Sovereign Debt and Vulture Funds

Similar documents
Creating a Soft Law Regime for Sovereign Debt Restructuring Based on the UN Principles

Gaps in the Architecture for Sovereign Debt Restructuring

Fixing Sovereign Debt Restructuring

FRAMEWORKS FOR SOVEREIGN DEBT RESTRUCTURING

Emerging Issues in Sovereign Debt What can developing countries do?

HAUT-COMMISSARIAT AUX DROITS DE L HOMME OFFICE OF THE HIGH COMMISSIONER FOR HUMAN RIGHTS PALAIS DES NATIONS 1211 GENEVA 10, SWITZERLAND

Keys For the Adoption of an Effective Regime on Sovereign Debt Restructurings 1

Sovereign debt restructuring Benu Schneider

Sovereign Debt and CDS

Design Failures in the Eurozone. Can they be fixed? Paul De Grauwe London School of Economics

Fixing Sovereign Debt Restructuring

Whither IMF Reform? Barry Eichengreen January So too, predictably, is the debate over whether that institution does more to enhance or

A New Chapter in the Pari Passu Saga

PART V LESSONS SovDebt_13_ch /25/02, 10:51 AM

SOVEREIGN DEBT CONTRACTS: RECENT DEVELOPMENTS. Anna Gelpern Georgetown Law Peterson Institute for International Economics

The Pari Passu Dilemma in the Sovereign Debt Context

Global Financial Systems Chapter 19 Sovereign Debt Crises

GOVERNMENT DEBT RESTRUCTURE PRINCIPLES

Eighth UNCTAD Debt Management Conference

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Youth Enterprise Support (Y.E.S)

Report Public Talk. Debt Restructuring in Developing Countries: The Case of Argentina

Financing Briefing. slaughter and may. IMO Car Wash: what it means for restructurings. August Case Summary

ECB-PUBLIC OPINION OF THE EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK. of 5 March on mortgage arrears resolution (CON/2018/13)

In the quest of a Framework for Sovereign Debt Restructuring 1

Financial Covenants in the Triangle between Lenders, Equity Sponsor and Management

Reconsidering the International Monetary System

DRAFT PRINCIPLES ON PROMOTING RESPONSIBLE SOVEREIGN LENDING AND BORROWING

DEBT AND DEVELOPMENT: THE NEXT 15 YEARS

Supreme Court hands down judgment in Durkin v DSG Retail Limited and another

Conference on Frameworks for Sovereign Debt Restructuring BRIEFING NOTE:

Has Argentina found a true Amicus?

The politics of Brazilian debt dynamics in the light of Argentina s default 1. By Domingo F. Cavallo

Toward A More Resilient Global Financial Architecture

The below new definitions are inserted into the TOB at Annex 1, Part 1, definitions:

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: An overview of ongoing work. Benu Schneider

Lars Heikensten: The IMF - mandate, means and governance in a changing world

RECOGNITION OF GOVERNMENT PENSION OBLIGATIONS

Discussion of Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and Interbank Market Collapse

COMMUNITY OF PRACTICE QUESTIONNAIRE ON INSOLVENCY LAW AND COMPANY LAW

Book Review of The Theory of Corporate Finance

THE EVOLUTION OF CONTRACTUAL TERMS IN SOVEREIGN BONDS

Princeton Review Litigation Puts Renewal Condition to the Test

Nouriel Roubini Do We Need a New Bankruptcy Regime?

School of Banking and Finance Working Paper University of New South Wales. Multinational Financing Strategies in High Political Risk Countries

Third-party funding in arbitration: a costs insurance broker s view

HSBC and the UN Financing for Development Office. Panel on Emerging Market Debt: Is the System Working Well Enough?

Review of. Financial Crises, Liquidity, and the International Monetary System by Jean Tirole. Published by Princeton University Press in 2002

Treasury Select Committee Inquiry into Credit Rating Agencies Memorandum by the Investment Management Association 1

Debt Clear Solutions Information Pack

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Sovereigns in Distress: Do They Need Bankruptcy?

