Lower and upper bounds of martingale measure densities in continuous time markets

Similar documents
Lower and upper bounds of martingale measure densities in continuous time markets

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Markets with convex transaction costs

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

Arbitrage and Asset Pricing

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

On Utility Based Pricing of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

Risk Neutral Pricing. to government bonds (provided that the government is reliable).

Law of the Minimal Price

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

ECOLE POLYTECHNIQUE CENTRE DE MATHÉMATIQUES APPLIQUÉES UMR CNRS PALAISEAU CEDEX (FRANCE). Tél: Fax:

CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

On the law of one price

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets

A class of coherent risk measures based on one-sided moments

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Convex duality in optimal investment under illiquidity

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

ON THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ASSET PRICING. Dedicated to the memory of G. Kallianpur

Performance Measurement with Nonnormal. the Generalized Sharpe Ratio and Other "Good-Deal" Measures

Spot and forward dynamic utilities. and their associated pricing systems. Thaleia Zariphopoulou. UT, Austin

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Discrete time interest rate models

L 2 -theoretical study of the relation between the LIBOR market model and the HJM model Takashi Yasuoka

Mathematics in Finance

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Price functionals with bid ask spreads: an axiomatic approach

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Arbitrage Theory. The research of this paper was partially supported by the NATO Grant CRG

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

A note on sufficient conditions for no arbitrage

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

Optimal Option Pricing via Esscher Transforms with the Meixner Process

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

European Contingent Claims

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility

Non-semimartingales in finance

Optimal Order Placement

Non replication of options

The Value of Information in Central-Place Foraging. Research Report

A generalized coherent risk measure: The firm s perspective

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand

Auction Prices and Asset Allocations of the Electronic Security Trading System Xetra

Exponential utility maximization under partial information and sufficiency of information

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

Interest rate models in continuous time

No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

The Notion of Arbitrage and Free Lunch in Mathematical Finance

Indices of Acceptability as Performance Measures. Dilip B. Madan Robert H. Smith School of Business

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

Option Pricing with Delayed Information

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

LIST OF PUBLICATIONS

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Portfolio Optimisation under Transaction Costs

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Characterization of the Optimum

Follow links for Class Use and other Permissions. For more information send to:

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

Fin 501: Asset Pricing Fin 501:

Optimal Stopping Rules of Discrete-Time Callable Financial Commodities with Two Stopping Boundaries

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Transcription:

Lower and upper bounds of martingale measure densities in continuous time markets Giulia Di Nunno Workshop: Finance and Insurance Jena, March 16 th 20 th 2009. presentation based on a joint work with Inga B. Eide

Outlines 1. Market modeling: EMM and no-arbitrage pricing principle 2. Framework: Claims and price operators 3. No-arbitrage pricing and representation theorems 4. EMM and extension theorems for operators 5. A version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing References

1. Market modeling Market modeling is based on a probability space (Ω, F, P) identifying the possible future scenarios. The probability measure P is derived from DATA and/or EXPERTS BELIEFS of the possible scenarios and the possible dynamics of the random phenomenon. On the other hand the modeling of asset pricing is connected with the idealization of a FAIR MARKET. This is based on the principle of no-arbitrage and its relation with a risk neutral probability measure P 0, under which all discounted prices are (local) martingales with respect to the evolution of the market events (for this reason P 0 is also called martingale measure). The probability space (Ω, F, P 0 ) provides an efficient mathematical framework.

Fundamental theorem of asset pricing Naturally, we would like the models of mathematical finance to be both consistent with data analysis and to be mathematically feasible. This topic was largely investigated for quite a long time yielding the various versions of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing. The basic statement is: For a given market model on (Ω, F, P) and the flow of market events F = {F t F, t [0, T ]} (T > 0), satisfying some assumptions, there exists a martingale measure P 0 such that P 0 P, i.e. P 0 (A) = 0 P(A) = 0, A F T. Cf. e.g. Delbaen, Harrison, Kreps, Pliska, Schachermayer.

No-arbitrage pricing principle Mathematically the existence of an equivalent martingale measure (EMM) implies the absence of arbitrage opportunities, this embodying the economical fact that in a fair market there should be no possibility of earning riskless profit. In fact the principle of no-arbitrage provides the basic pricing rule in mathematical finance: For any claim X, achievable at time t and purchased at time s, its fair price x st (X ) is given by x st (X ) = E 0 [ Rs R t X F s ]. Here R t, t [0, T ], represents some riskless investment always achievable and always available on the market (the numéraire).

