DO INDIVIDUALS KNOW WHEN THEY SHOULD BE SAVING FOR A SPOUSE?

Similar documents
HOW DOES 401(K) AUTO-ENROLLMENT RELATE TO THE EMPLOYER MATCH AND TOTAL COMPENSATION?

IS PENSION INEQUALITY GROWING?

HOW DO INHERITANCES AFFECT THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX?

HOW DOES WOMEN WORKING AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES?

WHY DON T LOWER-INCOME INDIVIDUALS HAVE PENSIONS?

HOW LONG DO UNEMPLOYED OLDER WORKERS SEARCH FOR A JOB?

DOG BITES MAN: AMERICANS ARE SHORTSIGHTED ABOUT THEIR FINANCES

THE IMPACT OF RAISING CHILDREN ON RETIREMENT SECURITY

USING PARTICIPANT DATA TO IMPROVE 401(k) ASSET ALLOCATION

HOW HAVE WORKERS RESPONDED TO OREGON S AUTO-IRA?

NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX: HOW MUCH LONGER DO WE NEED TO WORK?

DOES SOCIOECONOMIC STATUS LEAD PEOPLE TO RETIRE TOO SOON?

HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE

401(k) PLANS ARE STILL COMING UP SHORT

HOUSEHOLDS AT RISK : A CLOSER LOOK AT THE BOTTOM THIRD

WHY DID POVERTY DROP FOR THE ELDERLY?

IMPACT OF PUBLIC SECTOR ASSUMED RETURNS ON INVESTMENT CHOICES

THE IMPACT OF INTEREST RATES ON THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2006 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

HOW IMPORTANT IS MEDICARE ELIGIBILITY IN THE TIMING OF RETIREMENT?

HOW MUCH DOES HOUSING AFFECT RETIREMENT SECURITY? AN NRRI UPDATE

SHOULD YOU CARRY A MORTGAGE INTO RETIREMENT?

DO YOUNG ADULTS WITH STUDENT DEBT SAVE LESS FOR RETIREMENT?

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2007 REPORT IN PERSPECTIVE

A NUDGE ISN T ALWAYS ENOUGH

THE IMPACT OF INTEREST RATES ON THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX

MODERNIZING SOCIAL SECURITY: HELPING THE OLDEST OLD

401(k) PLANS AND RACE

IS WORKING LONGER A GOOD PRESCRIPTION FOR ALL?

NRRI UPDATE SHOWS HALF STILL FALLING SHORT

CAN EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT EXPLAIN THE RISE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION AT OLDER AGES?

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

THE IMPACT OF AGING BABY BOOMERS ON LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

EMPIRICAL REGULARITY SUGGESTS RETIREMENT RISKS

ESTIMATING PENSION COVERAGE USING DIFFERENT DATA SETS

JOB TENURE AND THE SPREAD OF 401(K)S

THE IMPACT OF INFLATION ON SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS

DO INCOME PROJECTIONS AFFECT RETIREMENT SAVING?

MEDICARE COSTS AND RETIREMENT SECURITY

Research Report. The Population of Workers Covered by the Auto IRA: Trends and Characteristics. AARP Public Policy Institute.

HOW IMPORTANT ARE INHERITANCES FOR BABY BOOMERS?

PENSION COVERAGE AND RETIREMENT SECURITY

ARE PEOPLE CLAIMING SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS LATER?

WHY ARE OLDER WORKERS AT GREATER RISK OF DISPLACEMENT?

THE IMPACT OF LEAKAGES ON 401(K)/IRA ASSETS

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2014 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

IS ADVERSE SELECTION IN THE ANNUITY MARKET A BIG PROBLEM?

EMPLOYERS (LACK OF) RESPONSE TO THE RETIREMENT INCOME CHALLENGE

THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX: AFTER THE CRASH

REDUCING DEFAULT RATES OF REVERSE MORTGAGES

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2018 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

THE STRUCTURE OF 401(k) FEES

PUBLIC SECTOR WORKERS AND JOB SECURITY

Is Debt Good or Bad for a Comfortable Retirement? Exploring the Relationship between Consumer Debt and Retirement Preparedness

MAKING YOUR NEST EGG LAST A LIFETIME

THE STATE OF PRIVATE PENSIONS: CURRENT 5500 DATA

HOW HAS THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AFFECTED THE CONSUMPTION OF RETIREES?