The efficient resolution of capital account crises: how to avoid moral hazard

A Latin American View of IMF Governance

T he US Supreme Court s recent decision in Janus Capital Group, Inc. v. First Derivative

Consultation Response Office of Fair Trading: Proposals Payday Lending, Consultation on a Market Investigation Reference March 2013

Corporate Governance, Information, and Investor Confidence

Avoiding Currency Crises * Martin Feldstein **

Fixing Sovereign Debt Restructuring 1

Debt Relief for Poor Countries Robert Powell

Inflation Targeting and Output Stabilization in Australia

International Commercial Arbitration and the Arbitrator's Contract

CONTRACTUAL INDEMNITIES: PUBLIC & PRIVATE SECTOR IMPLICATIONS. Updated April 2005

Cayman Islands: Restructuring & Insolvency

BANKRUPTCY POLICY REFORMS AND CORPORATE RESTRUCTURING IN POSTCRISIS KOREA

An Oracle White Paper February Temporal Reasoning: Manage Complex Changes in Rules, Rates, and Circumstances

Some Promises Ought Not Be Honored: The Case of Odious Debts

The Ideal Collection Alternative

Christoph G. Paulus, Professor of Law, Humboldt University, Berlin Steven T. Kargman, President, Kargman Associates, New York

Debt Reorganization. Introduction. Definitions

IMO Car Wash: A Washout for Junior Creditors?

Asset specificity and holdups. Benjamin Klein 1

International Experience with Sub-national Fiscal Crises

Consultation response

AIM Rules for Companies (clean) - AIM Notice 50. AIM Rules for Companies

Assura Group Limited

Making the international financial architecture work for development

Public consultation on the 2014 Review of the OECD Principles of Corporate Governance

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT. Accompanying the document. Commission Recommendation

PCAOB RELEASE (RULE 4003) of 4 December 2008

Learning Accountancy: The Novel Way

A Report on Corporate Governance at Five Companies that Collapsed in 2001 August 2002

ACCOUNTING STANDARDS BOARD EXPOSURE DRAFT OF A PROPOSED GUIDELINE ON THE APPLICATION OF MATERIALITY TO FINANCIAL STATEMENTS (ED 168)

Cross-border recognition of resolution action. Consultative Document

Being a Guarantor. This booklet will help you understand all that is involved in being a Guarantor.

Gold vs. Bonds: Another Look

A Tip of the Hat Supreme Court s Indalex Decision Puts Spotlight on Pension Plan Governance

Simplifying the Formal Structure of UK Income Tax

Creditor Committees in Sovereign Debt Restructurings: Understanding the Benefits and Addressing Concerns

IRISH CONGRESS OF TRADE UNIONS. Response to

Greece. Eurozone rebalancing. EY Eurozone Forecast June Portugal Slovakia Slovenia Spain. Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Malta Netherlands

Why Bank Equity is Not Expensive

Sukuk restructuring. Chapter Introduction A Case for restructuring. 232 Global Islamic Finance Report (GIFR 2011)

Discussion of the Evans Paper

Taxing Risk* Narayana Kocherlakota. President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Economic Club of Minnesota. Minneapolis, Minnesota.

Narrowing the Scope of Auditor Duties

Professional Level Essentials Module, Paper P2 (INT)

Non-Legal Sanctions and Strategic Alliances: The Use of the Marriage Contract as a Model for Strategic Alliances

Guide to Enforcement

Financial Services Authority

Transcription:

King s Student Journal for Politics, Philosophy and Law Sovereign Debt and Vulture Funds Author: Eugenia Caracciolo-Drudis King s Student Journal for Politics, Philosophy and Law, Issue 1 (2017) pp.6-31 Available at: http://blogs.kcl.ac.uk/ksjppl/ All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, recording or otherwise, or stored in any retrieval system of any nature, without the prior, express written permission of the King s Student Journal for Politics, Philosophy and Law. Within the UK, exceptions are allowed in respect of any fair dealing for the purpose of research of private study, or criticism or review, as permitted under the Copyrights, Designs and Patents Act 1988. Enquiries concerning reproducing outside these terms and in other countries should be sent to the Editor-in-Chief. King s Student Journal for Politics, Philosophy and Law