The martingale measure P 0 used in the no-arbitrage evaluation is not necessarily unique: the equivalent martingale measure is unique if and only if the market is complete, i.e. if all claims are attainable in the market. In an incomplete market, if the claim X is attainable, the no-arbitrage evaluation of the price is independent of the choice of the martingale measure applied, thus the price is unique. But, if X is not-attainable, then the no-arbitrage principle does not give a unique price, but a whole range of prices that are equally valid from the no-arbitrage point of view. Many authors have been engaged in the study of how to select a martingale measure to be used. The approaches have been different.

Selection of one measure that either is in some sense optimal or whose use is justified by specific arguments in incomplete markets. Without aim or possibility to be complete we mention the minimal martingale measure and variance-optimal martingale measure which are both in some sense minimizing the distance to the physical measure (ref. e.g. Schweizer 2001). The Esscher measure is motivated by utility arguments to justify its use and it is also proved that it is also structure-preserving when applied to Lévy driven models (ref. e.g. Delbaen et al. 1989, Gerber et al. 1996). Instead of searching for the unique optimal equivalent martingale measure, one can try to characterize probability measures that are in some sense reasonable. This is the case of restrictions of the set of EMM in such a way that not only arbitrage opportunities are ruled out, but also deals that are too good as in the case of bounds on the Sharpe ratio (the ratio of the risk premium to the volatility). Ref. e.g. Cochrane et al. (2000), Björk et al. (2006), Staum (2006).

In various stochastic phenomena the impact of some events is crucial both for its own being and for the market effects triggered. As example, think of the devastating effects of natural catastrophies (e.g. earthquakes, hurricanes, etc.) and epidemies (e.g. SARS, bird flu, etc.). These events, though devastating, occur with small, but still positive probabilities. Having this in mind, the choice of a reasonable EMM should take in to account a proper evaluation of small probabilities, i.e. P(A) small P 0 (A) small. Note in fact that the assessment under P of the risk of these events incurring can be seriously misjugded under a P 0 only equivalent to P. This is particularly relevant for the evaluation of insurance linked securities.

Goal We study the existence of EMM P 0 with densities dp0 dp pre-considered lower and upper bounds: 0 < m dp0 dp M < P-a.s. We have to stress that these bounds are random variables: m = m(ω), ω Ω, M = M(ω), ω Ω. lying within

A bit on related literature: In Roklin and Schachermayer (2006), we follow the study on the existence of a martingale measure with lower bounded density. In Kabanov and Stricker (2001) (see also Ràzonyi (2002)) densities are bounded from above. Here the study shows that the set of equivalent σ-martingale measures with density in L (F) is dense (in total variation) in the set of equivalent σ-martingale measures. Here, we consider lower and upper bounds for martingale measure densities simultaneously.

2. Framework We consider a continuous time market model without friction for the time interval [0, T ] (T > 0) on the complete probability space (Ω, F, P). The flow of information is described by the filtration F := {F t F, t [0, T ]} augmented of the P-zero events, right-continuous and such that F = F T. Claims. For any fixed t, the achievable claims in the market payable at t constitue the convex sub-cone of the cone L + t L + p (F t ) L + p (F t ) := {X L p (Ω, F t, P) : X 0}, p [1, ).

N.B. The case L + t = L + p (F t ) for all t [0, T ] corresponds to a complete market. Otherwise the market is incomplete, i.e. L + t L + p (F t ) for at least a t [0, T ].

N.B. The case L + t = L + p (F t ) for all t [0, T ] corresponds to a complete market. Otherwise the market is incomplete, i.e. L + t L + p (F t ) for at least a t [0, T ]. N.B. If borrowing and short-selling is admitted, then the variety of claims is a linear sub-space L t L p (F t ) : L t := L + t L + t, i.e. X L t can be represented as X = X X with X, X L + t.

Price operators If X L + t is available at time s : s t, then its price ˆx st (X ) is an F s -measurable random variable such that ˆx st (X ) < P a.s.

Price operators If X L + t is available at time s : s t, then its price ˆx st (X ) is an F s -measurable random variable such that ˆx st (X ) < P a.s. N.B. If short-selling is admitted, the price operators are defined on the sub-space L t L p (F t ) according to ˆx st (X ) := ˆx st (X ) ˆx st (X ) for any X L t : X = X X with X, X L + t.