Dodged a bullet? "Rothification" likely to reduce retirement saving

Falling Short: The Coming Retirement Crisis and What to Do About It

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2011 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

PENSION WEALTH AND INCOME: 1992,

Do Defaults Have Spillover Effects? The Effect of the Default Asset on Retirement Plan Contributions

THE U.K. S AMBITIOUS NEW RETIREMENT SAVINGS INITIATIVE

DO PUBLIC PENSIONS HELP RECRUIT AND RETAIN HIGH-QUALITY WORKERS?

Automatic enrollment: The power of the default

PLANNING FOR RETIREMENT: THE ROLE OF 401(K)S IN RETIREMENT INCOME

Racial, Ethnic, and Gender Differentials in Employer-Sponsored Pensions

center for retirement research

WORKERS RESPONSE TO THE MARKET CRASH: SAVE MORE, WORK MORE?

HOW SENSITIVE IS PUBLIC PENSION FUNDING TO INVESTMENT RETURNS?

HOW MUCH DO OLDER WORKERS VALUE EMPLOYEE HEALTH INSURANCE?

DO STATE ECONOMICS OR INDIVIDUAL CHARACTERISTICS DETERMINE WHETHER OLDER MEN WORK?

HOW RETIREMENT PROVISIONS AFFECT TENURE OF STATE AND LOCAL WORKERS

OVER THE PAST TWO DECADES THERE HAS BEEN

FIGURE 1: NATIONAL SAVING HAS PLUMMETED OVER PAST QUARTER CENTURY

Retirements At Risk: The Outlook for the United States

INADEQUATE RETIREMENT SAVINGS FOR WORKERS NEARING RETIREMENT

MAKING MAXIMUM USE OF TAX-DEFERRED RETIREMENT ACCOUNTS. Janette Kawachi, Karen E. Smith, and Eric J. Toder

STATE AND LOCAL PENSION COSTS: PRE- CRISIS, POST-CRISIS, AND POST-REFORM

GUARDIANSHIP AND THE REPRESENTATIVE PAYEE PROGRAM. Anek Belbase and Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher. CRR WP August 2017

DO PEOPLE PLAN TO TAP THEIR HOME EQUITY IN RETIREMENT?

A Look at the End-of-Life Financial Situation in America, p. 2

WILL MILLENNIALS BE READY FOR RETIREMENT?

THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND STATE/LOCAL DEFINED BENEFIT PLANS

Prepared remarks for testimony before the Maryland Joint Committee on Pensions

WHY DO WOMEN CLAIM SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS SO EARLY?

The Impact of Employer Matching on Savings Plan Participation under Automatic Enrollment

A primer on reverse mortgages

SOCIAL SECURITY CLAIMING GUIDE

Are Early Withdrawals from Retirement Accounts a Problem?

WILL THE FINANCIAL FRAGILITY OF RETIREES INCREASE?

SOCIAL SECURITY AND TOTAL REPLACEMENT RATES IN DISABILITY AND RETIREMENT. Mashfiqur R. Khan, Matthew S. Rutledge, and Geoffrey T.

The Decision to Delay Social Security Benefits: Theory and Evidence

HOW THE INCOME TAX TREATMENT OF SAVING AND SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS MAY AFFECT BOOMERS RETIREMENT INCOMES

MODERNIZING SOCIAL SECURITY: AN OVERVIEW

Potential vs. realized savings under automatic enrollment

401(K)/IRA HOLDINGS IN 2013: AN UPDATE FROM THE SCF

Do Households Increase Their Savings When the Kids Leave Home?

DO LATE-CAREER WAGES BOOST SOCIAL SECURITY MORE FOR WOMEN THAN MEN? Matthew S. Rutledge and John E. Lindner. CRR WP November 2016

Transcription:

March 2019, Number 19-5 RETIREMENT RESEARCH DO INDIVIDUALS KNOW WHEN THEY SHOULD BE SAVING FOR A SPOUSE? By Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher and Wenliang Hou* Introduction Households save for retirement to help maintain their standard of living once they stop working. The amount of savings needed depends on how much a household earns. Since dual-earner households generally earn more than one-earner households, they need more savings. But only about half of private sector workers have a workplace retirement plan at any given time, and people rarely save outside of such plans. As a result, only one person in many dualearner couples is actually saving. In this situation, the spouse with a plan should save more to make up for the non-saving spouse. But 401(k) plans are individual savings vehicles, and contribution decisions are often driven by plan design features like default contribution rates and employer matches, not household earnings. The question is whether workers recognize the need to save for two. The discussion is organized as follows. The first section provides background on how individuals make saving decisions and whether they are likely to factor in their spouses situation. The second section describes the data and methodology used in the analysis. The third section provides results. The final section concludes that individuals do not seem to consider their spouses behavior when making saving decisions, which means households with two earners but only one saver end up saving relatively little for retirement. This finding highlights the importance of plan features like auto-escalation and suggests a role for educating spouses about saving for two. Alternatively, policymakers could ensure that all workers have access to a workplace plan. Background A common metric for retirement savings is having enough to maintain a household s pre-retirement standard of living. Since some expenses go down when people retire, a typical rule of thumb is that households should save enough, along with Social Security, to replace about 75 percent of their preretirement income. 1 If one of the two earners in a couple does not save, the spouse who is saving should contribute more to his 401(k) plan. Existing research, however, suggests that 401(k) plan design is the main factor driving an individual s contribution rate decision. 2 Two features of plan design are especially important. The first is autoenrollment, offered by roughly half of plans, where * Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher is associate director of research at the Center for Retirement Research at Boston College (CRR). Wenliang Hou is a senior research advisor at the CRR. The CRR gratefully acknowledges the Anna-Maria & Stephen Kellen Foundation for support of this brief. The CRR thanks our corporate partner First Eagle Investment Management for spurring our interest in this topic.

2 Center for Retirement Research the default contribution rate often determines the rate at which workers save. 3 The second is the employer match, a near universal feature, with employees bunching around the contribution rate that receives the full match. 4 If plan design plays such a key role in behavior, it suggests less room for taking spousal earnings and savings into account. While little research has addressed this issue, the evidence that does exist suggests that, all else equal, members of dual-earner couples contribute a similar share of their individual earnings to 401(k)s as those in single-earner couples. 5 This finding raises a potential concern as many of these individuals have a non-saving spouse and so should be contributing more. Data and Methodology This project uses data from the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP) for 2009, 2011, and 2013 (the three most recent years available). The SIPP is a national survey that collects information on all individuals in a household, including demographics (e.g., marital status, age, and race) and economic characteristics (e.g., employment status and earnings). In the years used for this study, the SIPP also includes questions on coverage by employer-sponsored retirement savings plans and contributions to those plans. 6 The analysis focuses on married couples where at least one member (age 25-54) is contributing to a 401(k) or other defined contribution plan. If the worker s spouse has access to a defined benefit plan, she is assumed to be saving for retirement automatically. 7 The end result is that individuals in the sample are in one of three groups: 1) single-earner couples; 2) dual-earner couples where both members are saving; or 3) dual-earner couples with just one saver. This study focuses on the saving behavior of the third group relative to the other two. The analysis takes two approaches. The first approach is a simple comparison of saving rates across the three groups. Table 1 provides selected demographic characteristics of these groups, which show that the biggest difference is total household earnings, with dual-earner households that have two savers making the most. So, if the simple comparison turns up that dual-earners with one saver do not save a higher share of their earnings, it could just be that they are constrained by lower household earnings. Therefore, the second approach uses a regression to control for earnings and other observable differences between households that could affect the individual saving rates. Table 1. Selected Characteristics for 401(k) Participants Ages 25-54, by Household Type Single-earner couples Dual-earner couples Two savers One saver Median household earnings $59,317 $101,748 $86,318 Share with some college 65.8% 69.4% 66.1% Share non-white 23.1 19.5 20.7 Number of observations 1,960 3,394 2,433 Source: Authors calculations from the 2008 and 2014 panels of the Census Bureau's Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP), covering calendar years 2009, 2011, and 2013. Results The simple comparison of 401(k) contribution rates for individuals in the three groups shows that no matter what a saver s spouse is doing his total contribution rate is typically 8-9 percent of his earnings (including employer contributions) (see Figure 1). 8 Figure 1. Average Contribution Rate for 401(k) Participants Ages 25-54, by Household Type 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% 8.6% Single-earner couples 9.4% Two savers 8.4% One saver Dual-earner couples Source: Authors calculations from the 2008 and 2014 SIPP panels, representing calendar years 2009, 2011, and 2013.