Sovereign Debt and Vulture Funds Eugenia Caracciolo-Drudis 1 To dismiss the role of vulture funds in the international sovereign debt process is to fundamentally oversimplify the sovereign debt process and misrepresent borrowers (i.e. sovereigns) and creditors (i.e. banks; private equity houses; governments; trusts) as mutually exclusive in their status of victimhood. This can be illustrated by the 2001 Argentinian financial crisis whereby it is to mischaracterise vulture funds and the Argentinian socio-political situation as causes of victimisation. Rather, they are effects of a larger cause: the current institutional framework governing the sovereign debt restructuring process. For the purposes of this essay, the current institutional framework is defined 1 Dickson Poon School of Law, King s College London, Strand, London, WC2R 2LS, email Eugenia.Carracciolo- Drudis@Kcl.ac.uk 6

in terms of its legal features: the nature of the contractual debt relationship between parties and the international legal structure governing sovereign debt restructuring (SDR). As this essay will demonstrate, incomplete contracts existing within an international legal vacuum engender inefficiencies, perverse incentives and uncertainty, producing an environment in which vulture funds and socio-political discontent thrive. Restructuring therefore comes too little, too late and takes too long, harming both debtors, who suffer from severe economic distress and creditors, who stand to lose out on their investment in the process. 2 The essay will begin by contextualising SDR within the Argentinian case study in order to demonstrate how incomplete 2 Guzman and Stiglitz, 2015:3 7

contracts and the lack of an international legal framework victimise sovereign debt actors. Argentina provides a particularly interesting case study, illustrating the collective action problem creditors face in the event of sovereign debt default. In 2001, Argentina went through the largest sovereign debt default in history, leaving international creditors with drastically reduced returns on their investments. By placing creditors in this position, certain rogue creditors were incentivised to take advantage of the system, selling their over-valued bonds at a discount to so-called vulture funds who could then sue the Argentinian government for repayment. Using the Argentinian example, the essay will unpack the theoretical assumptions behind the statement, questioning its apparent reliance on a realist model of International Political Economy (IPE), before turning to the 8

future to ask where there is potential for meaningful reform. SDR is the renegotiation and settlement process for debt repayment prior to, or in the event of a default. That is, where a borrower is no longer willing or able to repay the debt they issued to creditors at the terms negotiated in the debt contract. 3 As the current institutional framework for SDR stands, where a borrower breaches, or intends to breach the terms of his debt contract, he is subject to the renegotiation or settlement of their outstanding debt, potentially lowering or extending the repayments. While simple enough in theory, with contracts governing myriad forms of debt issued to thousands of creditors across a large number of jurisdictions, in practice, SDR negotiations become highly disordered, politicised 3 Das, Papaioannou and Trebesch, 2012 9

and time-sensitive. 4 Negotiations carried out against a setting of conflicting national legal regimes, with parties holding varying degrees of political power, leads to outcomes that rely more on power dynamics than legal and economic principles. 5 Sovereign Debt Contracts Complex or Careless? Looking first to the nature of the contractual relationship between parties, it will be argued that the problem of incomplete contracts creates gaps in the SDR architecture which incentivise short-term utility maximising self-interested behaviour on the part of creditors, while simultaneously constraining debtor behaviour. 6 Incomplete contracts is a concept borrowed from the microeconomics literature, that explains contractual arrangements will necessarily 4 Tomz 2007:3 5 Guzman and Stiglitz, 2015: 3 6 Ibid.:4 10

be incomplete as they lack the capacity to anticipate all contingencies that may arise with regards to the terms of the arrangements. 7 In SDR, contractual incompleteness manifests itself in the insufficient protections granted to majority creditors against potential holdout behaviour by minority creditor groups in the restructuring process. Holdout behaviour refers to the incentive for a minority of creditors to refuse negotiations/settlement in an attempt to claim full payment or secure more than their originally contracted share of the eventual settlement payout. 8 With debt contracts during the Argentinian crisis primarily being drafted with unanimity clauses, in order for negotiations to be completed, all creditors across all kinds of credit had to agree to 7 Hart (1995) 8 Schwarcz, 2012:98 11

the changes discussed, giving holdout creditors a great deal of influence over negotiations. At their most destructive, these holdouts can buy up cheap sovereign debt with intention to bring litigation in a creditor-friendly jurisdiction, claiming full repayment of the debt, as NML Capital Ltd. successfully did in the case of Argentina. 9 In doing so, these creditors also referred to as vulture funds go one step further, bypassing the formal creditor repayment structure, undermining the provisions governing creditor priority in repayment, and the contracts as a whole. 10 Were these contracts drafted more effectively, minimising their degree of incompleteness, they could mitigate uncertainty by disincentivising holdout behaviour and facilitating 9 Vernengo, 2014:47 10 Ibid. 12

