, and computed the principal component score matrix F and loading matrix X. Recall that the columns of F represent orthogonal time series. The first column is the vector that best explains all columns of R c. The second column of F is the vector that is orthogonal to the first column, and best explains the remainder of the variance in R c. Similarly, for n > 1, the nth column of F is the one that is orthogonal to all preceding n 1 columns and best explains the remaining variance in R c. Table 1 lists the summary statistics (pooled over all two-year periods and all experiments) of the variance explained by the first ten principal components. This shows that the median variance explained by the first two principal components (PC1 and PC2) are 12.8% and 7.4%, respectively. Beyond the third principal component, the variance explained falls below 5%. min Q1 med Q3 max PC1 5.56 11.9 12.82 15.75 37.61 PC2 3.2 6.7 7.44 9.6 19.54 PC3 2.51 4.73 5.53 6.55 12.74 PC4 2.21 4.2 4.58 5.24 1.8 PC5 2.11 3.53 3.97 4.44 7.91 PC6 1.95 3.17 3.52 3.89 6.24 PC7 1.61 2.86 3.18 3.49 5.66 PC8 1.53 2.62 2.92 3.18 4.56 PC9 1.35 2.41 2.69 2.91 4.25 PC1 1.32 2.23 2.5 2.7 3.87 Table 1: Pooled Summary Statistics of Variance Explained by the First 1 Principal Components 5

Figure 1 gives a graphical representation of the data summarized in Table 1. From it, we see again that the first component explains the most variance in the returns. In many cases, the first component explains more than 3% of the variance in the returns. Using a 1% cutoff for significance, we believe that the returns can be explained by a single-factor model; i.e., a model using only the first principal component. 1 2 3 PC1 PC2 PC3 PC4 PC5 PC6 PC7 PC8 PC9 PC1 Principal Component Boxplots of Variance Explained by Pooled Principal Components Figure 1: Box Plots of Variance Explained by the First 1 Principal Components 6

The variance explained by the principal components varies by time period. Table 2 shows the median variance explained by the first five principal components for the ten twoyear periods from the beginning of 1998 to the end of 217. Naturally, the first principal component always explains more variance than the other components. However, it is clear that in the 28 29 period, PC1 explains more variance than other times, and much more than is explained by other components at the same time. This, of course, corresponds to a period in which stock returns were highly correlated. Thus, a single component explains stock returns, and that single component is the principal component analog of the market. PC1 PC2 PC3 PC4 PC5 1998 1999 8.76 6.9 5.65 4.8 4.17 2 21 12.15 6.54 4.9 4.18 3.75 22 23 12.22 8.28 5.91 4.82 4.11 24 25 11.21 8.49 6.36 5.2 4.28 26 27 13.91 8.49 5.97 4.63 3.84 28 29 26.91 5.3 4.18 3.6 3.17 21 211 24.7 9. 5.43 4.7 3.36 212 213 12.35 9.13 6.78 5.36 4.42 214 215 13.17 6.77 5.42 4.71 4.17 216 217 11.96 6.75 5.38 4.65 4.12 Table 2: Median Variance Explained by First Five Principal Components over Time. 7

Figure 2 shows histograms of the statistics of the first principal component for each of the 1, experiments conducted for 1 companies for every two-year period from 1998 to 2. 1. The top panel of the figure shows the variance explained in each experiment. The variance explained is skewed left with a median of about 8.5%. 2. The second panel shows the standard deviation of the first principal component. The distributional shape of the standard deviations is not clear, but lie in the range of 9% to 14%. 3. The third panel shows the skewness of the first component. This is clearly bimodal. The reason for the bimodality is that principal components are unique only up to a change of sign. Therefore, the sign of all odd moments is indeterminate. 4. The bottom panel shows the kurtosis of the first principal component. A normal distribution has a kurtosis of 3. Here, we see that in the vast majority of cases, the kurtosis is greater than 3, and the distributions are therefore leptokurtic. Figures 2 through 11 show the histograms for all two-year periods studied. In each figure, the layout is the same as that described above. The ambiguity in the signs of the principal components is an important issue when one tries to compute statistics of these components. We have tried to resolve the ambiguity for the first principal component at least. We believe that the first principal component represents an estimate of the market. Therefore, this component should be positively correlated with a broad market index. Accordingly, we computed the correlation between the Russell 3 Index returns and the first principal component in every experiment. We multiplied the first principal component by the sign of this correlation, in this way attempting to ensure that the first principal component and the market were positively correlated. This should have removed the ambiguity in the signs of the odd order moments and resulted in unimodal odd-order moments. The results of the transformation were largely successful, although periods 1998 2, 24 25, 26 27, and 212 213 still show some bimodal behavior. Nevertheless, visual inspection of the graphs shows the following: The standard deviation of the first principal component is approximately 1%. Recall that the component itself is constrained to have a norm of one. Looking at only the most prominent mode in each case, the skewness is approximately positive 25% or negative 25%. The kurtosis is significantly greater than the normal kurtosis of 3. Although not shown in the figures, the mean of the principal component was indistinguishable from zero in each case. In addition to the results described above, for each test, we also computed the first four moments (M1 through M4) of the first principal components. The first moment was zero, and the second through fourth are listed in Table 3. Note that the third moment is contaminated because of the sign ambiguity discussed above. 8