Issue in Brief 3 The individuals who should have the highest saving rate those with an earning, non-saving spouse actually have somewhat lower saving rates than the other groups. 9 In other words, these individual savers do not seem to realize that they need to pick up the slack for their spouse. It is possible that these individuals would prefer to save more, but that factors like their lower household earnings prevent it. The regression analysis controls for these differences by comparing individuals with similar characteristics. The basic equation is: Saving rate = ƒ (spousal earnings and saving, household earnings, other demographics) The dependent variable is an individual s saving rate and the key independent variable is whether the individual s spouse is earning but not saving. If savers are trying to make up for their spouse, then the coefficient would indicate a positive relationship between having an earning, non-saving spouse and the individual s own contribution rate. However, the results in Figure 2 show that, even controlling for other factors, members of dual-earner couples with one saver save somewhat less than otherwise similar individuals the same pattern as in the raw data. Furthermore, the coefficient of -0.8 percentage point for this key variable is very similar in magnitude to the difference between the saving rates in Figure 1. (The results for other household characteristics are in the expected direction.) 10 Given that the regression validates the pattern in the raw data, these data can be used to look at saving rates relative to the whole household. Figure 3 reproduces Figure 1, but with household earnings as the denominator instead of individual earnings. This analysis shows that dual-earners with one saver are doing far worse their average saving rate is only 4.9 percent of household earnings. 11 The bottom line is that an individual who is the only saver in a dual-earner household clearly does not save for two. Figure 3. Average Contribution Rate as Share of Household Earnings for 401(k) Participants Ages 25-54, by Household Type 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% 8.6% Single-earner couples 9.3% Two savers 4.9% One saver Dual-earner couples Source: Authors calculations from the 2008 and 2014 SIPP panels, representing calendar years 2009, 2011, and 2013. Figure 2. Impact of Selected Characteristics on Average 401(k) Contribution Rates for 401(k) Participants Ages 25-54 Dual earner w/ non-saving spouse -0.8% All dual earners Some college Non-white Female 10 years added age 10% increase in household earnings -0.2% -0.2% 0.2% 0.1% 0.6% 0.8% -1% 0% 1% Notes: Solid bars indicate statistical significance at least at the 10-percent level. Source: Authors calculations from the 2008 and 2014 SIPP panels, representing calendar years 2009, 2011, and 2013. Conclusion Saving is an individual decision, but the adequacy of retirement income is a household affair. This study shows that individuals with earning, non-saving spouses fail to take this information into account in their own saving decisions. As a result, dual-earner households with just one saver save too little. This result is discouraging because these households should have a leg up for saving for retirement; after all, they have two earners and access to a 401(k) two characteristics that should make it easier to save. These findings therefore suggest a role for 401(k) plan features that, at least, auto-escalate contributions with time and, at best, consider an individual s marital status when setting default rates. The findings also suggest a role for educating individuals with 401(k) plans to remember that, if they have a working spouse who is not saving, they themselves should be

4 saving for two. Finally, the issue would be moot if everyone had access to a savings vehicle in the first place so that all dual-earner households could also be dual-saver households. Thus, solving the coverage gap through programs like auto-iras is an alternative way to address this problem. Whatever the solution, until something is done, dual-earner couples are likely to end up less prepared for retirement than they could be. Endnotes Center for Retirement Research 1 Retirees no longer need to save for retirement, they pay less in taxes, and they have often paid off their mortgages. See Munnell, Webb, and Delorme (2006). 2 For an excellent discussion, see Beshears et al. (2009). 3 For classic examples in the 401(k) space, see Madrian and Shea (2001) or Choi et al. (2004). For evidence indicating that low default rates may cause some workers to contribute less to their 401(k)s than without auto-enrollment, see Choi et al. (2005). 4 See Bassett, Fleming, and Rodrigues (1998) or Choi et al. (2004). In fact, this match ceiling can sometimes trump the default rate in one plan with a default rate set below the match ceiling, many workers moved their contributions up to get the full match. Again, see Beshears et al. (2009). 5 See Butrica and Smith (2016). Although not explicitly discussed in their paper, their estimates seem to suggest that dual-earner couples contribute less when one member is not contributing to a retirement plan and slightly more when both members are contributing the opposite of what one might expect. 6 The SIPP asks about both the individual s contribution rate and the actual dollar amount. Where possible, the analysis uses the contribution rate and falls back on the dollar amount only when individuals did not provide a contribution rate. 7 The analysis assumes that spouses with defined benefit plans are saving 9 percent of their salaries. 8 Although the SIPP has data on employer matches, the exact nature of the match is not clear. For simplicity, the analysis assumes employers match 50 percent of the employee contribution. 9 One question is whether contributors in a dualearner couple with a non-saving spouse want to save more, but are constrained by the 401(k) limit ($16,500 in 2009 and 2011 and $17,500 in 2013). However, just 5 percent of these individuals are within $1,000 of the limit. This number is actually lower than the 7 percent near the limit for the other two groups of savers.