negotiation across different sets of creditors. 11 The contracts governing Argentinian debt were unable to discinentivise holdouts or facilitate negotiations, as they used unanimity clauses to govern the decision-making procedures for renegotiation of debt terms 12 ; in other words, these contracts failed to mitigate uncertainty. Due to the ineffective contractual structure, constructive negotiations between creditors with different interests become much more difficult, resulting in restructuring that comes too little, too late and too long. 13 Therefore, while Argentina cannot be said not to be a victim of so-called vulture funds, given their holdout behaviour, as motivated by personal interests, this behaviour can be understood as actually being engendered by the contractual 11 Tomz, 2013:12 12 Guzman and Stiglitz, 2015:11 13 Ibid.:3 13

framework in which vulture funds (and creditors more generally) operate. On the other side of the drafting table, incomplete contracts have important implications for debtors as well. As inefficiencies in the negotiation process at creditor-level draw out the SDR process, social and political preferences at the government-level are apt to change. The longer a debtor takes to restructure, the higher the actual costs of restructuring and foregone costs of domestic investment become. 14 An important distinction arises here between the international lenders on one hand and domestic creditors on the other. With domestic creditors often holding a large proportion of a sovereign s debt, default proceedings directly affect the national economy in terms of these loans 14 Krueger (2002) 14

as well. 15 By overlooking the effect of domestic creditors on SDR, the statement mischaracterises Argentina as wholly refusing to meet their loan obligations, suggesting an unwillingness to repay anyone, a characterisation which essentially misjudges the Argentinian socio-political situation in 2001. Facing both internal and external pressures, governments in dire economic straits appear to be faced with a choice between protecting their citizens and protecting their external relations. While it may make more sense to repay foreign creditors first, protecting the domestic creditors from a default 16, States often choose to treat domestic creditors more favourably than foreign creditors. 17 This was the case in Argentina, with domestic residents being 15 Erce and Diaz-Cassou (2011) 16 Broner, Martin and Ventura (2010) 17 Tomz, 2013: 23 15

afforded the opportunity to switch their debt into new legal instruments, which later received better treatment than the foreign-held instruments. 18 Hence, governments are forced to choose between servicing foreign or domestic debt. Given the inefficient and time-sensitive nature of the current SDR process, SDR exacerbates political tensions, pitting desperate sovereign States on the brink of economic collapse against creditors with much larger pockets. 19 Microeconomic contract theory provides further insight into this deep political and economic imbalance, claiming that at the point of renegotiation, parties with access to external assets (i.e. money) hold superior bargaining power in incomplete contracts. 20 18 Gelpern and Sester, 2004:794 19 Guzman and Stiglitz, 2015:19 20 Hart (1995) 16

Therefore, although the Argentinian people may have chosen not to repay, it is unclear to what extent their choice was entirely their own. It would be to overlook the nuances of SDR to Exclusively focus on international lenders and assume Argentina simply refused to repay its debts. A more complete understanding of the institutional SDR framework demonstrates that as opposed to prioritising shortterm self-interest maximisation, directly causing international lenders to suffer, the Argentinian decision was caused by the larger institutional inefficiencies of SDR thereby indirectly harming lenders by effect. Anarchy in the SDR As such, if incomplete debt contracts allow vulture funds to arise and force governments into difficult choices, without mechanisms to oversee 17

and enforce these debt contracts, vulture funds derive the means through which to survive within the institutional SDR framework. Then, governments may not have the incentives to follow through on their contractual promises. Interestingly, vulture funds have defended their actions as providing sovereigns with a form of accountability for their borrowing patterns through their litigation processes. 21 While it is questionable to what extent they succeed in providing such accountability, this justification raises important questions regarding international accountability more generally. Just as borrowers should be held to account for implementing morally hazardous fiscal policies 22, so lenders should be held to account for their predatory behaviour. Without an international 21 Moore (2014) 22 Schwarcz, 2012:97 18

mechanism through which to be held formally accountable for their decisions, lavish spending habits, irresponsible taxation policies and relaxed fiscal discipline take place without concern for the future. 23 Argentine officials made the decisions they did, surrendering the sovereignty of future governments in return for easy money, with no shadow of the future to constrain them 24, knowing the costs of restructuring would likely be borne by future governments. In light of the latter, the assumption of shortterm self-interested utility maximisation on behalf of both creditors and debtors appears to naturally indicate the application of realist theory to SDR. Without an international legal framework to operate within, and self-interest as the sole guide for actor 23 Blustein, 2005:6 24 Axelrod, 1984:12 19