Any s, t : s t, the price operator ˆx st (X ), X L + t, satisfies: It is strictly monotone, i.e. for any X, X L + t ˆx st (X ) ˆx st (X ), X X, ˆx st (X ) > ˆx st (X ), X > X available at s The notation represents the standard point-wise P-a.s., while > means that, in addition to P-a.s., the point-wise relation > holds on an event of positive P-measure. It is additive, i.e. for any X, X L + t available at s ˆx st (X + X ) = ˆx st (X ) + ˆx st (X ). It is F s -homogeneous, i.e. for any X L + t F s -multiplier λ such that λx L + t, then available at s and any ˆx st (λx ) = λˆx st (X ). We set ˆx tt (X ) = X, X t +.

Definition. The price operator ˆx st (X ), X L + t, is tame if ˆx st (X ) L p (F s ), X L + t, i.e. ˆx st (X ) p := ( E(ˆx st (X ) ) p ) 1/p <. N.B. This definition is motivated by forthcoming arguments on time-consistency of the price operators. In view of the forthcoming no-arbitrage arguments we consider only tame price operators.

Discounting To be able to compare prices over time, we consider a numéraire which represents the chosen unit of measurement for money. This is an asset always available with payoff R t > 0 P-a.s. for every t and R s = ˆx st (R t ), s t, R s R s p 0, s s. We set R 0 = 1. Hence it is natural to assume that, for any X L + t X R s L + t, s t and we also assume that for every s t there exist c st, C st > 0 constants such that c st R t R s C st.

N.B. We have that 1 = ˆx st(r t ) R s = ˆx st ( Rt R s ) L + s. Thus 1 L + t for all t [0, T ]. Definition. The discounted price operator is defined as: Naturally, x st (R t ) = 1, s t. x st (X ) := ˆx st(x ) R s = ˆx st ( X R s ), s t. N.B. The discounted price operator x st inherits the properties of strict monotonicity, additivity and F s -homogeneity from ˆx st. Thus it is itself a price operator. Moreover, the discounted price operator is tame if and only if the price operator is tame.

Here we consider the family of price operators of X L + t, t T, ˆx st (X ), 0 s t, x st (X ), 0 s t. Definition. The family of the prices above is right-continuous at s if X is available for some interval of time [s, s + δ] (δ > 0) and ˆx s t(x ) ˆx st (X ) p 0, s s. N.B. The family of discounted prices is right-continuous if and only if the family of the original prices is. Definition. Let T [0, T ]. The family x st, s, t T : s t, of tame discounted price operators x st (X ), X L + t, is time-consistent (in T ) if for all s, u, t T : s u t x st (X ) = x su ( xut (X ) ), for all X L + t such that x ut (X ) L + u.

Comment. This axiomatic approach to price processes is inspired by risk measure theory. The requirements of monotonicity, additivity, and homogenuity are related to the concept of coherent risk measures. The additional assumption of strict monotonicity, is related to the concept of a relevant risk measure.

3. No-arbitrage pricing and representation theorems We can reformulate the basic statement of the fundamental theorem saying that: The absence of arbitrage is ensured by the existence of an EMM P 0, such that the discounted prices x st (X ), X L + t, admit the representation x st (X ) = E 0 [X F s ], X L + t. Moreover, for any t [0, T ] and X L + t the price process x st (X ), 0 s t is a martingale with respect to the measure P 0 and the filtration F. Definition. A probability measure Q P is tame if, for every t [0, T ], we have that E Q [X F t ] L p (F t ), X L p (F T ).

Facts. Let us consider P 0 P and tame probability measure. The study of the operator conditional expectation : E 0 [ F s ] : L p (F t ) L p (F s ) shows that it is: tame, strictly monotone, linear, and F s -homogeneous. Hence it has all the properties of a tame price operator on the whole L + p (F s ). Moreover, the family of conditional expectations is time-consistent: E 0 [X F s ] = E 0 [E 0 [X F u ] F s ], X L p (F t ), 0 s u t, and also right-continuous. Quite remarkably, it turns out that the converse is also true: any tame price operator x st (X ), X L p (F t ), admits representation as conditional expectation with respect to an equivalent martingale measure.