Issue in Brief 5 10 See Appendix Table A1 for full regression results. 11 It is worth noting that 90 percent of the savers in the dual-earner, one-saver couples could raise their contribution rate to match the 9.3 percent rate of dual-earner, dual savers without being constrained by the limit on 401(k) contributions. References Bassett, William F., Michael J. Fleming, and Anthony P. Rodrigues. 1998. How Workers Use 401(k) Plans: The Participation, Contribution, and Withdrawal Decisions. National Tax Journal 51(2): 263-289. Beshears, John, James J. Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian. 2009. The Importance of Default Options for Retirement Saving Outcomes: Evidence from the United States. In Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment, edited by Jeffrey Brown, Jeffrey Liebman and David A. Wise, 167-195. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Butrica, Barbara A. and Karen E. Smith. 2016. 401(k) Participant Behavior in a Volatile Economy. Journal of Pension Economics and Finance 15(1): 1-29. Choi, James J., David Laibson, Brigitte C. Madrian, and Andrew Metrick. 2004. "For Better or For Worse: Default Effects and 401(k) Savings Behavior." In Perspectives in the Economics of Aging, edited by David A Wise, 81-125. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Choi, James J., David Laibson, Brigitte C. Madrian, and Andrew Metrick. 2005. Saving for Retirement on the Path of Least Resistance. Working Paper 9. Philadelphia, PA: Rodney L. White Center for Financial Research at the University of Pennsylvania. Madrian, Brigitte and Dennis Shea. 2001. The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings Behavior. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(4): 1149-1187. Munnell, Alicia H., Anthony Webb, and Luke F. Delorme. 2006. Retirements at Risk: A New National Retirement Risk Index. Chestnut Hill, MA: Center for Retirement Research at Boston College. U.S. Census Bureau. Survey of Income and Program Participation, 2008 and 2014. Washington, DC.

APPENDIX

Issue in Brief 7 Table A1. Effect of Variables on Average 401(k) Contribution Rates for 401(k) Participants Ages 25-54 Coefficient Variable (std. error) Dual earner w/ non-saving spouse -0.753%*** (0.00148) All dual earners 0.157% (0.00166) Some college 0.585%*** (0.00143) Non-white -0.203% (0.00150) Female -0.214%* (0.00128) Additional year of age 0.077%*** (0.00008) 10% increase in household earnings 0.112%*** (0.000138) Year 2009 0.536%*** (0.00198) Year 2011 0.405%* (0.00209) Constant -7.635%*** (0.01590) R-squared 0.032 Number of observations 7,787 Notes: Each observation is a 401(k) plan participant. The regression also includes controls for the years 2009 and 2011. Standard errors are clustered at the household level. *** p<0.01, ** p<.05, * p<0.1. Source: Authors calculations from the 2008 and 2014 SIPP panels, representing calendar years 2009, 2011, and 2013.

RETIREMENT RESEARCH About the Center The mission of the Center for Retirement Research at Boston College is to produce first-class research and educational tools and forge a strong link between the academic community and decision-makers in the public and private sectors around an issue of critical importance to the nation s future. To achieve this mission, the Center sponsors a wide variety of research projects, transmits new findings to a broad audience, trains new scholars, and broadens access to valuable data sources. Since its inception in 1998, the Center has established a reputation as an authoritative source of information on all major aspects of the retirement income debate. Affiliated Institutions The Brookings Institution Mathematica Center for Studying Disability Policy Syracuse University Urban Institute Contact Information Center for Retirement Research Boston College Hovey House 140 Commonwealth Avenue Chestnut Hill, MA 02467-3808 Phone: (617) 552-1762 Fax: (617) 552-0191 E-mail: crr@bc.edu Website: http://crr.bc.edu 2019, by Trustees of Boston College, Center for Retirement Research. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that the authors are identified and full credit, including copyright notice, is given to Trustees of Boston College, Center for Retirement Research. The research reported herein was supported by the Anna-Maria & Stephen Kellen Foundation. The findings and conclusions expressed are solely those of the authors and do not represent the opinions or policy of the Anna-Maria & Stephen Kellen Foundation or the Center for Retirement Research at Boston College.