behaviour 25, one would be forgiven for hastily characterising the world of SDR as a realist world. However, as soon as this assumption is called into doubt, realism looks increasingly like an overstatement of the perils faced by actors in SDR, overlooking that existing structures guide actor behaviour far more than pure self-interest. Given the hostile institutional framework in which the Argentinian crisis took place, this essay argues that where short-term self-interested utility maximisation takes place, it is caused by something other than the realist race to survive in a world constantly at war. Instead, it is the lack of legal frameworks and incomplete contracts which give rise to holdout creditors and constrain government behaviour, in turn engendering situational shortterm self-interest utility maximisation. SDR, after 25 Donnelly, 2000:131 20

all, is not a zero-sum game. 26 Cooperation and negotiation are not only possible in SDR, but desirable where they cannot take place, it is because actors are prevented by their institutional frameworks. Questioning the necessary conditions to allow cooperative agreements to be reached, maintained and enforced 27, rationalist institutionalism provides a more truthful model for SDR, placing it within its appropriate context. Where they work effectively, institutions (i.e. contracts and international legal structures) help mitigate adverse negotiating environments and reduce transaction costs of exchange. 28 In so doing, they enhance efficiency while simultaneously addressing uncertainties and providing positive 26 Guzman and Stiglitz, 2015:24 27 Cooley, 2010:48 28 Keohane (1984) 21

incentives for parties to negotiations. Nevertheless, the realist might question to what extent institutions are able to affect the behaviour of international entities how can we be sure it is not just that actors are inherently self-interested, seeking to maximise their short-term utility? 29 Considerations of State reputation demonstrate that short-term utility maximisation is not inherent to international actors in SDR, hence addressing this concern. 30 In theory, consideration for reputation of States suggests that actors should cooperate today to ensure good relations in the future and the avoidance of political or economic sanctions by upset parties. 31 Reputation is particularly important in the SDR context, as both parties have a vested interest in continuing the 29 Mearsheimer, 1995:7 30 Tomz, 2007:6 31 Ibid.:2 22

creditor/debtor relationship into the future, even if the current institutional framework does not accommodate for these future interests. As will be explored in more detail below, even with the flawed institutional structure in place, actors have taken concerted steps to implement reforms. This movement for reform itself provides compelling evidence for the argument that there is a meaningful dialogue between actors, institutions and actual circumstances; one far more in line with the rational institutionalist (or even perhaps constructivist) than the realist model of IPE. Too Little, Too Late, Too Long So far, this essay has set out the case for how incomplete contracts in a legal vacuum create vulture funds (including holdout behaviour more generally) and engender socio-political problems 23

within debtor governments. In this SDR world, creditors and debtors alike appear too interested in maximising their own short-term objectives, ignoring the long-term benefits of an orderly and timely restructuring process. The foregoing may paint a bleak picture of the sovereign debt landscape, but it is important to keep in mind the dialogue between actors, institutions and actual circumstances. has manifested itself in the push for institutional reforms taking place within SDR since 2001. While the international community has yet to implement an international legal structure for SDR, important progress has been made in reviewing the language of sovereign debt contracts. To protect majority creditors from holdout behaviour, Collective Action Clauses (CACs) have 24

been introduced into contracts. 32 The Argentinian debt crisis itself appears to have been an important driving force in this progress, with 95% of New York-issued debt excluding CACs pre-argentina, compared to only 21% post-argentina. 33 Such provisions allow a supermajority of creditors to agree to changes in arrangement terms, effectively overruling holdout creditors attempting to block negotiations. 34 This is not to say all sovereign debt contracts are created equal; as the aforementioned 21% evidences, CACs are still not always included in contractual arrangements, with potentially disastrous consequences. In Greece alone, approximately 90% of debt was not governed by CACs. 35 However, continued calls for reform have been taken up by the International Monetary Fund 32 Guzman and Stiglitz, 2015:15 33 Choi, Gulati and Posner (2012) 34 Ibid. 35 Schwarcz, 2012:105 25