Lemma. For s, t [0, T ] : s t fixed, the operator x st (X ), X L p (F t ), is monotone linear F s -homogeneous if and only if it admits representation (1) x st (X ) = E 0 st[x F s ], X L p (F t ), with respect to a probability measure Pst(A) 0 = f st (ω)p(dω), A F t, A where f st L + 1 q (F t ), q + 1 p = 1. Moreover the operator is strictly monotone if and only if f st > 0 P-a.s. In addition, the operator (1) is bounded (continuous) if and only if { essupe[fst q F s ] <, p (1, ) essupf st <, p = 1 and is tame if and only if P 0 st is tame.

The results above are restricted to the two fixed time points s t. Now we keep s fixed and we compare the representations for different time points u t. Theorem. Let s, t [0, T ]: s t. Assume that the operators x su (X ), X L p (F u ), s u t, are tame price operators constituting a time-consistent family. Then, for all u [s, t], the representation (2) x su (X ) = E 0 st[x F s ], X L p (F u ), holds in terms of the measure Pst 0 defined on (Ω, F t ). Moreover Pst 0 Fu = Psu, 0 for all u [s, t].

Summary and the following steps. Whenever we have a time-consistent family of tame price operators x st (X ), 0 s t T, defined on the whole cone X L + p (F t ), we have an EMM. This is always true in markets that are complete. However, in general, operators are defined on the sub-cones L + t L + p (F t ). Then the existence of an EMM is linked to the admissibility of an extension of the price operator from the sub-cones to the corresponding cones. Need to give conditions (necessary and sufficient) for the extension of operators.

4. EMM and extension theorems for operators Let m st, M st L + q (F t) ( 1 p + 1 q = 1) such that 0 < m st M st, P-a.s. and { ess sup E[Mst F q s ] <, 1 < p <, ess sup M st <, p = 1. Theorem. For s, t [0, T ]: s t, fixed. The price operator x st (X ), X L + t, lying in the sandwich E[Xm st F s ] x st (X ) E[XM st F s ], X L + t, admits a tame strictly monotone linear F s -homogeneous extension x st (X ), X L + p (F t ), defined on the whole cone L + p (F t ) if and only if the sandwich condition E[Y m st F s ] + x st (X ) x st (X ) + E[Y M st F s ] holds for all X, X L + t X + Y X + Y. and Y, Y L + p (F t ) such that

The sandwich extension theorem is an extension theorem for operators lying in a given sandwich. The theorem fits in the Banach lattice framework generalizing the König extension theorem for functionals. N.B. The extension x st (X ), X L + p (F t ), if existing, is sandwich preserving, i.e. E[Xm st F s ] x st (X ) E[XM st F s ], X L + p (F t ). N.B. The extension, if existing, admits representation x st (X ) = E 0 st[x F s ] = E[Xf st F s ] N.B. The density f st lies in the sandwich ( f st := dp0 st dp ). 0 < m st f st M st P a.s.

5. A version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing Let m, M L q (F T ) ( 1 p + 1 q = 1) such that 0 < m M, P-a.s. and { ess sup E[M q F s ] <, 1 < p <, ess sup M <, p = 1. For any s t define m st := (E[m F 0 ]) t s T E[m F t ] E[m F s ], M st := (E[M F 0 ]) t s T E[M F t ] E[M F s ]. In particular we have that m = m 0T, M = M 0T. N.B. For any s t, we have m 0T = m 0s m st m tt. Analogously for M.

Theorem. A tame martingale measure P 0 on (Ω, F T ) equivalent to P such that the density f := dp0 dp lies in the sandwich 0 < m f M P a.s. exists if and only if for all s, t [0, T ]: s t, the price operators x st (X ), X L + t, satisfy the sandwich condition E[Y m st F s ] + x st (X ) x st (X ) + E[Y M st F s ] for all X, X L + t and Y, Y L + p (F t ) such that X + Y X + Y. N.B. In this case, we have also 0 < m st E[f F t] E[f F s ] M st.

Sketch of proof. Necessary condition. Consider the set of EMM: P := {P 0 dp0 dp = f, m f M; s, t [0, T ], s t E[f F 0 ] and the approximating set: P (T ) := x st (X ) = E 0 [X F s ], X L + t, {P 0 dp0 dp = f, m f M; s T, t [s, T ] E[f F 0 ] where T is some partition of [0, T ] of the form x st (X ) = E 0 [X F s ], X L + t, T = {s 0, s 1,..., s K }, with 0 = s 0 < s 1 < < s K = T. }, },

Further, we consider a sequence {T n } n=1 of increasingly refined partitions, such that T n T n+1 and mesh(t n ) 0 as n. Clearly P (Tn+1) P (Tn). Then the proof proceeds with the following steps: A. P (T ) is non-empty for any finite partition T, B. the infinite intersection n=1 P(Tn) is non-empty, and C. any P 0 n=1 P(Tn) is also in P.