M2 M3 M4 1998 1999 1.32E-2-1.E-4 8.E-4 2 21 2.34E-2 7.E-4 2.4E-3 22 23 1.6E-2 2.E-4 9.E-4 24 25 9.1E-3-1.E-4 4.E-4 26 27 1.3E-2-2.E-4 5.E-4 28 29 6.24E-2-9.E-4 2.6E-2 21 211 2.52E-2-1.E-3 3.5E-3 212 213 9.9E-3-1.E-4 4.E-4 214 215 1.5E-2-2.E-4 4.E-4 216 217 1.9E-2-2.E-4 5.E-4 Table 3: Moments of the First Principal Component. Conclusion In this paper, we propose a model that accurately mimics the statistical properties of security returns. We find that realistic security returns can be generated by a low-order principal component model. We examined the statistics of a large cross section of US equities for the ten two-year periods from 1998 to 217. In all periods, the principal components were highly skewed and leptokurtic. Previously [Gerber et al., 219], we introduced the Gerber statistic, which is a robust measure of correlation between two time series. The statistics reported in the current paper, and the return model proposed, show that characteristics of the market may make the Gerber statistic a better comovement measure for portfolio construction than traditional correlation. 9

Histograms of PC1 Statistics for Period 1998 1999 3 2 1 7.5 1. 12.5 15. 3 2 1.9.1.11.12.13.14 Standard Deviation 4 3 2 1.5..5 Skewness 6 4 2 2.5 5. 7.5 1. Kurtosis Figure 2: Histograms for the Period 1998 1999 1

Histograms of PC1 Statistics for Period 2 21 2 1 3 7.5 1. 12.5 15. 17.5 2 1.12.14.16.18 Standard Deviation 4 3 2 1.2..2.4 Skewness 3 2 1 3 4 5 6 Kurtosis Figure 3: Histograms for the Period 2 21 11

Histograms of PC1 Statistics for Period 22 23 3 2 1 1 15 2 3 2 1.11.12.13.14.15 Standard Deviation 4 3 2 1.3..3 Skewness 5 4 3 2 1 3 4 5 Kurtosis Figure 4: Histograms for the Period 22 23 12

Histograms of PC1 Statistics for Period 24 25 4 3 2 1 8 12 16 2 3 2 1.8.9.1.11.12 Standard Deviation 6 4 2 1..5..5 Skewness 75 5 25 4 6 8 Kurtosis Figure 5: Histograms for the Period 24 25 13

Histograms of PC1 Statistics for Period 26 27 3 2 1 1. 12.5 15. 17.5 2. 2 1.9.95.1.15.11.115 Standard Deviation 6 4 2.5.25..25.5 Skewness 8 6 4 2 3 4 5 6 Kurtosis Figure 6: Histograms for the Period 26 27 14

Histograms of PC1 Statistics for Period 28 29 3 2 1 2 25 3 35 3 2 1.21.23.25.27.29 Standard Deviation 3 2 1.3.2.1..1 Skewness 4 3 2 1 4.5 5. 5.5 6. 6.5 Kurtosis Figure 7: Histograms for the Period 28 29 15

Histograms of PC1 Statistics for Period 21 211 3 2 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 3 2 1.14.15.16.17 Standard Deviation 3 2 1.5.4.3.2.1. Skewness 5 4 3 2 1 4 5 6 Kurtosis Figure 8: Histograms for the Period 21 211 16

5 Histograms of PC1 Statistics for Period 212 213 4 3 2 1 1 15 2 25 3 2 1.8.9.1.11.12.13 Standard Deviation 4 3 2 1.6.3..3.6 Skewness 6 4 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Kurtosis Figure 9: Histograms for the Period 212 213 17

Histograms of PC1 Statistics for Period 214 215 6 4 2 1 15 2 25 4 2.1.12.14 Standard Deviation 3 2 1.6.4.2..2 Skewness 4 3 2 1 3 4 5 Kurtosis Figure 1: Histograms for the Period 214 215 18

Histograms of PC1 Statistics for Period 216 217 6 4 2 1 15 2 25 3 6 4 2 6.8.1.12.14.16 Standard Deviation 4 2.8.4..4.8 Skewness 4 3 2 1 3 4 5 6 Kurtosis Figure 11: Histograms for the Period 216 217 19

References Rama Cont. Empirical Properties of Asset Returns: Stylized Facts and Statistical Issues. Quantitative Finance, 1:223 236, 21. Eugene F Fama and Kenneth R French. The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns. Journal of Finance, 47(2):427 465, June 1992. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French. Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, 33(1):3 56, February 1993. Sander Gerber, Babak Javid, Harry Markowitz, Paul Sargen, and David Starer. The Gerber Statistic: A Robust Measure of Correlation. Technical report, Hudson Bay Capital Management, 219. Gene H. Golub and Charles F. Van Loan. Matrix Computations. Johns Hopkins University Press, Fourth edition, 213. Harold Hotelling. Analysis of a Complex of Statistical Variables into Principal Components. Journal of Educational Psychology, 24(6):417 441, 1933. Laurent Laloux, Pierre Cizeau, Marc Potters, and Jean-Philippe Bouchaud. Random Matrix Theory and Financial Correlations. International Journal of Theoretical & Applied Finance, 3(3):391 397, 2. ISSN 219249. Harry M. Markowitz. Portfolio Selection. Journal of Finance, 7(1):77 91, 1952. Harry M. Markowitz. Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments. Basil Blackwell, Cambridge, MA, 1959. Karl Pearson. LIII. On Lines and Planes of Closest Fit to Systems of Points in Space. The London, Edinburgh, and Dublin Philosophical Magazine and Journal of Science, 2(11): 559 572, 191. Barr Rosenberg and Vinay Maranthe. Common Factors in Security Returns: Microeconomic Determinants and Macroeconomic Correlates. In Proceedings of the Seminar on the Analysis of Security Prices, pages 61 115. University of Chicago, 1976. William F. Sharpe. A Simplified Model for Portfolio Analysis. Management Science, 9(2): 277 293, January 1963. Charles E. Spearman. The Proof and Measurement of Association between Two Things. The American Journal of Psychology, 15(1):72 11, January 194. 2