and the International Capital Markets Association respectively. 36 Nonetheless, contracts are still only as strong as the enforcement and oversight structure in which they exist. With or without CACs, parties have no higher legal authority to turn to, in the event of a breach of contract by either side. This issue has been recognised throughout the SDR world, beginning with Krueger s appeal to the international economics community to architect a new structure for SDR in 2002, culminating in the 2014 General Assembly resolution 68/304 Towards the establishment of a multilateral legal framework for SDR processes. Drawing inspiration from the US Bankruptcy Code, the proposed framework aims to encourage an orderly and timely restructuring process through facilitated negotiations, guarantees 36 IMF 2014; ICMA 2014 26

of debtor protection from holdout behaviour, along with creditor protection from unfair treatment by debtors. 37 By introducing international legal principles and obligations to SDR, parties are incentivised to cooperate, given the high actual and reputational costs of failure to uphold contractual promises. 38 Conclusion With its incomplete contractual arrangements and lack of international legal framework, the current SDR system engenders, if not entirely encourages self-interested behaviour in both debtors and creditors, placing a premium on the achievement of short-term objectives over longterm goals. As such, it is not that the Argentinian 37 Krueger (2002) 38 Schwarcz, 2012:114 27

government victimises creditors or that vulture funds victimise the Argentines, rather it is the system that victimises them all. It is important to note that this is not to absolve Argentina or vulture funds of responsibility, but to understand the underlying structure of SDR in order to prevent another Argentina or another set of vulture creditors from arising in the future. Institutional features, rather than individual intentions appear to have a stronger role in shaping actor behaviour in SDR, allowing us to isolate important areas in need of institutional reform in the hope that future countries with a similar experience to Argentina, will have strong contractual arrangements and an international legal framework within which to enforce them, rendering questions of who is a victim of whom irrelevant. 28

References Al Jazeera (2014) The end of vulture funds?, available at http://america.aljazeera.com/articles/2014/3/22/the -end-of-vulturefunds.html Axelrod, R., (2006) The Evolution of Cooperation (New York, NY: Basic Books) Blustein, Paul., (2005) And the Money Kept Rolling In (And Out) (Cambridge MA: Perseus Books) Blyth, M. (ed.)., (2009) Routledge Handbook of International Political Economy: IPE as a Global Conversation (Abingdon UK: Routledge) Broner F., Martin A., Ventura J., (2010) Sovereign Risk and Secondary Markets American Economic Review, 100, 1523-55 Choi SJ, Gulati GM, Posner EA. (2012) The Dynamics of Contract Evolution NYU Center for Law, Economics and Organization Working Paper 12-16 Das, Udaibir S., Michael G. Papaioannou and Christopher Trebesch (2012) Sovereign Debt Restructurings 1950-2010: Literature Survey, Data, and Stylized Facts. IMF Working Paper/12/203. August. Donelly, J., (2000) Realism and International Relations (Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press) Erce A, Diaz-Cassou J., (2011) Selective Sovereign Defaults Unpublished manuscript, Banco de España Gelpern A, Setser B., (2004) Domestic and external debt: the doomed quest for equal treatment Georgetown Journal of International Law, 35, 795-814 29

Guzman, M., and Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). Fixing Sovereign Debt Restructuring, Too Little, Too Late: The Quest to Resolve Sovereign Debt Crises Columbia University. July Hart, O., (1995) Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. (Oxford: Oxford University Press) ICMA, (2014). Standard Collective Action and Pari Passu Clauses for the Terms and Conditions of Sovereign Notes IMF, (2014). Strengthening the Contractual Framework to Address Collective Action Problems in Sovereign Debt Restructuring. October Keohane, R. O., (1984) After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. (Princeton PA: Princeton University Press) Krueger, A., (2002) International Financial Architecture for 2002: A New Approach to Sovereign Debt Restructuring, Address to the National Economists Club, AEI, Washington 26 th November 2001. Mearsheimer, J. J., (1995) The False Promise of International Institutions International Security, 19(3), 5-49 Schwarcz, S. L. (2012). Sovereign Debt Restructuring Options: An Analytical Comparison Harvard Business Law Review, 2, 95-121. Tomz, Michael. (2007) Reputation and International Cooperation: Sovereign Debt across Three Centuries. (Princeton PA: Princeton University Press). Tomz, Michael, and Mark LJ Wright. (2013). Empirical research on sovereign debt and default. National Bureau of Economic Research, Paper No. w18855. 30

UNGA Res 68/304 (17 September 2014) UN Doc A/RES/68/304 Vernengo, Mark. (2014). Argentina, Vulture Funds, and the American Justice System. Challenge, 57(6), 46-55. 31