Example Let L + T := {αx + β : α, β 0} be the set of claims, i.e. α represents the fraction of the claim X = (z z 0 )N(T, dz), N(T, dz) Poi(T ν(dz)), z>z 0 and β is the amount in a money market account with zero-interest. Note that X can be interpreted as an insurance policy covering all losses exceeding the deductible z 0 in the time span [0, T ]. Let the price at time 0 of X be given by the expected value principle, i.e. x 0T (X ) = (1 + δ)ex = (1 + δ)t (z z 0 )ν(dz). z>z 0 Let the bounds for the possible density be given by: δt ν(u) m = e M = (1 + δ) N(T,U) e δt ν(u), U := (z 0, )

Then both and P 0 1 {N(T, dz) = n} = (1 + δ) n e δt ν(dz) P{N(T, dz) = n} P 0 2 {N(T, dz) = n} = { 1 P{N(T, dz) = n}, z z, (1 + γ) n e γt ν(dz) P{N(T, dz) = n}, z > z, for z > z 0 and γ := δex T R z (z z 0)ν(dz), are EMM. However, the sandwich condition shows that while for P 0 1 we have m dp0 1 dp M P a.s., for P2 0 the relation is not true.

References This presentation was based on: G. Di Nunno, Inga B. Eide. Events of small but positive probability and a fundamental theorem of asset pricing. E-print, University of Oslo 2008. Relevant related references: S. Albeverio, G. Di Nunno, and Y. A. Rozanov. Price operators analysis in L p-spaces. Acta Applicandae Mathematicae, 89:85 108, 2005. T. Björk and I. Slinko. Towards a general theory of good deal bounds. Review of Finance, 10:221 260, 2006. J. H. Cochrane and J. Saá-Requejo. Beyond arbitrage: good-deal asset price bounds in incomplete markets. Journal of Political Economy, 101:79 119, 2000. F. Delbaen and J. Haezendonck. A martingale approach to premium calculation principles in an arbitrage free market. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 8:269 277, 1989. F. Delbaen and W. Schachermayer. A general version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing. Math. Ann., 300:463 520, 1994. F. Delbaen and W. Schachermayer. The Mathematics of Arbitrage. Springer, 2006. G. Di Nunno. Some versions of the fundamental teorem of asset pricing. Preprint 13/02, available at www.math.uio.no/eprint, 2002. G. Di Nunno. Hölder equality for conditional expectations with applications to linear monotone operators. Theor. Probability Appl., 48:177 181, 2003. B. Fuchssteiner and W. Lusky. Convex Cones. North-Holland, 1981. H. U. Gerber and E. S. W. Shiu. Actuarial bridges to dynamic hedging and option pricing. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 18:183 218, 1996. J.M. Harrison and S. Pliska. A stochastic calculus model of continuous trading: Complete markets. Stochastic processes and their applications, 15:313 316, 1983.

Y. Kabanov and C. Stricker. On equivalent martingale measures with bounded densities, pages 139 148. Lecture Notes in Math. 1755. Springer, 2001. O. Kreps. Arbitrage and equilibrium in economics with infinitely many commodities. Journal of Math. Econom., 8:15 35, 1981. M. Rásonyi. A note on martingale measures with bounded densities. Tr. Mat. Inst. Steklova, 237:212 216, 2002. D. Rokhlin and W. Schachermayer. A note on lower bounds of martingale measure densities. Illinois Journal of Mathematics, 50:815 824, 2006. M. Schweizer. A guided tour through quadratic hedging approaches. In E. Jouini, J. Cvitanic, and M. Musiela, editors, Option Pricing, Interest Rates and Risk Management, pages 538 574. Cambridge University Press, 2001. J. Staum. Fundamental theorems of asset pricing for good-deal bounds. Mathematical Finance, 50:141 161, 2006. V. R. Young. Premium principles. In Encyclopedia of Actuarial Science. J. Wiley & Sons, Ltd, 2004.